AN
INQUIRY INTO THE NATURE AND CAUSES OF
THE
WEALTH OF NATIONS.
by Adam
Smith
INTRODUCTION
AND PLAN OF THE WORK.
The
annual labour of every nation is the fund which originally supplies it
with
all the necessaries and conveniencies of life which it annually
consumes,
and which consist always either in the immediate produce of that
labour,
or in what is purchased with that produce from other nations.
According,
therefore, as this produce, or what is purchased with it, bears a
greater
or smaller proportion to the number of those who are to consume it,
the
nation will be better or worse supplied with all the necessaries and
conveniencies
for which it has occasion.
But
this proportion must in every nation be regulated by two different
circumstances:
first, by the skill, dexterity, and judgment with which its
labour
is generally applied; and, secondly, by the proportion between the
number
of those who are employed in useful labour, and that of those who are
not so
employed. Whatever be the soil, climate, or extent of territory of
any
particular nation, the abundance or scantiness of its annual supply
must,
in that particular situation, depend upon those two circumstances.
The
abundance or scantiness of this supply, too, seems to depend more upon
the
former of those two circumstances than upon the latter. Among the savage
nations
of hunters and fishers, every individual who is able to work is more
or less
employed in useful labour, and endeavours to provide, as well as he
can,
the necessaries and conveniencies of life, for himself, and such of his
family
or tribe as are either too old, or too young, or too infirm, to go
a-hunting
and fishing. Such nations, however, are so miserably poor, that,
from
mere want, they are frequently reduced, or at least think themselves
reduced,
to the necessity sometimes of directly destroying, and sometimes of
abandoning
their infants, their old people, and those afflicted with
lingering
diseases, to perish with hunger, or to be devoured by wild beasts.
Among
civilized and thriving nations, on the. contrary, though a great
number
of people do not labour at all, many of whom consume the produce of
ten
times, frequently of a hundred times, more labour than the greater part
of
those who work ; yet the produce of the whole labour of the society is so
great,
that all are often abundantly supplied ; and a workman, even of the
lowest
and poorest order, if he is frugal and industrious, may enjoy a
greater
share of the necessaries and conveniencies of life than it is
possible
for any savage to acquire.
The
causes of this improvement in the productive powers of labour, and the
order
according to which its produce is naturally distributed among the
different
ranks and conditions of men in the society, make the subject of
the
first book of this Inquiry.
Whatever
be the actual state of the skill, dexterity, and judgment, with
which
labour is applied in any nation, the abundance or scantiness of its
annual
supply must depend, during the continuance of that state, upon the
proportion
between the number of those who are annually employed in useful
labour,
and that of those who are not so employed. The number of useful and
productive
labourers, it will hereafter appear, is everywhere in proportion
to the
quantity of capital stock which is employed in setting them to work,
and to
the particular way in which it is so employed. The second book,
therefore,
treats of the nature of capital stock, of the manner in which it
is
gradually accumulated, and of the different quantities of labour which it
puts
into motion, according to the different ways in which it is employed.
Nations
tolerably well advanced as to skill, dexterity, and judgment, in the
application
of labour, have followed very different plans in the general
conduct
or direction of it; and those plans have not all been equally
favourable
to the greatness of its produce. The policy of some nations has
given
extraordinary encouragement to the industry of the country ; that of
others
to the industry of towns. Scarce any nation has dealt equally and
impartially
with every sort of industry. Since the down-fall of the Roman
empire,
the policy of Europe has been more favourable to arts, manufactures,
and
commerce, the industry of towns, than to agriculture, the Industry of
the
country. The circumstances which seem to have introduced and
established
this policy are explained in the third book.
Though
those different plans were, perhaps, first introduced by the private
interests
and prejudices of particular orders of men, without any regard to,
or
foresight of, their consequences upon the general welfare of the society;
yet
they have given occasion to very different theories of political
economy;
of which some magnify the importance of that industry which is
carried
on in towns, others of that which is carried on in the country.
Those
theories have had a considerable influence, not only upon the opinions
of men
of learning, but upon the public conduct of princes and sovereign
states.
I have endeavoured, in the fourth book, to explain as fully and
distinctly
as I can those different theories, and the principal effects
which
they have produced in different ages and nations.
To
explain in what has consisted the revenue of the great body of the
people,
or what has been the nature of those funds, which, in different ages
and
nations, have supplied their annual consumption, is the object of these
four
first books. The fifth and last book treats of the revenue of the
sovereign,
or commonwealth. In this book I have endeavoured to shew, first,
what are
the necessary expenses of the sovereign, or commonwealth ; which of
those
expenses ought to be defrayed by the general contribution of the whole
society,
and which of them, by that of some particular part only, or of some
particular
members of it: secondly, what are the different methods in which
the
whole society may be made to contribute towards defraying the expenses
incumbent
on the whole society, and what are the principal advantages and
inconveniencies
of each of those methods ; and, thirdly and lastly, what are
the
reasons and causes which have induced almost all modern governments to
mortgage
some part of this revenue, or to contract debts; and what have been
the
effects of those debts upon the real wealth, the annual produce of the
land and
labour of the society.
BOOK I.
OF THE
CAUSES OF IMPROVEMENT IN THE PRODUCTIVE POWERS OF LABOUR, AND OF THE ORDER
ACCORDING TO WHICH ITS PRODUCE IS NATURALLY DISTRlBUTED AMONG THE DIFFERENT
RANKS OF THE PEOPLE.
CHAPTER I.
OF THE
DIVISlON OF LABOUR.
The
greatest improvements in the productive powers of labour, and the
greater
part of the skill, dexterity, and judgment, with which it is
anywhere
directed, or applied, seem to have been the effects of the division
of
labour. The effects of the division of labour, in the general business of
society,
will be more easily understood, by considering in what manner it
operates
in some particular manufactures. It is commonly supposed to be
carried
furthest in some very trifling ones ; not perhaps that it really is
carried
further in them than in others of more importance: but in those
trifling
manufactures which are destined to supply the small wants of but a
small
number of people, the whole number of workmen must necessarily be
small ;
and those employed in every different branch of the work can often
be
collected into the same workhouse, and placed at once under the view of
the
spectator.
In
those great manufactures, on the contrary. which are destined to supply
the
great wants of the great body of the people, every different branch
of the
work employs so great a number of workmen, that it is impossible to
collect
them all into the same workhouse. We can seldom see more, at one
time,
than those employed in one single branch.
Though in such
manufactures,
therefore, the work may really be divided into a much greater
number
of parts, than in those of a more trifling nature, the division is
not
near so obvious, and has accordingly been much less observed.
To take
an example, therefore, from a very trifling manufacture, but one in
which
the division of labour has been very often taken notice of, the
trade
of a pin-maker: a workman not educated to this business (which the
division
of labour has rendered a distinct trade, nor acquainted with the
use of
the machinery employed in it (to the invention of which the same
division
of labour has probably given occasion), could scarce, perhaps, with
his
utmost industry, make one pin in a day, and certainly could not make
twenty.
But in the way in which this business is now carried on, not only
the
whole work is a peculiar trade, but it is divided into a number of
branches,
of which the greater part are likewise peculiar trades. One man
draws
out the wire; another straights it; a third cuts it; a fourth points
it; a
fifth grinds it at the top for receiving the head; to make the head
requires
two or three distinct operations ; to put it on is a peculiar
business;
to whiten the pins is another ; it is even a trade by itself to
put
them into the paper ; and the important business of making a pin is, in
this
manner, divided into about eighteen distinct operations, which, in some
manufactories,
are all performed by distinct hands, though in others the
same
man will sometimes perform two or three of them. I have seen a small
manufactory
of this kind, where ten men only were employed, and where some
of them
consequently performed two or three distinct operations. But though
they
were very poor, and therefore but indifferently accommodated with the
necessary
machinery, they could, when they exerted themselves, make among
them
about twelve pounds of pins in a day. There are in a pound upwards of
four
thousand pins of a middling size. Those ten persons, therefore, could
make
among them upwards of forty-eight thousand pins in a day. Each
person,
therefore, making a tenth part of forty-eight thousand pins, might
be
considered as making four thousand eight hundred pins in a day. But if
they
had all wrought separately and independently, and without any of them
having
been educated to this peculiar business, they certainly could not
each of
them have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day; that is,
certainly,
not the two hundred and fortieth, perhaps not the four thousand
eight
hundredth, part of what they are at present capable of performing, in
consequence
of a proper division and combination of their different
operations.
In
every other art and manufacture, the effects of the division of labour
are
similar to what they are in this very trifling one, though, in many of
them,
the labour can neither be so much subdivided, nor reduced to so great
a
simplicity of operation. The division of labour, however, so far as it
can be
introduced, occasions, in every art, a proportionable increase of
the
productive powers of labour. The separation of different trades and
employments
from one another, seems to have taken place in consequence of
this
advantage. This separation, too, is generally carried furthest in those
countries
which enjoy the highest degree of industry and improvement; what
is the
work of one man, in a rude state of society, being generally that of
several
in an improved one. In every improved society, the farmer is
generally
nothing but a farmer ; the manufacturer, nothing but a
manufacturer.
The labour, too, which is necessary to produce any one
complete
manufacture, is almost always divided among a great number of
hands.
How many different trades are employed in each branch of the linen
and woollen
manufactures, from the growers of the flax and the wool, to the
bleachers
and smoothers of the linen, or to the dyers and dressers of the
cloth !
The nature of agriculture, indeed, does not admit of so many
subdivisions
of labour, nor of so complete a separation of one business
from
another, as manufactures. It is impossible to separate so entirely
the
business of the grazier from that of the corn-farmer, as the trade of
the
carpenter is commonly separated from that of the smith. The spinner is
almost
always a distinct person from the, weaver; but the ploughman, the
harrower,
the sower of the seed, and the reaper of the corn, are often the
same.
The occasions for those different sorts of labour returning with the
different
seasons of the year, it is impossible that one man should be
constantly
employed in any one of them. This impossibility of making so
complete
and entire a separation of all the different branches of labour
employed
in agriculture, is perhaps the reason why the improvement of the
productive
powers of labour, in this art, does not always keep pace with
their
improvement in manufactures. The most opulent nations, indeed,
generally
excel all their neighbours in agriculture as well as in
manufactures
; but they are commonly more distinguished by their superiority
in the
latter than in the former. Their lands are in general better
cultivated,
and having more labour and expense bestowed upon them, produce
more in
proportion to the extent and natural fertility of the ground. But
this
superiority of produce is seldom much more than in proportion to the
superiority
of labour and expense. In agriculture, the labour of the rich
country
is not always much more productive than that of the poor ; or, at
least,
it is never so much more productive, as it commonly is in
manufactures.
The corn of the rich country, therefore, will not always, in
the
same degree of goodness, come cheaper to market than that of the poor.
The
corn of Poland, in the same degree of goodness, is as cheap as that of
France,
notwithstanding the superior opulence and improvement of the latter
country.
The corn of France is, in the corn-provinces, fully as good, and in
most
years nearly about the same price with the corn of England, though, in
opulence
and improvement, France is perhaps inferior to England. The
corn-lands
of England, however, are better cultivated than those of France,
and the
corn-lands of France are said to be much better cultivated than
those
of Poland. But though the poor country, notwithstanding the
inferiority
of its cultivation, can, in some measure. rival the rich in the
cheapness
and goodness of its corn, it can pretend to no such competition in
its
manufactures, at least if those manufactures suit the soil, climate, and
situation,
of the rich country. The silks of France are better and cheaper
than
those of England, because the silk manufacture, at least under the
present
high duties upon the importation of raw silk, does not so well suit
the
climate of England as that of France. But the hardware and the coarse
woollens
of England are beyond all comparison superior to those of France,
and
much cheaper, too, in the same degree of goodness. In Poland there are
said to
be scarce any manufactures of any kind, a few of those coarser
household
manufactures excepted, without which no country can well subsist.
This
great increase in the quantity of work, which, in consequence of the
division
of labour, the same number of people are capable of performing, is
owing
to three different circumstances ; first, to the increase of dexterity
in
every particular workman ; secondly, to the saving of the time which is
commonly
lost in passing from one species of work to another ; and, lastly,
to the
invention of a great number of machines which facilitate and abridge
labour,
and enable one man to do the work of many.
First,
the improvement of the dexterity of the workmen, necessarily
increases
the quantity of the work he can perform; and the division of
labour,
by reducing every man's business to some one simple operation, and
by
making this operation the sole employment of his life, necessarily
increases
very much the dexterity of the workman. A common smith, who,
though
accustomed to handle the hammer, has never been used to make nails,
if,
upon some particular occasion, he is obliged to attempt it, will scarce,
I am
assured, be able to make above two or three hundred nails in a day, and
those,
too, very bad ones. A smith who has been accustomed to make nails,
but
whose sole or principal business has not been that of a nailer, can
seldom,
with his utmost diligence, make more than eight hundred or a
thousand
nails in a day. I have seen several boys, under twenty years of
age,
who had never exercised any other trade but that of making nails, and
who,
when they exerted themselves, could make, each of them, upwards of two
thousand
three hundred nails in a day. The making of a nail, however, is by
no
means one of the simplest operations. The same person blows the bellows,
stirs
or mends the fire as there is occasion, heats the iron, and forges
every
part of the nail: in forging the head, too, he is obliged to change
his
tools. The different operations into which the making of a pin, or of a
metal
button, is subdivided, are all of them much more simple, and the
dexterity
of the person, of whose life it has been the sole business to
perform
them, is usually much greater. The rapidity with which some of the
operations
of those manufactures are performed, exceeds what the human hand
could,
by those who had never seen them, he supposed capable of acquiring.
Secondly,
The advantage which is gained by saving the time commonly lost in
passing
from one sort of work to another, is much greater than we should at
first
view be apt to imagine it. It is impossible to pass very quickly from
one
kind of work to another, that is carried on in a different place, and
with
quite different tools. A country weaver, who cultivates a small farm,
must
loose a good deal of time in passing from his loom to the field, and
from
the field to his loom. When the two trades can be carried on in the same
workhouse,
the loss of time is, no doubt, much less. It is, even in this
case,
however, very considerable. A man commonly saunters a little in
turning
his hand from one sort of employment to another. When he first
begins
the new work, he is seldom very keen and hearty; his mind, as they
say,
does not go to it, and for some time he rather trifles than applies to
good
purpose. The habit of sauntering, and of indolent careless application,
which
is naturally, or rather necessarily, acquired by every country workman
who is
obliged to change his work and his tools every half hour, and to
apply
his hand in twenty different ways almost every day of his life,
renders
him almost always slothful and lazy, and incapable of any vigorous
application,
even on the most pressing occasions. Independent, therefore, of
his
deficiency in point of dexterity, this cause alone must always reduce
considerably
the quantity of work which he is capable of performing.
Thirdly,
and lastly, everybody must be sensible how much labour is
facilitated
and abridged by the application of proper machinery. It is
unnecessary
to give any example. I shall only observe, therefore, that the
invention
of all those machines by which labour is to much facilitated and
abridged,
seems to have been originally owing to the division of labour. Men
are
much more likely to discover easier and readier methods of attaining any
object.
when the whole attention of their minds is directed towards that
single
object, than when it is dissipated among a great variety of things.
But, in
consequence of the division of labour, the whole of every man's
attention
comes naturally to be directed towards some one very simple
object.
It is naturally to be expected, therefore, that some one or other of
those
who are employed in each particular branch of labour should soon find
out
easier and readier methods of performing their own particular work,
whenever
the nature of it admits of such improvement. A great part of the
machines
made use of in those manufactures in which labour is most
subdivided,
were originally the invention of common workmen, who, being each
of them
employed in some very simple operation, naturally turned their
thoughts
towards finding out easier and readier methods of performing it.
Whoever
has been much accustomed to visit such manufactures, must frequently
have
been shewn very pretty machines, which were the inventions of such
workmen,
in order to facilitate and quicken their own particular part of the
work.
In the first fire engines {this was the current designation for steam
engines},
a boy was constantly employed to open and shut alternately the
communication
between the boiler and the cylinder, according as the piston
either
ascended or descended. One of those boys, who loved to play with his
companions,
observed that, by tying a string from the handle of the valve
which
opened this communication to another part of the machine, the valve
would
open and shut without his assistance, and leave him at liberty to
divert
himself with his play-fellows. One of the greatest improvements that
has
been made upon this machine, since it was first invented, was in this
manner
the discovery of a boy who wanted to save his own labour.
All the
improvements in machinery, however, have by no means been the
inventions
of those who had occasion to use the machines. Many improvements
have
been made by the ingenuity of the makers of the machines, when to make
them
became the business of a peculiar trade; and some by that of those who
are
called philosophers, or men of speculation, whose trade it is not to do
any
thing, but to observe every thing, and who, upon that account, are often
capable
of combining together the powers of the most distant and dissimilar
objects.
in the progress of society, philosophy or speculation becomes, like
every
other employment, the principal or sole trade and occupation of a
particular
class of citizens. Like every other employment, too, it is
subdivided
into a great number of different branches, each of which affords
occupation
to a peculiar tribe or class of philosophers ; and this
subdivision
of employment in philosophy, as well as in every other business,
improve
dexterity, and saves time. Each individual becomes more expert in
his own
peculiar branch, more work is done upon the whole, and the quantity
of
science is considerably increased by it.
It is
the great multiplication of the productions of all the different arts,
in
consequence of the division of labour, which occasions, in a
well-governed
society, that universal opulence which extends itself to the
lowest
ranks of the people. Every workman has a great quantity of his own
work to
dispose of beyond what he himself has occasion for; and every other
workman
being exactly in the same situation, he is enabled to exchange a
great
quantity of his own goods for a great quantity or, what comes to the
same
thing, for the price of a great quantity of theirs. He supplies them
abundantly
with what they have occasion for, and they accommodate him as
amply
with what he has occasion for, and a general plenty diffuses itself
through
all the different ranks of the society.
Observe
the accommodation of the most common artificer or daylabourer in a
civilized
and thriving country, and you will perceive that the number of
people,
of whose industry a part, though but a small part, has been employed
in
procuring him this accommodation, exceeds all computation. The woollen
coat,
for example, which covers the day-labourer, as coarse and rough as it
may
appear, is the produce of the joint labour of a great multitude of
workmen.
The shepherd, the sorter of the wool, the wool-comber or carder,
the
dyer, the scribbler, the spinner, the weaver, the fuller, the dresser,
with
many others, must all join their different arts in order to complete
even
this homely production. How many merchants and carriers, besides, must
have
been employed in transporting the materials from some of those workmen
to
others who often live in a very distant part of the country ? How much
commerce
and navigation in particular, how many ship-builders, sailors,
sail-makers,
rope-makers, must have been employed in order to bring together
the
different drugs made use of by the dyer, which often come from the
remotest
corners of the world ? What a variety of labour, too, is necessary
in
order to produce the tools of the meanest of those workmen ! To say
nothing
of such complicated machines as the ship of the sailor, the mill of
the
fuller, or even the loom of the weaver, let us consider only what a
variety
of labour is requisite in order to form that very simple machine,
the
shears with which the shepherd clips the wool. The miner, the builder of
the
furnace for smelting the ore the feller of the timber, the burner of
the
charcoal to be made use of in the smelting-house, the brickmaker, the
bricklayer,
the workmen who attend the furnace, the millwright, the forger,
the
smith, must all of them join their different arts in order to produce
them.
Were we to examine, in the same manner, all the different parts of his
dress
and household furniture, the coarse linen shirt which he wears next
his
skin, the shoes which cover his feet, the bed which he lies on, and all
the
different parts which compose it, the kitchen-grate at which he prepares
his
victuals, the coals which he makes use of for that purpose, dug from the
bowels
of the earth, and brought to him, perhaps, by a long sea and a long
land-carriage,
all the other utensils of his kitchen, all the furniture of
his
table, the knives and forks, the earthen or pewter plates upon which he
serves
up and divides his victuals, the different hands employed in
preparing
his bread and his beer, the glass window which lets in the heat
and the
light, and keeps out the wind and the rain, with all the knowledge
and art
requisite for preparing that beautiful and happy invention, without
which
these northern parts of the world could scarce have afforded a very
comfortable
habitation, together with the tools of all the different workmen
employed
in producing those different conveniencies ; if we examine, I say,
all
these things, and consider what a variety of labour is employed about
each of
them, we shall be sensible that, without the assistance and
co-operation
of many thousands, the very meanest person in a civilized
country
could not be provided, even according to, what we very falsely
imagine,
the easy and simple manner in which he is commonly accommodated.
Compared,
indeed, with the more extravagant luxury of the great, his
accommodation
must no doubt appear extremely simple and easy ; and yet it
may be
true, perhaps, that the accommodation of an European prince does not
always
so much exceed that of an industrious and frugal peasant, as the
accommodation
of the latter exceeds that of many an African king, the
absolute
masters of the lives and liberties of ten thousand naked savages.
CHAPTER
II.
OF THE
PRINCIPLE WHICH GIVES OCCASION TO
THE
DIVISION OF LABOUR.
This
division of labour, from which so many advantages are derived, is not
originally
the effect of any human wisdom, which foresees and intends that
general
opulence to which it gives occasion. It is the necessary, though
very
slow and gradual, consequence of a certain propensity in human nature,
which
has in view no such extensive utility ; the propensity to truck,
barter,
and exchange one thing for another.
Whether
this propensity be one of those original principles in human nature,
of
which no further account can be given, or whether, as seems more
probable,
it be the necessary consequence of the faculties of reason and
speech,
it belongs not to our present subject to inquire. It is common to
all
men, and to be found in no other race of animals, which seem to know
neither
this nor any other species of contracts. Two greyhounds, in running
down
the same hare, have sometimes the appearance of acting in some sort of
concert.
Each turns her towards his companion, or endeavours to intercept
her
when his companion turns her towards himself. This, however, is not the
effect
of any contract, but of the accidental concurrence of their passions
in the
same object at that particular time. Nobody ever saw a dog make a
fair
and deliberate exchange of one bone for another with another dog.
Nobody
ever saw one animal, by its gestures and natural cries signify to
another,
this is mine, that yours ; I am willing to give this for that. When
an
animal wants to obtain something either of a man, or of another animal,
it has
no other means of persuasion, but to gain the favour of those whose
service
it requires. A puppy fawns upon its dam, and a spaniel endeavours,
by a
thousand attractions, to engage the attention of its master who is at
dinner,
when it wants to be fed by him. Man sometimes uses the same arts
with
his brethren, and when he has no other means of engaging them to act
according
to his inclinations, endeavours by every servile and fawning
attention
to obtain their good will. He has not time, however, to do this
upon
every occasion. In civilized society he stands at all times in need of
the
co-operation and assistance of great multitudes, while his whole life is
scarce
sufficient to gain the friendship of a few persons. In almost every
other
race of animals, each individual, when it is grown up to maturity, is
entirely
independent, and in its natural state has occasion for the
assistance
of no other living creature. But man has almost constant
occasion
for the help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect
it from
their benevolence only. He will be more likely to prevail if he can
interest
their self-love in his favour, and shew them that it is for their
own
advantage to do for him what he requires of them. Whoever offers to
another
a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I
want,
and you shall have this which you want, is the meaning of every such
offer;
and it is in this manner that we obtain from one another the far
greater
part of those good offices which we stand in need of. It is not from
the
benevolence of the butcher the brewer, or the baker that we expect our
dinner,
but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves,
not to
their humanity, but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our
own
necessities, but of their advantages. Nobody but a beggar chooses to
depend
chiefly upon the benevolence of his fellow-citizens. Even a beggar
does
not depend upon it entirely. The charity of well-disposed people,
indeed,
supplies him with the whole fund of his subsistence. But though
this
principle ultimately provides him with all the necessaries of life
which
he has occasion for, it neither does nor can provide him with them as
he has
occasion for them. The greater part of his occasional wants are
supplied
in the same manner as those of other people, by treaty, by barter,
and by
purchase. With the money which one man gives him he purchases food.
The old
clothes which another bestows upon him he exchanges for other
clothes
which suit him better, or for lodging, or for food, or for money,
with
which he can buy either food, clothes, or lodging, as he has occasion.
As it
is by treaty, by barter, and by purchase, that we obtain from one
another
the greater part of those mutual good offices which we stand in need
of, so
it is this same trucking disposition which originally gives occasion
to the
division of labour. In a tribe of hunters or shepherds, a particular
person
makes bows and arrows, for example, with more readiness and dexterity
than
any other. He frequently exchanges them for cattle or for venison, with
his
companions; and he finds at last that he can, in this manner, get more
cattle
and venison, than if he himself went to the field to catch them. From
a
regard to his own interest, therefore, the making of bows and arrows grows
to be
his chief business, and he becomes a sort of armourer. Another excels
in
making the frames and covers of their little huts or moveable houses. He
is
accustomed to be of use in this way to his neighbours, who reward him in
the
same manner with cattle and with venison, till at last he finds it his
interest
to dedicate himself entirely to this employment, and to become a
sort of
house-carpenter. In the same manner a third becomes a smith or a
brazier;
a fourth, a tanner or dresser of hides or skins, the principal part
of the
clothing of savages. And thus the certainty of being able to exchange
all
that surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and
above
his own consumption, for such parts of the produce of other men's
labour
as he may have occasion for, encourages every man to apply himself to
a
particular occupation, and to cultivate and bring to perfection whatever
talent
of genius he may possess for that particular species of business.
The
difference of natural talents in different men, is, in reality, much less
than we
are aware of ; and the very different genius which appears to
distinguish
men of different professions, when grown up to maturity, is not
upon
many occasions so much the cause, as the effect of the division of
labour.
The difference between the most dissimilar characters, between a
philosopher
and a common street porter, for example, seems to arise not so
much
from nature, as from habit, custom, and education. When they came in to
the
world, and for the first six or eight years of their existence, they
were,
perhaps, very much alike, and neither their parents nor play-fellows
could
perceive any remarkable difference. About that age, or soon after,
they
come to be employed in very different occupations. The difference of
talents
comes then to be taken notice of, and widens by degrees, till at
last
the vanity of the philosopher is willing to acknowledge scarce any
resemblance.
But without the disposition to truck, barter, and exchange,
every
man must have procured to himself every necessary and conveniency of
life
which he wanted. All must have had the same duties to perform, and the
same
work to do, and there could have been no such difference of employment
as
could alone give occasion to any great difference of talents.
As it
is this disposition which forms that difference of talents, so
remarkable
among men of different professions, so it is this same
disposition
which renders that difference useful. Many tribes of animals,
acknowledged
to be all of the same species, derive from nature a much more
remarkable
distinction of genius, than what, antecedent to custom and
education,
appears to take place among men. By nature a philosopher is not
in
genius and disposition half so different from a street porter, as a
mastiff
is from a grey-hound, or a grey-hound from a spaniel, or this last
from a
shepherd's dog. Those different tribes of animals, however, though
all of
the same species are of scarce any use to one another. The strength
of the
mastiff is not in the least supported either by the swiftness of the
greyhound,
or by the sagacity of the spaniel, or by the docility of the
shepherd's
dog. The effects of those different geniuses and talents, for
want of
the power or disposition to barter and exchange, cannot be brought
into a
common stock, and do not in the least contribute to the better
accommodation
and conveniency of the species. Each animal is still obliged
to
support and defend itself, separately and independently, and derives no
sort of
advantage from that variety of talents with which nature has
distinguished
its fellows. Among men, on the contrary, the most dissimilar
geniuses
are of use to one another ; the different produces of their
respective
talents, by the general disposition to truck, barter, and
exchange,
being brought, as it were, into a common stock, where every man
may
purchase whatever part of the produce of other men's talents he has
occasion
for,
CHAPTER III.
THAT
THE DIVISION OF LABOUR IS LIMITED BY THE EXTENT OF THE MARKET.
As it
is the power of exchanging that gives occasion to the division of labour, so
the extent of
this
division must always be limited by the extent of that power, or, in other
words, by the
extent
of the market. When the market is very small, no person can have any
encouragement
to
dedicate himself entirely to one employment, for want of the power to exchange
all that
surplus
part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his own
consumption,
for
such parts of the produce of other men's labour as he has occasion for.
There
are some sorts of industry, even of the lowest kind, which can be carried on
nowhere
but in
a great town. A porter, for example, can find employment and subsistence in no
other
place.
A village is by much too narrow a sphere for him; even an ordinary market-town
is
scarce
large enough to afford him constant occupation. In the lone houses and very
small
villages
which are scattered about in so desert a country as the highlands of Scotland,
every
farmer
must be butcher, baker, and brewer, for his own family. In such situations we
can
scarce
expect to find even a smith, a carpenter, or a mason, within less than twenty
miles of
another
of the same trade. The scattered families that live at eight or ten miles
distance from
the
nearest of them, must learn to perform themselves a great number of little
pieces of work,
for
which, in more populous countries, they would call in the assistance of those
workmen.
Country
workmen are almost everywhere obliged to apply themselves to all the different
branches
of industry that have so much affinity to one another as to be employed about
the
same
sort of materials. A country carpenter deals in every sort of work that is made
of wood ;
a
country smith in every sort of work that is made of iron. The former is not
only a carpenter,
but a
joiner, a cabinet-maker, and even a carver in wood, as well as a wheel-wright,
a
plough-wright,
a cart and waggon-maker. The employments of the latter are still more
various.
It is impossible there should be such a trade as even that of a nailer in the
remote and
inland
parts of the highlands of Scotland. Such a workman at the rate of a thousand
nails
a-day,
and three hundred working days in the year, will make three hundred thousand
nails in
the
year. But in such a situation it would be impossible to dispose of one
thousand, that is, of
one
day's work in the year. As by means of water-carriage, a more extensive market
is opened
to
every sort of industry than what land-carriage alone can afford it, so it is
upon the sea-coast,
and
along the banks of navigable rivers, that industry of every kind naturally
begins to
subdivide
and improve itself, and it is frequently not till a long time after that those
improvements
extend themselves to the inland parts of the country. A broad-wheeled waggon,
attended
by two men, and drawn by eight horses, in about six weeks time, carries and
brings
back
between London and Edinburgh near four ton weight of goods. In about the same
time a
ship
navigated by six or eight men, and sailing between the ports of London and
Leith,
frequently
carries and brings back two hundred ton weight of goods. Six or eight men,
therefore,
by the help of water-carriage, can carry and bring back, in the same time, the
same
quantity
of goods between London and Edinburgh as fifty broad-wheeled waggons, attended
by a
hundred men, and drawn by four hundred horses. Upon two hundred tons of goods,
therefore,
carried by the cheapest land-carriage from London to Edinburgh, there must be
charged
the maintenance of a hundred men for three weeks, and both the maintenance and
what is
nearly equal to maintenance the wear and tear of four hundred horses, as well
as of
fifty
great waggons. Whereas, upon the same quantity of goods carried by water, there
is to be
charged
only the maintenance of six or eight men, and the wear and tear of a ship of
two
hundred
tons burthen, together with the value of the superior risk, or the difference
of the
insurance
between land and water-carriage. Were there no other communication between
those
two places, therefore, but by land-carriage, as no goods could be transported
from the
one to
the other, except such whose price was very considerable in proportion to their
weight,
they
could carry on but a small part of that commerce which at present subsists
between them,
and
consequently could give but a small part of that encouragement which they at
present
mutually
afford to each other's industry. There could be little or no commerce of any
kind
between
the distant parts of the world. What goods could bear the expense of
land-carriage
between
London and Calcutta ? Or if there were any so precious as to be able to support
this
expense,
with what safety could they be transported through the territories of so many
barbarous
nations? Those two cities, however, at present carry on a very considerable
commerce
with each other, and by mutually affording a market, give a good deal of
encouragement
to each other's industry.
Since
such, therefore, are the advantages of water-carriage, it is natural that the
first
improvements
of art and industry should be made where this conveniency opens the whole
world
for a market to the produce of every sort of labour, and that they should
always be
much
later in extending themselves into the inland parts of the country. The inland
parts of the
country
can for a long time have no other market for the greater part of their goods,
but the
country
which lies round about them, and separates them from the sea-coast, and the
great
navigable
rivers. The extent of the market, therefore, must for a long time be in
proportion to
the
riches and populousness of that country, and consequently their improvement
must always
be
posterior to the improvement of that country. In our North American colonies,
the
plantations
have constantly followed either the sea-coast or the banks of the navigable
rivers,
and
have scarce anywhere extended themselves to any considerable distance from
both.
The
nations that, according to the best authenticated history, appear to have been
first
civilized,
were those that dwelt round the coast of the Mediterranean sea. That sea, by
far the
greatest
inlet that is known in the world, having no tides, nor consequently any waves,
except
such as
are caused by the wind only, was, by the smoothness of its surface, as well as
by the
multitude
of its islands, and the proximity of its neighbouring shores, extremely
favourable to
the
infant navigation of the world; when, from their ignorance of the compass, men
were
afraid
to quit the view of the coast, and from the imperfection of the art of
ship-building, to
abandon
themselves to the boisterous waves of the ocean. To pass beyond the pillars of
Hercules,
that is, to sail out of the straits of Gibraltar, was, in the ancient world,
long
considered
as a most wonderful and dangerous exploit of navigation. It was late before
even
the
Phoenicians and Carthaginians, the most skilful navigators and ship-builders of
those old
times,
attempted it; and they were, for a long time, the only nations that did attempt
it.
Of all
the countries on the coast of the Mediterranean sea, Egypt seems to have been
the first
in
which either agriculture or manufactures were cultivated and improved to any
considerable
degree.
Upper Egypt extends itself nowhere above a few miles from the Nile; and in
Lower
Egypt,
that great river breaks itself into many different canals, which, with the
assistance of a
little
art, seem to have afforded a communication by water-carriage, not only between
all the
great
towns, but between all the considerable villages, and even to many farm-houses
in the
country,
nearly in the same manner as the Rhine and the Maese do in Holland at present.
The
extent
and easiness of this inland navigation was probably one of the principal causes
of the
early
improvement of Egypt.
The
improvements in agriculture and manufactures seem likewise to have been of very
great
antiquity
in the provinces of Bengal, in the East Indies, and in some of the eastern
provinces
of
China, though the great extent of this antiquity is not authenticated by any
histories of
whose
authority we, in this part of the world, are well assured. In Bengal, the
Ganges, and
several
other great rivers, form a great number of navigable canals, in the same manner
as the
Nile
does in Egypt. In the eastern provinces of China, too, several great rivers
form, by their
different
branches, a multitude of canals, and, by communicating with one another, afford
an
inland
navigation much more extensive than that either of the Nile or the Ganges, or,
perhaps,
than
both of them put together. It is remarkable, that neither the ancient
Egyptians, nor the
Indians,
nor the Chinese, encouraged foreign commerce, but seem all to have derived
their
great
opulence from this inland navigation.
All the
inland parts of Africa, and all that part of Asia which lies any considerable
way north
of the
Euxine and Caspian seas, the ancient Scythia, the modern Tartary and Siberia,
seem, in
all
ages of the world, to have been in the same barbarous and uncivilized state in
which we
find
them at present. The sea of Tartary is the frozen ocean, which admits of no
navigation ;
and
though some of the greatest rivers in the world run through that country, they
are at too
great a
distance from one another to carry commerce and communication through the
greater
part of
it. There are in Africa none of those great inlets, such as the Baltic and
Adriatic seas in
Europe,
the Mediterranean and Euxine seas in both Europe and Asia, and the gulfs of
Arabia,
Persia,
India, Bengal, and Siam, in Asia, to carry maritime commerce into the interior
parts of
that
great continent; and the great rivers of Africa are at too great a distance
from one another
to give
occasion to any considerable inland navigation. The commerce, besides, which
any
nation
can carry on by means of a river which does not break itself into any great
number of
branches
or canals, and which runs into another territory before it reaches the sea, can
never
be very
considerable, because it is always in the power of the nations who possess that
other
territory
to obstruct the communication between the upper country and the sea. The
navigation
of the
Danube is of very little use to the different states of Bavaria, Austria. and
Hungary, in
comparison
of what it would be, if any of them possessed the whole of its course, till it
falls
into
the Black sea.
CHAPTER IV.
OF THE
ORIGIN AND USE OF MONEY.
When
the division of labour has been once thoroughly established, it is but
a very
small part of a man's wants which the produce of his own labour can
supply.
He supplies the far greater part of them by exchanging that surplus
part of
the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his own
consumption,
for such parts of the produce of other men's labour as he has
occasion
for. Every man thus lives by exchanging, or becomes, in some
measure,
a merchant, and the society itself grows to be what is properly a
commercial
society.
But
when the division of labour first began to take place, this power of
exchanging
must frequently have been very much clogged and embarrassed in
its
operations. One man, we shall suppose, has more of a certain commodity
than he
himself has occasion for, while another has less. The former,
consequently,
would be glad to dispose of; and the latter to purchase, a
part of
this superfluity. But if this latter should chance to have nothing
that
the former stands in need of, no exchange can be made between them. The
butcher
has more meat in his shop than he himself can consume, and the
brewer
and the baker would each of them be willing to purchase a part of it.
But
they have nothing to offer in exchange, except the different productions
of
their respective trades, and the butcher is already provided with all the
bread
and beer which he has immediate occasion for. No exchange can, in this
case,
be made between them. He cannot be their merchant, nor they his
customers
; and they are all of them thus mutually less serviceable to one
another.
In order to avoid the inconveniency of such situations, every
prudent
man in every period of society, after the first establishment of the
division
of labour, must naturally have endeavoured to manage his affairs in
such a
manner, as to have at all times by him, besides the peculiar produce
of his
own industry, a certain quantity of some one commodity or other, such
as he
imagined few people would be likely to refuse in exchange for the
produce
of their industry. Many different commodities, it is probable, were
successively
both thought of and employed for this purpose. In the rude ages
of
society, cattle are said to have been the common instrument of commerce ;
and,
though they must have been a most inconvenient one, yet, in old times,
we find
things were frequently valued according to the number of cattle
which
had been given in exchange for them. The armour of Diomede, says
Homer,
cost only nine oxen; but that of Glaucus cost a hundred oxen. Salt is
said to
be the common instrument of commerce and exchanges in Abyssinia ; a
species
of shells in some parts of the coast of India ; dried cod at
Newfoundland;
tobacco in Virginia; sugar in some of our West India colonies;
hides
or dressed leather in some other countries; and there is at this day a
village
In Scotland, where it is not uncommon, I am told, for a workman to
carry
nails instead of money to the baker's shop or the ale-house.
In all
countries, however, men seem at last to have been determined by
irresistible
reasons to give the preference, for this employment, to metals
above
every other commodity. Metals can not only be kept with as little loss
as any
other commodity, scarce any thing being less perishable than they
are,
but they can likewise, without any loss, be divided into any number of
parts,
as by fusion those parts can easily be re-united again; a quality
which
no other equally durable commodities possess, and which, more than any
other
quality, renders them fit to be the instruments of commerce and
circulation.
The man who wanted to buy salt, for example, and had nothing
but
cattle to give in exchange for it, must have been obliged to buy salt to
the
value of a whole ox, or a whole sheep, at a time. He could seldom buy
less
than this, because what he was to give for it could seldom be divided
without
loss; and if he had a mind to buy more, he must, for the same
reasons,
have been obliged to buy double or triple the quantity, the value,
to wit,
of two or three oxen, or of two or three sheep. If, on the contrary,
instead
of sheep or oxen, he had metals to give in exchange for it, he could
easily
proportion the quantity of the metal to the precise quantity of the
commodity
which he had immediate occasion for.
Different
metals have been made use of by different nations for this
purpose.
Iron was the common instrument of commerce among the ancient
Spartans,
copper among the ancient Romans, and gold and silver among all
rich
and commercial nations.
Those
metals seem originally to have been made use of for this purpose in
rude
bars, without any stamp or coinage. Thus we are told by Pliny (Plin.
Hist
Nat. lib. 33, cap. 3), upon the authority of Timaeus, an ancient
historian,
that, till the time of Servius Tullius, the Romans had no coined
money,
but made use of unstamped bars of copper, to purchase whatever they
had
occasion for. These rude bars, therefore, performed at this time the
function
of rnoney.
The use
of metals in this rude state was attended with two very considerable
inconveniences
; first, with the trouble of weighing, and secondly, with
that of
assaying them. In the precious metals, where a small difference in
the
quantity makes a great difference in the value, even the business of
weighing,
with proper exactness, requires at least very accurate weights and
scales.
The weighing of gold, in particular, is an operation of some nicety
In the
coarser metals, indeed, where a small error would be of little
consequence,
less accuracy would, no doubt, be necessary. Yet we should find
it
excessively troublesome if every time a poor man had occasion either to
buy or
sell a farthing's worth of goods, he was obliged to weigh the
farthing.
The operation of assaying is still more difficult, still more
tedious
; and, unless a part of the metal is fairly melted in the crucible,
with
proper dissolvents, any conclusion that can be drawn from it is
extremely
uncertain. Before the institution of coined money, however, unless
they
went through this tedious and difficult operation, people must always
have
been liable to the grossest frauds and impositions; and instead of a
pound
weight of pure silver, or pure copper, might receive, in exchange for
their
goods, an adulterated composition of the coarsest and cheapest
materials,
which had, however, in their outward appearance, been made to
resemble
those metals. To prevent such abuses, to facilitate exchanges, and
thereby
to encourage all sorts of industry and commerce, it has been found
necessary,
in all countries that have made any considerable advances towards
improvement,
to affix a public stamp upon certain quantities of such
particular
metals, as were in those countries commonly made use of to
purchase
goods. Hence the origin of coined money, and of those public
offices
called mints; institutions exactly of the same nature with those of
the
aulnagers and stamp-masters of woollen and linen cloth. All of them are
equally
meant to ascertain, by means of a public stamp, the quantity and
uniform
goodness of those different commodities when brought to market.
The
first public stamps of this kind that were affixed to the current
metals,
seem in many cases to have been intended to ascertain, what it was
both
most difficult and most important to ascertain, the goodness or
fineness
of the metal, and to have resembled the sterling mark which is at
present
affixed to plate and bars of silver, or the Spanish mark which is
sometimes
affixed to ingots of gold, and which, being struck only upon one
side of
the piece, and not covering the whole surface, ascertains the
fineness,
but not the weight of the metal. Abraham weighs to Ephron the four
hundred
shekels of silver which he had agreed to pay for the field of
Machpelah.
They are said, however, to be the current money of the merchant,
and yet
are received by weight, and not by tale, in the same manner as
ingots
of gold and bars of silver are at present. The revenues of the
ancient
Saxon kings of England are said to have been paid, not in money, but
in
kind, that is, in victuals and provisions of all sorts. William the
Conqueror
introduced the custom of paying them in money. This money,
however,
was for a long time, received at the exchequer, by weight, and not
by
tale,
The
inconveniency and difficulty of weighing those metals with exactness,
gave
occasion to the institution of coins, of which the stamp, covering
entirely
both sides of the piece, and sometimes the edges too, was supposed
to
ascertain not only the fineness, but the weight of the metal. Such
coins,
therefore, were received by tale, as at present, without the trouble
of
weighing.
The
denominations of those coins seem originally to have expressed the
weight
or quantity of metal contained in them. In the time of Servius
Tullius,
who first coined money at Rome, the Roman as or pondo contained a
Roman
pound of good copper. It was divided, in the same manner as our Troyes
pound,
into twelve ounces, each of which contained a real ounce of good
copper.
The English pound sterling, in the time of Edward I. contained a
pound,
Tower weight, of silver of a known fineness. The Tower pound seems to
have
been something more than the Roman pound, and something less than the
Troyes
pound. This last was not introduced into the mint of England till the
18th of
Henry the VIII. The French livre contained, in the time of
Charlemagne,
a pound, Troyes weight, of silver of a known fineness. The fair
of
Troyes in Champaign was at that time frequented by all the nations of
Europe,
and the weights and measures of so famous a market were generally
known
and esteemed. The Scots money pound contained, from the time of
Alexander
the First to that of Robert Bruce, a pound of silver of the same
weight
and fineness with the English pound sterling. English, French, and
Scots
pennies, too, contained all of them originally a real penny-weight of
silver,
the twentieth part of an ounce, and the two hundred-and-fortieth
part of
a pound. The shilling, too, seems originally to have been
the
denomination of a weight. "When wheat is at twelve shillings the quarter,"
says an
ancient statute of Henry III." then wastel bread of a farthing shall
weigh
eleven shillings and fourpence". The proportion, however, between the
shilling,
and either the penny on the one hand, or the pound on the other,
seems
not to have been so constant and uniform as that between the penny and
the
pound. During the first race of the kings of France, the French sou or
shilling
appears upon different occasions to have contained five, twelve,
twenty,
and forty pennies. Among the ancient Saxons, a shilling appears at
one
time to have contained only five pennies, and it is not improbable that
it may
have been as variable among them as among their neighbours, the
ancient
Franks. From the time of Charlemagne among the French, and from that
of
William the Conqueror among the English, the proportion between the
pound,
the shilling, and the penny, seems to have been uniformly the same as
at
present, though the value of each has been very different ; for in every
country
of the world, I believe, the avarice and injustice of princes and
sovereign
states, abusing the confidence of their subjects, have by degrees
diminished
the real quantity of metal, which had been originally contained
in
their coins. The Roman as, in the latter ages of the republic, was
reduced
to the twenty-fourth part of its original value, and, instead of
weighing
a pound, came to weigh only half an ounce. The English pound and
penny
contain at present about a third only ; the Scots pound and penny
about a
thirty-sixth ; and the French pound and penny about a sixty-sixth
part of
their original value. By means of those operations, the princes and
sovereign
states which performed them were enabled, in appearance, to pay
their
debts and fulfil their engagements with a smaller quantity of silver
than
would otherwise have been requisite. It was indeed in appearance only ;
for
their creditors were really defrauded of a part of what was due to them.
All
other debtors in the state were allowed the same privilege, and might
pay
with the same nominal sum of the new and debased coin whatever they had
borrowed
in the old. Such operations, therefore, have always proved
favourable
to the debtor, and ruinous to the creditor, and have sometimes
produced
a greater and more universal revolution in the fortunes of private
persons,
than could have been occasioned by a very great public calamity.
It is
in this manner that money has become, in all civilized nations, the
universal
instrument of commerce, by the intervention of which goods of all
kinds
are bought and sold, or exchanged for one another.
What
are the rules which men naturally observe, in exchanging them either
for
money, or for one another, I shall now proceed to examine. These rules
determine
what may be called the relative or exchangeable value of goods.
The
word VALUE, it is to be observed, has two different meanings, and
sometimes
expresses the utility of some particular object, and sometimes the
power
of purchasing other goods which the possession of that object conveys.
The one
may be called ' value in use ;' the other, 'value in exchange.' The
things
which have the greatest value in use have frequently little or no
value
in exchange ; and, on the contrary, those which have the greatest
value
in exchange have frequently little or no value in use. Nothing is more
useful
than water ; but it will purchase scarce any thing; scarce any thing
can be
had in exchange for it. A diamond, on the contrary, has scarce any
value
in use; but a very great quantity of other goods may frequently be had
in
exchange for it.
In
order to investigate the principles which regulate the exchangeable value
of
commodities, I shall endeavour to shew,
First,
what is the real measure of this exchangeable value; or wherein
consists
the real price of all commodities.
Secondly,
what are the different parts of which this real price is composed
or made
up.
And,
lastly, what are the different circumstances which sometimes raise some
or all
of these different parts of price above, and sometimes sink them
below,
their natural or ordinary rate; or, what are the causes which
sometimes
hinder the market price, that is, the actual price of commodities,
from
coinciding exactly with what may be called their natural price.
I shall
endeavour to explain, as fully and distinctly as I can, those three
subjects
in the three following chapters, for which I must very earnestly
entreat
both the patience and attention of the reader : his patience, in
order
to examine a detail which may, perhaps, in some places, appear
unnecessarily
tedious; and his attention, in order to understand what may
perhaps,
after the fullest explication which I am capable of giving it,
appear
still in some degree obscure. I am always willing to run some hazard
of
being tedious, in order to be sure that I am perspicuous; and, after
taking
the utmost pains that I can to be perspicuous, some obscurity may
still
appear to remain upon a subject, in its own nature extremely
abstracted.
CHAPTER V.
OF THE
REAL AND NOMINAL PRICE OF COMMODITIES, OR OF THEIR PRICE IN
LABOUR,
AND THEIR PRICE IN MONEY.
Every
man is rich or poor according to the degree in which he can afford to
enjoy
the necessaries, conveniencies, and amusements of human life. But
after
the division of labour has once thoroughly taken place, it is but a
very
small part of these with which a man's own labour can supply him. The
far
greater part of them he must derive from the labour of other people, and
he must
be rich or poor according to the quantity of that labour which he
can
command, or which he can afford to purchase. The value of any commodity,
therefore,
to the person who possesses it, and who means not to use or
consume
it himself, but to exchange it for other commodities, is equal to
the
quantity of labour which it enables him to purchase or command. Labour
therefore,
is the real measure of the exchangeable value of all commodities.
The
real price of every thing, what every thing really costs to the man who
wants
to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it. What every
thing
is really worth to the man who has acquired it and who wants to
dispose
of it, or exchange it for something else, is the toil and trouble
which
it can save to himself, and which it can impose upon other people.
What is
bought with money, or with goods, is purchased by labour, as much as
what we
acquire by the toil of our own body. That money, or those goods,
indeed,
save us this toil. They contain the value of a certain quantity of
labour,
which we exchange for what is supposed at the time to contain the
value
of an equal quantity. Labour was the first price, the original
purchase
money that was paid for all things. It was not by gold or by silver,
but by
labour, that all the wealth of the world was originally purchased;
and its
value, to those who possess it, and who want to exchange it for some
new
productions, is precisely equal to the quantity of' labour which it can
enable
them to purchase or command.
Wealth,
as Mr Hobbes says, is power. But the person who either acquires, or
succeeds
to a great fortune, does not necessarily acquire or succeed to any
political
power, either civil or military. His fortune may, perhaps, afford
him the
means of acquiring both; but the mere possession of that fortune
does
not necessarily convey to him either. The power which that possession
immediately
and directly conveys to him, is the power of purchasing a
certain
command over all the labour, or over all the produce of labour which
is then
in the market. His fortune is greater or less, precisely in
proportion
to the extent of this power, or to the quantity either of other
men's
labour, or, what is the same thing, of the produce of other men's
labour,
which it enables him to purchase or command. The exchangeable value
of
every thing must always be precisely equal to the extent of this power
which
it conveys to its owner.
But
though labour be the real measure of the exchangeable value of all
commodities,
it is not that by which their value is commonly estimated. It
is
often difficult to ascertain the proportion between two different
quantities
of labour. The time spent in two different sorts of work will not
always
alone determine this proportion. The different degrees of hardship
endured,
and of ingenuity exercised, must likewise be taken into account.
There
may be more labour in an hour's hard work, than in two hours easy
business
; or in an hour's application to a trade which it cost ten years
labour
to learn, than in a month's industry, at an ordinary and obvious
employment.
But it is not easy to find any accurate measure either of
hardship
or ingenuity. In exchanging, indeed, the different productions of
different
sorts of labour for one another, some allowance is commonly made
for
both. It is adjusted, however, not by any accurate measure, but by the
higgling
and bargaining of the market, according to that sort of rough
equality
which, though not exact, is sufficient for carrying on the business
of
common life.
Every
commodity, besides, Is more frequently exchanged for, and thereby
compared
with, other commodities, than with labour. It is more natural,
therefore,
to estimate its exchangeable value by the quantity of some other
commodity,
than by that of the labour which it can produce. The greater part
of
people, too, understand better what is meant by a quantity of a
particular
commodity, than by a quantity of labour. The one is a plain
palpable
object ; the other an abstract notion, which though it can be made
sufficiently
intelligible, is not altogether so natural and obvious.
But
when barter ceases, and money has become the common instrument of
commerce,
every particular commodity is more frequently exchanged for money
than
for any other commodity. The butcher seldom carries his beef or his
mutton
to the baker or the brewer, in order to exchange them for bread or
for
beer ; but he carries them to the market, where he exchanges them for
money,
and afterwards exchanges that money for bread and for beer. The
quantity
of money which he gets for them regulates, too, the quantity of
bread
and beer which he can afterwards purchase. It is more natural and
obvious
to him, therefore, to estimate their value by the quantity of money,
the
commodity for which he immediately exchanges them, than by that of
bread
and beer, the commodities for which he can exchange them only by the
intervention
of another commodity ; and rather to say that his butcher's
meat is
worth three-pence or fourpence a-pound, than that it is worth three
or four
pounds of bread, or three or four quarts of small beer. Hence it
comes
to pass, that the exchangeable value of every commodity is more
frequently
estimated by the quantity of money, than by the quantity either
of
labour or of any other commodity which can be had in exchange for it.
Gold
and silver, however, like every other commodity, vary in their value;
are
sometimes cheaper and sometimes dearer, sometimes of easier and
sometimes
of more difficult purchase. The quantity of labour which any
particular
quantity of them can purchase or command, or the quantity of
other
goods which it will exchange for, depends always upon the fertility or
barrenness
of the mines which happen to be known about the time when such
exchanges
are made. The discovery of the abundant mines of America, reduced,
in the
sixteenth century, the value of gold and silver in Europe to about a
third
of what it had been before. As it cost less labour to bring those
metals
from the mine to the market, so, when they were brought thither, they
could
purchase or command less labour; and this revolution in their value,
though
perhaps the greatest, is by no means the only one of which history
gives
some account. But as a measure of quantity, such as the natural foot,
fathom,
or handful, which is continually varying in its own quantity, can
never
be an accurate measure of the quantity of other things ; so a
commodity
which is itself continually varying in its own value, can never be
an
accurate measure of the value of other commodities. Equal quantities of
labour,
at all times and places, may be said to be of equal value to the
labourer.
In his ordinary state of health, strength, and spirits ; in the
ordinary
degree of his skill and dexterity, he must always lay down the same
portion
of his ease, his liberty, and his happiness. The price which he pays
must
always be the same, whatever may be the quantity of goods which he
receives
in return for it. Of these, indeed, it may sometimes purchase a
greater
and sometimes a smaller quantity ; but it is their value which
varies,
not that of the labour which purchases them. At all times and
places,
that is dear which it is difficult to come at, or which it costs
much
labour to acquire; and that cheap which is to be had easily, or with
very
little labour. Labour alone, therefore, never varying in its own value,
is
alone the ultimate and real standard by which the value of all
commodities
can at all times and places be estimated and compared. It is
their
real price; money is their nominal price only.
But
though equal quantities of labour are always of equal value to the
labourer,
yet to the person who employs him they appear sometimes to be of
greater,
and sometimes of smaller value. He purchases them sometimes with a
greater,
and sometimes with a smaller quantity of goods, and to him the
price
of labour seems to vary like that of all other things. It appears to
him
dear in the one case, and cheap in the other. In reality, however, it is
the
goods which are cheap in the one case, and dear in the other.
In this
popular sense, therefore, labour, like commodities, may be said to
have a
real and a nominal price. Its real price may be said to consist in
the
quantity of the necessaries and conveniencies of life which are given
for it
; its nominal price, in the quantity of money. The labourer is rich
or
poor, is well or ill rewarded, in proportion to the real, not to the
nominal
price of his labour.
The
distinction between the real and the nominal price of commodities and
labour
is not a matter of mere speculation, but may sometimes be of
considerable
use in practice. The same real price is always of the same
value;
but on account of the variations in the value of gold and silver, the
same
nominal price is sometimes of very different values. When a landed
estate,
therefore, is sold with a reservation of a perpetual rent, if it is
intended
that this rent should always be of the same value, it is of
importance
to the family in whose favour it is reserved, that it should not
consist
in a particular sum of money. Its value would in this case be liable
to
variations of two different kinds: first, to those which arise from the
different
quantities of gold and silver which are contained at different
times
in coin of the same denomination; and, secondly, to those which arise
from
the different values of equal quantities of gold and silver at
different
times.
Princes
and sovereign states have frequently fancied that they had a
temporary
interest to diminish the quantity of pure metal contained in their
coins;
but they seldom have fancied that they had any to augment it. The
quantity
of metal contained in the coins, I believe of all nations, has
accordingly
been almost continually diminishing, and hardly ever augmenting.
Such
variations, therefore, tend almost always to diminish the value of a
money
rent.
The
discovery of the mines of America diminished the value of gold and
silver
in Europe. This diminution, it is commonly supposed, though I
apprehend
without any certain proof, is still going on gradually, and is
likely
to continue to do so for a long time. Upon this supposition,
therefore,
such variations are more likely to diminish than to augment the
value of
a money rent, even though it should be stipulated to be paid, not
in such
a quantity of coined money of such a denomination (in so many pounds
sterling,
for example), but in so many ounces, either of pure silver, or of
silver
of a certain standard.
The
rents which have been reserved in corn, have preserved their value much
better
than those which have been reserved in money, even where the
denomination
of the coin has not been altered. By the 18th of Elizabeth, it
was
enacted, that a third of the rent of all college leases should be
reserved
in corn, to be paid either in kind, or according to the current
prices
at the nearest public market. The money arising from this corn rent,
though
originally but a third of the whole, is, in the present times,
according
to Dr. Blackstone, commonly near double of what arises from the
other
two-thirds. The old money rents of colleges must, according to this
account,
have sunk almost to a fourth part of their ancient value, or are
worth
little more than a fourth part of the corn which they were formerly
worth.
But since the reign of Philip and Mary, the denomination of the
English
coin has undergone little or no alteration, and the same number of
pounds,
shillings, and pence, have contained very nearly the same quantity
of pure
silver. This degradation, therefore, in the value of the money rents
of
colleges, has arisen altogether from the degradation in the price of
silver.
When
the degradation in the value of silver is combined with the diminution
of the
quantity of it contained in the coin of the same denomination, the
loss is
frequently still greater. In Scotland, where the denomination of the
coin
has undergone much greater alterations than it ever did in England, and
in
France, where it has undergone still greater than it ever did in
Scotland,
some ancient rents, originally of considerable value, have, in
this
manner, been reduced almost to nothing.
Equal
quantities of labour will, at distant times, be purchased more nearly
with
equal quantities of corn, the subsistence of the labourer, than with
equal
quantities of gold and silver, or, perhaps, of any other commodity.
Equal
quantities of corn, therefore, will, at distant times, be more nearly
of the
same real value, or enable the possessor to purchase or command more
nearly
the same quantity of the labour of other people. They will do this, I
say,
more nearly than equal quantities of almost any other commodity; for
even
equal quantities of corn will not do it exactly. The subsistence of the
labourer,
or the real price of labour, as I shall endeavour to shew
hereafter,
is very different upon different occasions ; more liberal in a
society
advancing to opulence, than in one that is standing still, and in
one
that is standing still, than in one that is going backwards. Every
other
commodity, however, will, at any particular time, purchase a greater
or
smaller quantity of labour, in proportion to the quantity of subsistence
which
it can purchase at that time. A rent, therefore, reserved in corn, is
liable
only to the variations in the quantity of labour which a certain
quantity
of corn can purchase. But a rent reserved in any other commodity is
liable,
not only to the variations in the quantity of labour which any
particular
quantity of corn can purchase, but to the variations in the
quantity
of corn which can be purchased by any particular quantity of that
commodity.
Though
the real value of a corn rent, it is to be observed, however, varies
much
less from century to century than that of a money rent, it varies much
more
from year to year. The money price of labour, as I shall endeavour to
shew
hereafter, does not fluctuate from year to year with the money price of
corn,
but seems to be everywhere accommodated, not to the temporary or
occasional,
but to the average or ordinary price of that necessary of life.
The
average or ordinary price of corn, again is regulated, as I shall
likewise
endeavour to shew hereafter, by the value of silver, by the
richness
or barrenness of the mines which supply the market with that metal,
or by
the quantity of labour which must be employed, and consequently of
corn
which must be consumed, in order to bring any particular quantity of
silver
from the mine to the market. But the value of silver, though it
sometimes
varies greatly from century to century, seldom varies much from
year to
year, but frequently continues the same, or very nearly the same,
for
half a century or a century together. The ordinary or average money
price
of corn, therefore, may, during so long a period, continue the same,
or very
nearly the same, too, and along with it the money price of labour,
provided,
at least, the society continues, in other respects, in the same,
or
nearly in the same, condition. In the mean time, the temporary and
occasional
price of corn may frequently be double one year of what it had
been
the year before, or fluctuate, for example, from five-and-twenty to
fifty
shillings the quarter. But when corn is at the latter price, not only
the
nominal, but the real value of a corn rent, will be double of what it is
when at
the former, or will command double the quantity either of labour, or
of the
greater part of other commodities; the money price of labour, and
along
with it that of most other things, continuing the same during all
these
fluctuations.
Labour,
therefore, it appears evidently, is the only universal, as well as
the
only accurate, measure of value, or the only standard by which we can
compare
the values of different commodities, at all times, and at all
places.
We cannot estimate, it is allowed, the real value of different
commodities
from century to century by the quantities of silver which were
given
for them. We cannot estimate it from year to year by the quantities of
corn.
By the quantities of labour, we can, with the greatest accuracy,
estimate
it, both from century to century, and from year to year. From
century
to century, corn is a better measure than silver, because, from
century
to century, equal quantities of corn will command the same quantity
of
labour more nearly than equal quantities of silver. From year to year, on
the
contrary, silver is a better measure than corn, because equal quantities
of it
will more nearly command the same quantity of labour.
But
though, in establishing perpetual rents, or even in letting very long
leases,
it may be of use to distinguish between real and nominal price; it
is of
none in buying and selling, the more common and ordinary transactions.
of
human life.
At the
same time and place, the real and the nominal price of all
commodities
are exactly in proportion to one another. The more or less money
you get
for any commodity, in the London market, for example, the more or
less
labour it will at that time and place enable you to purchase or
command.
At the same time and place, therefore, money is the exact measure
of the
real exchangeable value of all commodities. It is so, however, at the
same
time and place only.
Though
at distant places there is no regular proportion between the real and
the
money price of commodities, yet the merchant who carries goods from the
one to
the other, has nothing to consider but the money price, or the
difference
between the quantity of silver for which he buys them, and that
for
which he is likely to sell them. Half an ounce of silver at Canton in
China
may command a greater quantity both of labour and of the necessaries
and
conveniencies of life, than an ounce at London. A commodity, therefore,
which
sells for half an ounce of silver at Canton, may there be really
dearer,
of more real importance to the man who possesses it there, than a
commodity
which sells for an ounce at London is to the man who possesses it
at
London. If a London merchant, however, can buy at Canton, for half an
ounce
of silver, a commodity which he can afterwards sell at London for an
ounce,
he gains a hundred per cent. by the bargain, just as much as if an
ounce
of silver was at London exactly of the same value as at Canton. It is
of no importance
to him that half an ounce of silver at Canton would have
given
him the command of more labour, and of a greater quantity of the
necessaries
and conveniencies of life than an ounce can do at London. An
ounce
at London will always give him the command of double the quantity of
all
these, which half an ounce could have done there, and this is precisely
what he
wants.
As it
is the nominal or money price of goods, therefore, which finally
determines
the prudence or imprudence of all purchases and sales, and
thereby
regulates almost the whole business of common life in which price is
concerned,
we cannot wonder that it should have been so much more attended
to than
the real price.
In such
a work as this, however, it may sometimes be of use to compare the
different
real values of a particular commodity at different times and
places,
or the different degrees of power over the labour of other people
which
it may, upon different occasions, have given to those who possessed
it. We
must in this case compare, not so much the different quantities of
silver
for which it was commonly sold, as the different quantities or labour
which
those different quantities of silver could have purchased. But the
current
prices of labour, at distant times and places, can scarce ever be
known
with any degree of exactness. Those of corn, though they have in few
places
been regularly recorded, are in general better known, and have been
more
frequently taken notice of by historians and other writers. We must
generally,
therefore, content ourselves with them, not as being always
exactly
in the same proportion as the current prices of labour, but as being
the
nearest approximation which can commonly be had to that proportion. I
shall
hereafter have occasion to make several comparisons of this kind.
In the
progress of industry, commercial nations have found it convenient to
coin
several different metals into money; gold for larger payments, silver
for
purchases of moderate value, and copper, or some other coarse metal, for
those
of still smaller consideration, They have always, however, considered
one of
those metals as more peculiarly the measure of value than any of the
other
two; and this preference seems generally to have been given to the
metal
which they happen first to make use of as the instrument of commerce.
Having
once begun to use it as their standard, which they must have done
when
they had no other money, they have generally continued to do so even
when
the necessity was not the same.
The
Romans are said to have had nothing but copper money till within five
years
before the first Punic war (Pliny, lib.
xxxiii. cap. 3), when they
first
began to coin silver. Copper, therefore, appears to have continued
always
the measure of value in that republic. At Rome all accounts appear to
have
been kept, and the value of all estates to have been computed, either
in
asses or in sestertii. The as was always the denomination of a copper
coin.
The word sestertius signifies two asses and a half. Though the
sestertius,
therefore, was originally a silver coin, its value was estimated
in
copper. At Rome, one who owed a great deal of money was said to have a
great
deal of other people's copper.
The
northern nations who established themselves upon the ruins of the
Roman
empire, seem to have had silver money from the first beginning of
their
settlements, and not to have known either gold or copper coins for
several
ages thereafter. There were silver coins in England in the time of
the
Saxons ; but there was little gold coined till the time of Edward III
nor any
copper till that of James I. of Great Britain. In England,
therefore,
and for the same reason, I believe, in all other modern nations
of
Europe, all accounts are kept, and the value of all goods and of all
estates
is generally computed, in silver: and when we mean to express the
amount
of a person's fortune, we seldom mention the number of guineas, but
the
number of pounds sterling which we suppose would be given for it.
Originally,
in all countries, I believe, a legal tender of payment could be
made
only in the coin of that metal which was peculiarly considered as the
standard
or measure of value. In England, gold was not considered as a legal
tender
for a long time after it was coined into money. The proportion
between
the values of gold and silver money was not fixed by any public law
or
proclamation, but was left to be settled by the market. If a debtor
offered
payment in gold, the creditor might either reject such payment
altogether,
or accept of it at such a valuation of the gold as he and his
debtor
could agree upon. Copper is not at present a legal tender, except in
the
change of the smaller silver coins.
In this
state of things, the distinction between the metal which was the
standard,
and that which was not the standard, was something more than a
nominal
distinction.
In
process of time, and as people became gradually more familiar with the
use of
the different metals in coin, and consequently better acquainted with
the
proportion between their respective values, it has, in most countries, I
believe,
been found convenient to ascertain this proportion, and to declare
by a
public law, that a guinea, for example, of such a weight and fineness,
should
exchange for one-and-twenty shillings, or be a legal tender for a debt
of that
amount. In this state of things, and during the continuance of any
one
regulated proportion of this kind, the distinction between the metal,
which
is the standard, and that which is not the standard, becomes little
more
than a nominal distinction.
In
consequence of any change, however, in this regulated proportion, this
distinction
becomes, or at least seems to become, something more than
nominal
again. If the regulated value of a guinea, for example, was either
reduced
to twenty, or raised to two-and-twenty shillings, all accounts being
kept,
and almost all obligations for debt being expressed, in silver money,
the
greater part of payments could in either case be made with the same
quantity
of silver money as before; but would require very different
quantities
of gold money ; a greater in the one case, and a smaller in the
other.
Silver would appear to be more invariable in its value than gold.
Silver
would appear to measure the value of gold, and gold would not appear
to
measure the value of silver. The value of gold would seem to depend upon
the
quantity of silver which it would exchange for, and the value of silver
would
not seem to depend upon the quantity of gold which it would exchange
for.
This difference, however, would be altogether owing to the custom of
keeping
accounts, and of expressing the amount of all great and small sums
rather
in silver than in gold money. One of Mr Drummond's notes for
five-and-twenty
or fifty guineas would, after an alteration of this kind, be
still
payable with five-and-twenty or fifty guineas, in the same manner as
before.
It would, after such an alteration, be payable with the same
quantity
of gold as before, but with very different quantities of silver. In
the
payment of such a note, gold would appear to be more invariable in its
value
than silver. Gold would appear to measure the value of silver, and
silver
would not appear to measure the value of gold. If the custom of
keeping
accounts, and of expressing promissory-notes and other obligations
for
money, in this manner should ever become general, gold, and not silver,
would
be considered as the metal which was peculiarly the standard or
measure
of value.
In reality, during the continuance of any one
regulated proportion between the respective
values
of the different metals in coin, the value of the most precious metal regulates
the value
of the
whole coin. Twelve copper pence contain half a pound avoirdupois of copper, of
not the
best
quality, which, before it is coined, is seldom worth seven-pence in silver. But
as, by the
regulation,
twelve such pence are ordered to exchange for a shilling, they are in the
market
considered
as worth a shilling, and a shilling can at any time be had for them. Even
before the
late
reformation of the gold coin of Great Britain, the gold, that part of it at
least which
circulated
in London and its neighbourhood, was in general less degraded below its
standard
weight
than the greater part of the silver. One-and-twenty worn and defaced shillings,
however,
were considered as equivalent to a guinea, which, perhaps, indeed, was worn and
defaced
too, but seldom so much so. The late regulations have brought the gold coin as
near,
perhaps,
to its standard weight as it is possible to bring the current coin of any
nation; and the
order
to receive no gold at the public offices but by weight, is likely to preserve
it so, as long
as that
order is enforced. The silver coin still continues in the same worn and
degraded state as
before
the reformation of the cold coin. In the market, however, one-and-twenty
shillings of
this
degraded silver coin are still considered as worth a guinea of this excellent
gold coin.
The
reformation of the gold coin has evidently raised the value of the silver coin
which can be
exchanged
for it.
In the
English mint, a pound weight of gold is coined into forty-four guineas and a
half, which
at
one-and-twenty shillings the guinea, is equal to forty-six pounds fourteen
shillings and
sixpence.
An ounce of such gold coin, therefore, is worth £ 3:17:10½ in silver. In
England, no
duty or
seignorage is paid upon the coinage, and he who carries a pound weight or an
ounce
weight
of standard gold bullion to the mint, gets back a pound weight or an ounce
weight of
gold in
coin, without any deduction. Three pounds seventeen shillings and tenpence
halfpenny
an
ounce, therefore, is said to be the mint price of gold in England, or the
quantity of gold
coin
which the mint gives in return for standard gold bullion.
Before
the reformation of the gold coin, the price of standard gold bullion in the
market had,
for
many years, been upwards of £3:18s. sometimes £ 3:19s. and very frequently £4
an ounce;
that
sum, it is probable, in the worn and degraded gold coin, seldom containing more
than an
ounce
of standard gold. Since the reformation of the gold coin, the market price of
standard
gold
bullion seldom exceeds £ 3:17:7 an ounce. Before the reformation of the gold
coin, the
market
price was always more or less above the mint price. Since that reformation, the
market
price
has been constantly below the mint price. But that market price is the same
whether it is
paid in
gold or in silver coin. The late reformation of the gold coin, therefore, has
raised not
only
the value of the gold coin, but likewise that of the silver coin in proportion
to gold
bullion,
and probably, too, in proportion to all other commodities ; though the price of
the
greater
part of other commodities being influenced by so many other causes, the rise in
the
value
of either gold or silver coin in proportion to them may not be so distinct and
sensible.
In the
English mint, a pound weight of standard silver bullion is coined into
sixty-two
shillings,
containing, in the same manner, a pound weight of standard silver. Five
shillings
and
twopence an ounce, therefore, is said to be the mint price of silver in
England, or the
quantity
of silver coin which the mint gives in return for standard silver bullion.
Before the
reformation
of the gold coin, the market price of standard silver bullion was, upon
different
occasions,
five shillings and fourpence, five shillings and fivepence, five shillings and
sixpence,
five shillings and sevenpence, and very often five shillings and eightpence an
ounce.
Five
shillings and sevenpence, however, seems to have been the most common price.
Since
the
reformation of the gold coin, the market price of standard silver bullion has
fallen
occasionally
to five shillings and threepence, five shillings and fourpence, and five
shillings
and
fivepence an ounce, which last price it has scarce ever exceeded. Though the
market price
of
silver bullion has fallen considerably since the reformation of the gold coin,
it has not fallen
so low
as the mint price.
In the
proportion between the different metals in the English coin, as copper is rated
very
much
above its real value, so silver is rated somewhat below it. In the market of
Europe, in the
French
coin and in the Dutch coin, an ounce of fine gold exchanges for about fourteen
ounces
of fine
silver. In the English coin, it exchanges for about fifteen ounces, that is,
for more silver
than it
is worth, according to the common estimation of Europe. But as the price of copper
in
bars is
not, even in England, raised by the high price of copper in English coin, so
the price of
silver
in bullion is not sunk by the low rate of silver in English coin. Silver in
bullion still
preserves
its proper proportion to gold, for the same reason that copper in bars
preserves its
proper
proportion to silver.
Upon
the reformation of the silver coin, in the reign of William III., the price of
silver bullion
still
continued to be somewhat above the mint price. Mr Locke imputed this high price
to the
permission
of exporting silver bullion, and to the prohibition of exporting silver coin.
This
permission
of exporting, he said, rendered the demand for silver bullion greater than the
demand
for silver coin. But the number of
people who want silver coin for the common
uses of
buying and selling at home, is surely much greater than that of those who want
silver
bullion
either for the use of exportation or for any other use. There subsists at
present a like
permission
of exporting gold bullion, and a like prohibition of exporting gold coin; and
yet the
price
of gold bullion has fallen below the mint price. But in the English coin,
silver was then,
in the
same manner as now, under-rated in proportion to gold; and the gold coin (which
at that
time,
too, was not supposed to require any reformation) regulated then, as well as
now, the
real
value of the whole coin. As the reformation of the silver coin did not then
reduce the price
of
silver bullion to the mint price, it is not very probable that a like
reformation will do so
now.
Were
the silver coin brought back as near to its standard weight as the gold, a
guinea, it is
probable,
would, according to the present proportion, exchange for more silver in coin
than it
would
purchase in bullion. The silver coin containing its full standard weight, there
would in
this
case, be a profit in melting it down, in order, first to sell the bullion for
gold coin, and
afterwards
to exchange this gold coin for silver coin, to be melted down in the same
manner.
Some
alteration in the present proportion seems to be the only method of preventing
this
inconveniency.
The
inconveniency, perhaps, would be less, if silver was rated in the coin as much
above its
proper
proportion to gold as it is at present rated below it, provided it was at the
same time
enacted,
that silver should not be a legal tender for more than the change of a guinea,
in the
same
manner as copper is not a legal tender for more than the change of a shilling.
No creditor
could,
in this case, be cheated in consequence of the high valuation of silver in coin
; as no
creditor
can at present be cheated in consequence of the high valuation of copper. The
bankers
only
would suffer by this regulation. When a run comes upon them, they sometimes
endeavour
to gain time, by paying in sixpences, and they would be precluded by this
regulation
from this discreditable method of evading immediate payment.They would be
obliged,
in consequence, to keep at all times in their coffers a greater quantity of
cash than at
present
; and though this might, no doubt, be a considerable inconveniency to them, it
would,
at the
same time, be a considerable security to their creditors.
Three
pounds seventeen shillings and tenpence halfpenny (the mint price of gold)
certainly
does
not contain, even in our present excellent gold coin, more than an ounce of
standard
gold,
and it may be thought, therefore, should not purchase more standard bullion.
But gold in
coin is
more convenient than gold in bullion ; and though, in England, the coinage is
free, yet
the
gold which is carried in bullion to the mint, can seldom be returned in coin to
the owner
till
after a delay of several weeks. In the present hurry of the mint, it could not
be returned till
after a
delay of several months. This delay is equivalent to a small duty, and renders
gold in
coin
somewhat more valuable than an equal quantity of gold in bullion. If, in the
English coin,
silver
was rated according to its proper proportion to gold, the price of silver
bullion would
probably
fall below the mint price, even without any reformation of the silver coin ;
the value
even of
the present worn and defaced silver coin being regulated by the value of the
excellent
gold
coin for which it can be changed.
A small
seignorage or duty upon the coinage of both gold and silver, would probably
increase
still
more the superiority of those metals in coin above an equal quantity of either
of them in
bullion. The coinage would, in this case, increase
the value of the metal coined in
proportion
to the extent of this small duty, for the same reason that the fashion
increases the
value
of plate in proportion to the price of that fashion. The superiority of coin
above bullion
would
prevent the melting down of the coin, and would discourage its
exportation. If, upon
any
public exigency, it should become necessary to export the coin, the greater
part of it
would
soon return again, of its own accord. Abroad, it could sell only for its weight
in bullion.
At
home, it would buy more than that weight. There would be a profit, therefore,
in bringing it
home
again. In France, a seignorage of about eight per cent. is imposed upon the
coinage, and
the
French coin, when exported, is said to return home again, of its own accord.
The
occasional fluctuations in the market price of gold and silver bullion arise
from the same
causes
as the like fluctuations in that of all other commodities. The frequent loss of
those
metals
from various accidents by sea and by land, the continual waste of them in
gilding and
plating,
in lace and embroidery, in the wear and tear of coin, and in that of plate,
require, in all
countries
which possess no mines of their own, a continual importation, in order to
repair this
loss and
this waste. The merchant importers,
like all other merchants, we may believe,
endeavour,
as well as they can, to suit their occasional importations to what they judge
is
likely
to be the immediate demand. With all their attention, however, they sometimes
overdo
the
business, and sometimes underdo it. When they import more bullion than is
wanted, rather
than
incur the risk and trouble of exporting it again, they are sometimes willing to
sell a part
of it
for something less than the ordinary or average price. When, on the other hand,
they
import
less than is wanted, they get something more than this price. But when, under
all those
occasional
fluctuations, the market price either of gold or silver bullion continues for
several
years
together steadily and constantly, either more or less above, or more or less
below the
mint
price, we may be assured that this steady and constant, either superiority or
inferiority of
price,
is the effect of something in the state of the coin, which, at that time, renders
a certain
quantity
of coin either of more value or of less value than the precise quantity of
bullion
which
it ought to contain. The constancy and steadiness of the effect supposes a
proportionable
constancy and steadiness in the cause.
The money
of any particular country is, at any particular time and place, more or less an
accurate
measure or value, according as the current coin is more or less exactly
agreeable to
its
standard, or contains more or less exactly the precise quantity of pure gold or
pure silver
which
it ought to contain. If in England, for example, forty-four guineas and a half
contained
exactly
a pound weight of standard gold, or eleven ounces of fine gold, and one ounce
of
alloy,
the gold coin of England would be as accurate a measure of the actual value of
goods at
any
particular time and place as the nature of the thing would admit. But if, by
rubbing and
wearing,
forty-four guineas and a half generally contain less than a pound weight of
standard
gold,
the diminution, however, being greater in some pieces than in others, the
measure of
value
comes to be liable to the same sort of uncertainty to which all other weights
and
measures
are commonly exposed. As it rarely happens that these are exactly agreeable to
their
standard,
the merchant adjusts the price of his goods as well as he can, not to what
those
weights
and measures ought to be, but to what, upon an average, he finds, by
experience, they
actually
are. In consequence of a like disorder in the coin, the price of goods comes,
in the
same
manner, to be adjusted, not to the quantity of pure gold or silver which the
coin ought to
contain,
but to that which, upon an average, it is found, by experience, it actually
does
contain.
By the
money price of goods, it is to be observed, I understand always the quantity of
pure
gold or
silver for which they are sold, without any regard to the denomination of the
coin. Six
shillings
and eight pence, for example, in the time of Edward I., I consider as the same
money
price
with a pound sterling in the present times, because it contained, as nearly as
we can
judge,
the same quantity of pure silver.
CHAPTER VI.
OF THE
COMPONENT PART OF THE PRICE OF COMMODITIES.
In that
early and rude state of society which precedes both the accumulation
of
stock and the appropriation of land, the proportion between the
quantities
of labour necessary for acquiring different objects, seems to be
the
only circumstance which can afford any rule for exchanging them for one
another.
If among a nation of hunters, for example, it usually costs twice
the
labour to kill a beaver which it does to kill a deer, one beaver should
naturally
exchange for or be worth two deer. It is natural that what is
usually
the produce of two days or two hours labour, should be worth double
of what
is usually the produce of one day's or one hour's labour.
If the
one species of labour should be more severe than the other, some
allowance
will naturally be made for this superior hardship; and the produce
of one
hour's labour in the one way may frequently exchange for that of two
hour's
labour in the other.
Or if
the one species of labour requires an uncommon degree of dexterity
and
ingenuity, the esteem which men have for such talents, will naturally
give a
value to their produce, superior to what would be due to the time
employed
about it. Such talents can seldom be acquired but in consequence of
long
application, and the superior value of their produce may frequently be
no more
than a reasonable compensation for the time and labour which must be
spent
in acquiring them. In the advanced state of society, allowances of
this
kind, for superior hardship and superior skill, are commonly made in
the
wages of labour ; and something of the same kind must probably have
taken
place in its earliest and rudest period.
In this
state of things, the whole produce of labour belongs to the
labourer;
and the quantity of labour commonly employed in acquiring or
producing
any commodity, is the only circumstance which can regulate the
quantity
of labour which it ought commonly to purchase, command, or exchange
for.
As soon
as stock has accumulated in the hands of particular persons, some of
them
will naturally employ it in setting to work industrious people, whom
they
will supply with materials and subsistence, in order to make a profit
by the
sale of their work, or by what their labour adds to the value of the
materials.
In exchanging the complete manufacture either for money, for
labour,
or for other goods, over and above what may be sufficient to pay the
price
of the materials, and the wages of the workmen, something must be given
for the
profits of the undertaker of the work, who hazards his stock in this
adventure.
The value which the workmen add to the materials, therefore,
resolves
itself in this case into two parts, of which the one pays their
wages,
the other the profits of their employer upon the whole stock of
materials
and wages which he advanced. He could have no interest to employ
them,
unless he expected from the sale of their work something more than
what
was sufficient to replace his stock to him ; and he could have no
interest
to employ a great stock rather than a small one, unless his profits
were to
bear some proportion to the extent of his stock.
The
profits of stock, it may perhaps be thought, are only a different name
for the
wages of a particular sort of labour, the labour of inspection and
direction.
They are, however, altogether different, are regulated by quite
different
principles, and bear no proportion to the quantity, the hardship,
or the
ingenuity of this supposed labour of inspection and direction. They
are
regulated altogether by the value of the stock employed, and are greater
or
smaller in proportion to the extent of this stock. Let us suppose, for
example,
that in some particular place, where the common annual profits of
manufacturing
stock are ten per cent. there are two different manufactures,
in each
of which twenty workmen are employed, at the rate of fifteen pounds
a year
each, or at the expense of three hundred a-year in each manufactory.
Let us
suppose, too, that the coarse materials annually wrought up in the
one
cost only seven hundred pounds, while the finer materials in the other
cost
seven thousand. The capital annually employed in the one will, in this
case,
amount only to one thousand pounds; whereas that employed in the other
will
amount to seven thousand three hundred pounds. At the rate of ten per
cent.
therefore, the undertaker of the one will expect a yearly profit of
about
one hundred pounds only; while that of the other will expect about
seven
hundred and thirty pounds. But though their profits are so very
different,
their labour of inspection and direction may be either altogether
or very
nearly the same. In many great works, almost the whole labour of
this
kind is committed to some principal clerk. His wages properly express
the
value of this labour of inspection and direction. Though in settling
them some
regard is had commonly, not only to his labour and skill, but to
the
trust which is reposed in him, yet they never bear any regular
proportion
to the capital of which he oversees the management ; and the
owner
of this capital, though he is thus discharged of almost all labour,
still
expects that his profit should bear a regular proportion to his
capital.
In the price of commodities, therefore, the profits of stock
constitute
a component part altogether different from the wages of labour, and
regulated
by quite different principles.
In this
state of things, the whole produce of labour does not always belong
to the
labourer. He must in most cases share it with the owner of the stock
which
employs him. Neither is the quantity of labour commonly employed in
acquiring
or producing any commodity, the only circumstance which can
regulate
the quantity which it ought commonly to purchase, command or
exchange
for. An additional quantity, it is evident, must be due for the
profits
of the stock which advanced the wages and furnished the materials of
that
labour.
As soon
as the land of any country has all become private property, the
landlords,
like all other men, love to reap where they never sowed, and
demand
a rent even for its natural produce. The wood of the forest, the
grass
of the field, and all the natural fruits of the earth, which, when
land
was in common, cost the labourer only the trouble of gathering them,
come,
even to him, to have an additional price fixed upon them. He must then
pay for
the licence to gather them, and must give up to the landlord a
portion
of what his labour either collects or produces. This portion, or,
what
comes to the same thing, the price of this portion, constitutes the
rent of
land, and in the price of the greater part of commodities, makes a
third
component part.
The
real value of all the different component parts of price, it must be
observed,
is measured by the quantity of labour which they can, each of
them,
purchase or command. Labour measures the value, not only of that part
of
price which resolves itself into labour, but of that which resolves
itself
into rent, and of that which resolves itself into profit.
In
every society, the price of every commodity finally resolves itself into
some one
or other, or all of those three parts ; and in every improved
society,
all the three enter, more or less, as component parts, into the
price
of the far greater part of commodities.
In the
price of corn, for example, one part pays the rent of the landlord,
another
pays the wages or maintenance of the labourers and labouring cattle
employed
in producing it, and the third pays the profit of the farmer. These
three
parts seem either immediately or ultimately to make up the whole price
of
corn. A fourth part, it may perhaps be thought is necessary for replacing
the
stock of the farmer, or for compensating the wear and tear of his
labouring
cattle, and other instruments of husbandry. But it must be
considered,
that the price of any instrument of husbandry, such as a
labouring
horse, is itself made up of the same time parts ; the rent of the
land
upon which he is reared, the labour of tending and rearing him, and the
profits
of the farmer, who advances both the rent of this land, and the
wages
of this labour. Though the price of the corn, therefore, may pay the
price
as well as the maintenance of the horse, the whole price still
resolves
itself, either immediately or ultimately, into the same three parts
of
rent, labour, and profit.
In the
price of flour or meal, we must add to the price of the corn, the
profits
of the miller, and the wages of his servants ; in the price of
bread,
the profits of the baker, and the wages of his servants; and in the
price
of both, the labour of transporting the corn from the house of the
farmer
to that of the miller, and from that of the miller to that of the
baker,
together with the profits of those who advance the wages of that
labour.
The
price of flax resolves itself into the same three parts as that of corn.
In the
price of linen we must add to this price the wages of the
flax-dresser,
of the spinner, of the weaver, of the bleacher, etc. together
with
the profits of their respective employers.
As any
particular commodity comes to be more manufactured, that part of the
price
which resolves itself into wages and profit, comes to be greater in
proportion
to that which resolves itself into rent. In the progress of the
manufacture,
not only the number of profits increase, but every subsequent
profit
is greater than the foregoing ; because the capital from which it is
derived
must always be greater. The capital which employs the weavers, for
example,
must be greater than that which employs the spinners; because it
not
only replaces that capital with its profits, but pays, besides, the
wages
of the weavers : and the profits must always bear some proportion to
the
capital.
In the
most improved societies, however, there are always a few commodities
of
which the price resolves itself into two parts only the wages of labour,
and the
profits of stock ; and a still smaller number, in which it consists
altogether
in the wages of labour. In the price of sea-fish, for example,
one
part pays the labour of the fisherman, and the other the profits of the
capital
employed in the fishery. Rent very seldom makes any part of it,
though
it does sometimes, as I shall shew hereafter. It is otherwise, at
least
through the greater part of Europe, in river fisheries. A salmon
fishery
pays a rent ; and rent, though it cannot well be called the rent of
land,
makes a part of the price of a salmon, as well as wares and profit. In
some
parts of Scotland, a few poor people make a trade of gathering, along
the
sea-shore, those little variegated stones commonly known by the name of
Scotch
pebbles. The price which is paid to them by the stone-cutter, is
altogether
the wages of their labour ; neither rent nor profit makes an part
of it.
But the
whole price of any commodity must still finally resolve itself into some one or
other
or all
of those three parts; as whatever part of it remains after paying the rent of
the land, and
the
price of the whole labour employed in raising, manufacturing, and bringing it
to market,
must
necessarily be profit to somebody.
As the
price or exchangeable value of every particular commodity, taken
separately,
resolves itself into some one or other, or all of those three
parts ;
so that of all the commodities which compose the whole annual
produce
of the labour of every country, taken complexly, must resolve itself
into
the same three parts, and be parcelled out among different inhabitants
of the
country, either as the wages of their labour, the profits of their
stock,
or the rent of their land. The whole of what is annually either
collected
or produced by the labour of every society, or, what comes to the
same
thing, the whole price of it, is in this manner originally distributed
among
some of its different members. Wages, profit, and rent, are the three
original
sources of all revenue, as well as of all exchangeable value. All
other
revenue is ultimately derived from some one or other of these.
Whoever
derives his revenue from a fund which is his own, must draw it
either
from his labour, from his stock, or from his land. The revenue
derived
from labour is called wages; that derived from stock, by the person
who
manages or employs it, is called profit; that derived from it by the
person
who does not employ it himself, but lends it to another, is called
the
interest or the use of money. It is the compensation which the borrower
pays to
the lender, for the profit which he has an opportunity of making by
the use
of the money. Part of that profit naturally belongs to the borrower,
who
runs the risk and takes the trouble of employing it, and part to the
lender,
who affords him the opportunity of making this profit. The interest
of
money is always a derivative revenue, which, if it is not paid from the
profit
which is made by the use of the money, must be paid from some other
source
of revenue, unless perhaps the borrower is a spendthrift, who
contracts
a second debt in order to pay the interest of the first. The
revenue
which proceeds altogether from land, is called rent, and belongs to
the
landlord. The revenue of the farmer is derived partly from his labour,
and
partly from his stock. To him, land is only the instrument which enables
him to
earn the wages of this labour, and to make the profits of this stock.
All
taxes, and all the revenue which is founded upon them, all salaries,
pensions,
and annuities of every kind, are ultimately derived from some one
or
other of those three original sources of revenue, and are paid either
immediately
or mediately from the wages of labour, the profits of stock, or
the
rent of land.
When
those three different sorts of revenue belong to different persons,
they
are readily distinguished; but when they belong to the same, they are
sometimes
confounded with one another, at least in common language.
A
gentleman who farms a part of his own estate, after paying the expense of
cultivation,
should gain both the rent of the landlord and the profit of the
farmer.
He is apt to denominate, however, his whole gain, profit, and thus
confounds
rent with profit, at least in common language. The greater part of
our
North American and West Indian planters are in this situation. They
farm,
the greater part of them, their own estates : and accordingly we
seldom
hear of the rent of a plantation, but frequently of its profit.
Common
farmers seldom employ any overseer to direct the general operations
of the
farm. They generally, too, work a good deal with their own hands, as
ploughmen,
harrowers, etc. What remains of the crop, after paying the rent,
therefore,
should not only replace to them their stock employed in
cultivation,
together with its ordinary profits, but pay them the wages
which
are due to them, both as labourers and overseers. Whatever remains,
however,
after paying the rent and keeping up the stock, is called profit.
But
wages evidently make a part of it. The farmer, by saving these wages,
must
necessarily gain them. Wages, therefore, are in this case confounded
with
profit.
An
independent manufacturer, who has stock enough both to purchase
materials,
and to maintain himself till he can carry his work to market,
should
gain both the wages of a journeyman who works under a master, and the
profit
which that master makes by the sale of that journeyman's work. His
whole
gains, however, are commonly called profit, and wages are, in this
case,
too, confounded with profit.
A
gardener who cultivates his own garden with his own hands, unites in his
own
person the three different characters, of landlord, farmer, and
labourer.
His produce, therefore, should pay him the rent of the first, the
profit
of the second, and the wages of the third. The whole, however, is
commonly
considered as the earnings of his labour. Both rent and profit are,
in this
case, confounded with wages.
As in a
civilized country there are but few commodities of which the
exchangeable
value arises from labour only, rent and profit contributing
largely
to that of the far greater part of them, so the annual produce of
its
labour will always be sufficient to purchase or command a much greater
quantity
of labour than what was employed in raising, preparing, and
bringing
that produce to market. If the society were annually to employ all
the
labour which it can annually purchase, as the quantity of labour would
increase
greatly every year, so the produce of every succeeding year would
be of
vastly greater value than that of the foregoing. But there is no
country
in which the whole annual produce is employed in maintaining the
industrious.
The idle everywhere consume a great part of it; and, according
to the
different proportions in which it is annually divided between those
two
different orders of people, its ordinary or average value must either
annually
increase or diminish, or continue the same from one year to
another.
CHAPTER VII.
OF THE
NATURAL AND MARKET PRICE OF COMMODITIES.
There
is in every society or neighbourhood an ordinary or average rate, both
of
wages and profit, in every different employment of labour and stock. This
rate is
naturally regulated, as I shall shew hereafter, partly by the
general
circumstances of the society, their riches or poverty, their
advancing,
stationary, or declining condition, and partly by the particular
nature
of each employment.
There
is likewise in every society or neighbourhood an ordinary or average
rate of
rent, which is regulated, too, as I shall shew hereafter, partly by
the
general circumstances of the society or neighbourhood in which the land
is
situated, and partly by the natural or improved fertility of the land.
These
ordinary or average rates may be called the natural rates of wages,
profit
and rent, at the time and place in which they commonly prevail.
When
the price of any commodity is neither more nor less than what is
sufficient
to pay the rent of the land, the wages of the labour, and the
profits
of the stock employed in raising, preparing, and bringing it to
market,
according to their natural rates, the commodity is then sold for
what
may be called its natural price.
The
commodity is then sold precisely for what it is worth, or for what it
really
costs the person who brings it to market; for though, in common
language,
what is called the prime cost of any commodity does not comprehend
the
profit of the person who is to sell it again, yet, if he sells it at a
price
which does not allow him the ordinary rate of profit in his
neighbourhood,
he is evidently a loser by the trade; since, by employing his
stock
in some other way, he might have made that profit. His profit,
besides,
is his revenue, the proper fund of his subsistence. As, while he is
preparing
and bringing the goods to market, he advances to his workmen their
wages,
or their subsistence ; so he advances to himself, in the same manner,
his own
subsistence, which is generally suitable to the profit which he may
reasonably
expect from the sale of his goods. Unless they yield him this
profit,
therefore, they do not repay him what they may very properly be said
to have
really cost him.
Though
the price, therefore, which leaves him this profit, is not always the
lowest
at which a dealer may sometimes sell his goods, it is the lowest at
which
he is likely to sell them for any considerable time; at least where
there
is perfect liberty, or where he may change his trade as often as he
pleases.
The
actual price at which any commodity is commonly sold, is called its
market
price. It may either be above, or below, or exactly the same with its
natural
price.
The
market price of every particular commodity is regulated by the
proportion
between the quantity which is actually brought to market, and the
demand
of those who are willing to pay the natural price of the commodity,
or the
whole value of the rent, labour, and profit, which must be paid in
order
to bring it thither. Such people may be called the effectual
demanders,
and their demand the effectual demand; since it maybe sufficient
to
effectuate the bringing of the commodity to market. It is different from
the
absolute demand. A very poor man may be said, in some sense, to have a
demand
for a coach and six; he might like to have it; but his demand is not
an
effectual demand, as the commodity can never be brought to market in
order
to satisfy it.
When
the quantity of any commodity which is brought to market falls short of
the
effectual demand, all those who are willing to pay the whole value of
the
rent, wages, and profit, which must be paid in order to bring it
thither,
cannot be supplied with the quantity which they want. Rather than
want it
altogether, some of them will be willing to give more. A competition
will
immediately begin among them, and the market price will rise more or
less
above the natural price, according as either the greatness of the
deficiency,
or the wealth and wanton luxury of the competitors, happen to
animate
more or less the eagerness of the competition. Among competitors of
equal
wealth and luxury, the same deficiency will generally occasion a more
or less
eager competition, according as the acquisition of the commodity
happens
to be of more or less importance to them. Hence the exorbitant price
of the
necessaries of life during the blockade of a town, or in a famine.
When
the quantity brought to market exceeds the effectual demand, it cannot
be all
sold to those who are willing to pay the whole value of the rent,
wages,
and profit, which must be paid in order to bring it thither. Some
part
must be sold to those who are willing to pay less, and the low price
which
they give for it must reduce the price of the whole. The market price
will
sink more or less below the natural price, according as the greatness
of the
excess increases more or less the competition of the sellers, or
according
as it happens to be more or less important to them to get
immediately
rid of the commodity. The same excess in the importation of
perishable,
will occasion a much greater competition than in that of durable
commodities;
in the importation of oranges, for example, than in that of old
iron.
When
the quantity brought to market is just sufficient to supply the
effectual
demand, and no more, the market price naturally comes to be either
exactly,
or as nearly as can be judged of, the same with the natural price.
The
whole quantity upon hand can be disposed of for this price, and can not
be
disposed of for more. The competition of the different dealers obliges
them
all to accept of this price, but does not oblige them to accept of
less.
The
quantity of every commodity brought to market naturally suits itself to
the effectual
demand. It is the interest of all those who employ their land,
labour,
or stock, in bringing any commodity to market, that the quantity
never
should exceed the effectual demand ; and it is the interest of all
other
people that it never should fall short of that demand.
If at
any time it exceeds the effectual demand, some of the component parts
of its
price must be paid below their natural rate. If it is rent, the
interest
of the landlords will immediately prompt them to withdraw a part of
their
land; and if it is wages or profit, the interest of the labourers in
the one
case, and of their employers in the other, will prompt them to
withdraw
a part of their labour or stock, from this employment. The quantity
brought
to market will soon be no more than sufficient to supply the
effectual
demand. All the different parts of its price will rise to their
natural
rate, and the whole price to its natural price.
If, on
the contrary, the quantity brought to market should at any time fall
short of
the effectual demand, some of the component parts of its price must
rise
above their natural rate. If it is rent, the interest of all other
landlords
will naturally prompt them to prepare more land for the raising of
this
commodity ; if it is wages or profit, the interest of all other
labourers
and dealers will soon prompt them to employ more labour and stock
in
preparing and bringing it to market. The quantity brought thither will
soon be
sufficient to supply the effectual demand. All the different parts
of its
price will soon sink to their natural rate, and the whole price to
its
natural price.
The
natural price, therefore, is, as it were, the central price, to which
the
prices of all commodities are continually gravitating. Different
accidents
may sometimes keep them suspended a good deal above it, and
sometimes
force them down even somewhat below it. But whatever may be the
obstacles
which hinder them from settling in this centre of repose and
continuance,
they are constantly tending towards it.
The
whole quantity of industry annually employed in order to bring any
commodity
to market, naturally suits itself in this manner to the effectual
demand.
It naturally aims at bringing always that precise quantity thither
which
may be sufficient to supply, and no more than supply, that demand.
But, in
some employments, the same quantity of industry will, in different
years,
produce very different quantities of commodities ; while, in others,
it will
produce always the same, or very nearly the same. The same number of
labourers
in husbandry will, in different years, produce very different
quantities
of corn, wine, oil, hops, etc. But the same number of spinners or
weavers
will every year produce the same, or very nearly the same, quantity
of
linen and woollen cloth. It is only the average produce of the one
species
of industry which can be suited, in any respect, to the effectual
demand
; and as its actual produce is frequently much greater, and
frequently
much less, than its average produce, the quantity of the
commodities
brought to market will sometimes exceed a good deal, and
sometimes
fall short a good deal, of the effectual demand. Even though that
demand,
therefore, should continue always the same, their market price will
be
liable to great fluctuations, will sometimes fall a good deal below, and
sometimes
rise a good deal above, their natural price. In the other species
of
industry, the produce of equal quantities of labour being always the
same,
or very nearly the same, it can be more exactly suited to the
effectual
demand. While that demand continues the same, therefore, the
market
price of the commodities is likely to do so too, and to be either
altogether,
or as nearly as can be judged of, the same with the natural
price.
That the price of linen and woollen cloth is liable neither to such
frequent,
nor to such great variations, as the price of corn, every man's
experience
will inform him. The price of the one species of commodities
varies
only with the variations in the demand; that of the other varies not
only
with the variations in the demand, but with the much greater, and more
frequent,
variations in the quantity of what is brought to market, in order
to
supply that demand.
The
occasional and temporary fluctuations in the market price of any
commodity
fall chiefly upon those parts of its price which resolve
themselves
into wages and profit. That part which resolves itself into rent
is less
affected by them. A rent certain in money is not in the least
affected
by them, either in its rate or in its value. A rent which consists
either
in a certain proportion, or in a certain quantity, of the rude
produce,
is no doubt affected in its yearly value by all the occasional and
temporary
fluctuations in the market price of that rude produce; but it is
seldom
affected by them in its yearly rate. In settling the terms of the
lease,
the landlord and farmer endeavour, according to their best judgment,
to
adjust that rate, not to the temporary and occasional, but to the average
and
ordinary price of the produce.
Such
fluctuations affect both the value and the rate, either of wages or of
profit,
according as the market happens to be either overstocked or
understocked
with commodities or with labour, with work done, or with work
to be
done. A public mourning raises the price of black cloth ( with which
the
market is almost always understocked upon such occasions), and augments
the
profits of the merchants who possess any considerable quantity of it. It
has no
effect upon the wages of the weavers. The market is understocked with
commodities,
not with labour, with work done, not with work to be done. It
raises
the wages of journeymen tailors. The market is here understocked with
labour.
There is an effectual demand for more labour, for more work to be
done,
than can be had. It sinks the price of coloured silks and cloths, and
thereby
reduces the profits of the merchants who have any considerable
quantity
of them upon hand. It sinks, too, the wages of the workmen employed
in
preparing such commodities, for which all demand is stopped for six
months,
perhaps for a twelvemonth. The market is here overstocked both with
commodities
and with labour.
But
though the market price of every particular commodity is in this manner
continually
gravitating, if one may say so, towards the natural price; yet
sometimes
particular accidents, sometimes natural causes, and sometimes
particular
regulations of policy, may, in many commodities, keep up the
market
price, for a long time together, a good deal above the natural price.
When,
by an increase in the effectual demand, the market price of some
particular
commodity happens to rise a good deal above the natural price,
those
who employ their stocks in supplying that market, are generally
careful
to conceal this change. If it was commonly known, their great profit
would
tempt so many new rivals to employ their stocks in the same way, that,
the
effectual demand being fully supplied, the market price would soon be
reduced
to the natural price, and, perhaps, for some time even below it. If
the
market is at a great distance from the residence of those who supply it,
they
may sometimes be able to keep the secret for several years together,
and may
so long enjoy their extraordinary profits without any new rivals.
Secrets
of this kind, however, it must be acknowledged, can seldom be long
kept;
and the extraordinary profit can last very little longer than they are
kept.
Secrets
in manufactures are capable of being longer kept than secrets in
trade.
A dyer who has found the means of producing a particular colour with
materials
which cost only half the price of those commonly made use of, may,
with
good management, enjoy the advantage of his discovery as long as he
lives,
and even leave it as a legacy to his posterity. His extraordinary
gains
arise from the high price which is paid for his private labour. They
properly
consist in the high wages of that labour. But as they are repeated
upon
every part of his stock, and as their whole amount bears, upon that
account,
a regular proportion to it, they are commonly considered as
extraordinary
profits of stock.
Such
enhancements of the market price are evidently the effects of
particular
accidents, of which, however, the operation may sometimes last
for
many years together.
Some
natural productions require such a singularity of soil and situation,
that
all the land in a great country, which is fit for producing them, may
not be
sufficient to supply the effectual demand. The whole quantity brought
to
market, therefore, may be disposed of to those who are willing to give
more
than what is sufficient to pay the rent of the land which produced
them,
together with the wages of the labour and the profits of the stock
which
were employed in preparing and bringing them to market, according to
their
natural rates. Such commodities may continue for whole centuries
together
to be sold at this high price ; and that part of it which resolves
itself
into the rent of land, is in this case the part which is generally
paid
above its natural rate. The rent of the land which affords such
singular
and esteemed productions, like the rent of some vineyards in France
of a
peculiarly happy soil and situation, bears no regular proportion to the
rent of
other equally fertile and equally well cultivated land in its
neighbourhood.
The wages of the labour, and the profits of the stock
employed
in bringing such commodities to market, on the contrary, are seldom
out of
their natural proportion to those of the other employments of labour
and
stock in their neighbourhood.
Such
enhancements of the market price are evidently the effect of natural
causes,
which may hinder the effectual demand from ever being fully
supplied,
and which may continue, therefore, to operate for ever.
A
monopoly granted either to an individual or to a trading company, has the
same
effect as a secret in trade or manufactures. The monopolists, by
keeping
the market constantly understocked by never fully supplying the
effectual
demand, sell their commodities much above the natural price, and
raise
their emoluments. whether they consist in wages or profit, greatly
above
their natural rate.
The
price of monopoly is upon every occasion the highest which can be got.
The
natural price, or the price of free competition, on the contrary, is the
lowest
which can be taken, not upon every occasion indeed, but for any
considerable
time together. The one is upon every occasion the highest which
can be
squeezed out of the buyers, or which it is supposed they will
consent
to give; the other is the lowest which the sellers can commonly
afford
to take, and at the same time continue their business.
The
exclusive privileges of corporations, statutes of apprenticeship, and
all
those laws which restrain in particular employments, the competition to
a
smaller number than might otherwise go into them, have the same tendency,
though
in a less degree. They are a sort of enlarged monopolies, and may
frequently,
for ages together, and in whole classes of employments, keep up
the
market price of particular commodities above the natural price, and
maintain
both the wages of the labour and the profits of the stock employed
about
them somewhat above their natural rate.
Such
enhancements of the market price may last as long as the regulations of
policy
which give occasion to them.
The
market price of any particular commodity, though it may continue long
above,
can seldom continue long below, its natural price. Whatever part of
it was
paid below the natural rate, the persons whose interest it affected
would
immediately feel the loss, and would immediately withdraw either so
much
land or no much labour, or so much stock, from being employed about it,
that
the quantity brought to market would soon be no more than sufficient to
supply
the effectual demand. Its market price, therefore, would soon rise to
the
natural price; this at least would be the case where there was perfect
liberty.
The
same statutes of apprenticeship and other corporation laws, indeed,
which,
when a manufacture is in prosperity, enable the workman to raise his
wages a
good deal above their natural rate, sometimes oblige him, when it
decays,
to let them down a good deal below it. As in the one case they
exclude
many people from his employment, so in the other they exclude him
from
many employments. The effect of such regulations, however, is not near
so
durable in sinking the workman's wages below, as in raising them above
their
natural rate. Their operation in the one way may endure for many
centuries,
but in the other it can last no longer than the lives of some of
the
workmen who were bred to the business in the time of its prosperity.
When
they are gone, the number of those who are afterwards educated to the
trade
will naturally suit itself to the effectual demand. The policy must be
as
violent as that of Indostan or ancient Egypt (where every man was bound
by a
principle of religion to follow the occupation of his father, and was
supposed
to commit the most horrid sacrilege if he changed it for another),
which
can in any particular employment, and for several generations
together,
sink either the wages of labour or the profits of stock below
their
natural rate.
This is
all that I think necessary to be observed at present concerning the
deviations,
whether occasional or permanent, of the market price of
commodities
from the natural price.
The
natural price itself varies with the natural rate of each of its
component
parts, of wages, profit, and rent; and in every society this rate
varies
according to their circumstances, according to their riches or
poverty,
their advancing, stationary, or declining condition. I shall, in
the
four following chapters, endeavour to explain, as fully and distinctly
as I
can, the causes of those different variations.
First,
I shall endeavour to explain what are the circumstances which
naturally
determine the rate of wages, and in what manner those
circumstances
are affected by the riches or poverty, by the advancing,
stationary,
or declining state of the society.
Secondly,
I shall endeavour to shew what are the circumstances which
naturally
determine the rate of profit ; and in what manner, too, those
circumstances
are affected by the like variations in the state of the
society.
Though
pecuniary wages and profit are very different in the different
employments
of labour and stock ; yet a certain proportion seems commonly to
take
place between both the pecuniary wages in all the different employments
of
labour, and the pecuniary profits in all the different employments of
stock.
This proportion, it will appear hereafter, depends partly upon the
nature
of the different employments, and partly upon the different laws and
policy
of the society in which they are carried on. But though in many
respects
dependent upon the laws and policy, this proportion seems to be
little
affected by the riches or poverty of that society, by its advancing,
stationary,
or declining condition, but to remain the same, or very nearly
the
same, in all those different states. I shall, in the third place,
endeavour
to explain all the different circumstances which regulate this
proportion.
In the
fourth and last place, I shall endeavour to shew what are the
circumstances
which regulate the rent of land, and which either raise or
lower
the real price of all the different substances which it produces.
CHAPTER VIII.
OF THE
WAGES OF LABOUR.
The
produce of labour constitutes the natural recompence or wages of labour.
In that
original state of things which precedes both the appropriation of
land
and the accumulation of stock, the whole produce of labour belongs to
the
labourer. He has neither landlord nor master to share with him.
Had
this state continued, the wages of labour would have augmented with all
those
improvements in its productive powers, to which the division of labour
gives
occasion. All things would gradually have become cheaper. They would
have
been produced by a smaller quantity of labour ; and as the commodities
produced
by equal quantities of labour would naturally in this state of
things
be exchanged for one another, they would have been purchased likewise
with
the produce of a smaller quantity.
But
though all things would have become cheaper in reality, in appearance
many
things might have become dearer, than before, or have been exchanged
for a
greater quantity of other goods. Let us suppose, for example, that in
the
greater part of employments the productive powers of labour had been
improved
to tenfold, or that a day's labour could produce ten times the
quantity
of work which it had done originally ; but that in a particular
employment
they had been improved only to double, or that a day's labour
could
produce only twice the quantity of work which it had done before. In
exchanging
the produce of a day's labour in the greater part of employments
for
that of a day's labour in this particular one, ten times the original
quantity
of work in them would purchase only twice the original quantity in
it. Any
particular quantity in it, therefore, a pound weight, for example,
would
appear to be five times dearer than before. In reality, however, it
would
be twice as cheap. Though it required five times the quantity of other
goods
to purchase it, it would require only half the quantity of labour
either
to purchase or to produce it. The acquisition, therefore, would be
twice
as easy as before.
But
this original state of things, in which the labourer enjoyed the whole
produce
of his own labour, could not last beyond the first introduction of
the
appropriation of land and the accumulation of stock. It was at an end,
therefore,
long before the most considerable improvements were made in the
productive
powers of labour ; and it would be to no purpose to trace further
what
might have been its effects upon the recompence or wages of labour.
As soon
as land becomes private property, the landlord demands a share of
almost
all the produce which the labourer can either raise or collect from
it. His
rent makes the first deduction from the produce of the labour which
is
employed upon land.
It
seldom happens that the person who tills the ground has wherewithal to
maintain
himself till he reaps the harvest. His maintenance is generally
advanced
to him from the stock of a master, the farmer who employs him, and
who
would have no interest to employ him, unless he was to share in the
produce
of his labour, or unless his stock was to be replaced to him with a
profit.
This profit makes a second deduction from the produce of the labour
which
is employed upon land.
The
produce of almost all other labour is liable to the like deduction of
profit.
In all arts and manufactures, the greater part of the workmen stand
in need
of a master, to advance them the materials of their work, and their
wages
and maintenance, till it be completed. He shares in the produce of
their
labour, or in the value which it adds to the materials upon which it
is
bestowed; and in this share consists his profit.
It
sometimes happens, indeed, that a single independent workman has stock
sufficient
both to purchase the materials of his work, and to maintain
himself
till it be completed. He is both master and workman, and enjoys the
whole
produce of his own labour, or the whole value which it adds to the
materials
upon which it is bestowed. It includes what are usually two
distinct
revenues, belonging to two distinct persons, the profits of stock,
and the
wages of labour.
Such
cases, however, are not very frequent; and in every part of Europe
twenty
workmen serve under a master for one that is independent, and the
wages
of labour are everywhere understood to be, what they usually are, when
the
labourer is one person, and the owner of the stock which employs him
another.
What
are the common wages of labour, depends everywhere upon the contract
usually
made between those two parties, whose interests are by no means the
same.
The workmen desire to get as much, the masters to give as little, as
possible.
The former are disposed to combine in order to raise, the latter
in
order to lower, the wages of labour.
It is
not, however, difficult to foresee which of the two parties must, upon
all
ordinary occasions, have the advantage in the dispute, and force the
other
into a compliance with their terms. The masters, being fewer in
number,
can combine much more easily: and the law, besides, authorises, or
at
least does not prohibit, their combinations, while it prohibits those of
the
workmen. We have no acts of parliament against combining to lower the
price
of work, but many against combining to raise it. In all such disputes,
the
masters can hold out much longer. A landlord, a farmer, a master
manufacturer,
or merchant, though they did not employ a single workman,
could
generally live a year or two upon the stocks, which they have already
acquired.
Many workmen could not subsist a week, few could subsist a month,
and
scarce any a year, without employment. In the long run, the workman may
be as
necessary to his master as his master is to him ; but the necessity is
not so
immediate.
We
rarely hear, it has been said, of the combinations of masters, though
frequently
of those of workmen. But whoever imagines, upon this account,
that
masters rarely combine, is as ignorant of the world as of the subject.
Masters
are always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but constant and
uniform,
combination, not to raise the wages of labour above their actual
rate.
To violate this combination is everywhere a most unpopular action, and
a sort
of reproach to a master among his neighbours and equals. We seldom,
indeed,
hear of this combination, because it is the usual, and, one may say,
the
natural state of things, which nobody ever hears of. Masters, too,
sometimes
enter into particular combinations to sink the wages of labour
even
below this rate. These are always conducted with the utmost silence and
secrecy
till the moment of execution; and when the workmen yield, as they
sometimes
do without resistance, though severely felt by them, they are
never
heard of by other people. Such combinations, however, are frequently
resisted
by a contrary defensive combination of the workmen, who sometimes,
too, without
any provocation of this kind, combine, of their own accord, to
raise
tile price of their labour. Their usual pretences are, sometimes the
high
price of provisions, sometimes the great profit which their masters
make by
their work. But whether their combinations be offensive or
defensive,
they are always abundantly heard of. In order to bring the point
to a
speedy decision, they have always recourse to the loudest clamour, and
sometimes
to the most shocking violence and outrage. They are desperate, and
act
with the folly and extravagance of desperate men, who must either
starve,
or frighten their masters into an immediate compliance with their
demands.
The masters, upon these occasions, are just as clamorous upon the
other
side, and never cease to call aloud for the assistance of the civil
magistrate,
and the rigorous execution of those laws which have been enacted
with so
much severity against the combination of servants, labourers, and
journeymen.
The workmen, accordingly, very seldom derive any advantage from
the
violence of those tumultuous combinations, which, partly from the
interposition
of the civil magistrate, partly from the superior steadiness
of the
masters, partly from the necessity which the greater part of the
workmen
are under of submitting for the sake of present subsistence,
generally
end in nothing but the punishment or ruin of the ringleaders.
But
though, in disputes with their workmen, masters must generally have
the
advantage, there is, however, a certain rate, below which it seems
impossible
to reduce, for any considerable time, the ordinary wages even of
the
lowest species of labour.
A man
must always live by his work, and his wages must at least be
sufficient
to maintain him. They must even upon most occasions be somewhat
more,
otherwise it would be impossible for him to bring up a family. and the
race of
such workmen could not last beyond the first generation. Mr
Cantillon
seems, upon this account, to suppose that the lowest species of
common
labourers must everywhere earn at least double their own maintenance,
in
order that, one with another, they may be enabled to bring up two
children;
the labour of the wife, on account of her necessary attendance on
the
children, being supposed no more than sufficient to provide for herself:
But one
half the children born, it is computed, die before the age of
manhood.
The poorest labourers, therefore, according to this account, must,
one
with another, attempt to rear at least four children, in order; that two
may
have an equal chance of living to that age. But the necessary
maintenance
of four children, it is supposed, may be nearly equal to that of
one
man. The labour of an able-bodied slave, the same author adds, is
computed
to be worth double his maintenance ; and that of the meanest
labourer,
he thinks, cannot be worth less than that of an able-bodied slave.
Thus
far at least seems certain, that, in order to bring up a family, the
labour
of the husband and wife together must, even in the lowest species of
common
labour, be able to earn something more than what is precisely
necessary
for their own maintenance; but in what proportion, whether in that
above-mentioned,
or many other, I shall not take upon me to determine.
There
are certain circumstances, however, which sometimes give the labourers
an
advantage, and enable them to raise their wages considerably above this
rate,
evidently the lowest which is consistent with common humanity.
When in
any country the demand for those who live by wages, labourers,
journeymen,
servants of every kind, is continually increasing; when every
year
furnishes employment for a greater number than had been employed the
year
before, the workmen have no occasion to combine in order to raise their
wages.
The scarcity of hands occasions a competition among masters, who bid
against
one another in order to get workmen, and thus voluntarily break
through
the natural combination of masters not to raise wages. The demand
for
those who live by wages, it is evident, cannot increase but in proportion
to the
increase of the funds which are destined to the payment of
wages.
These funds are of two kinds, first, the revenue which is over and
above
what is necessary for the maintenance; and, secondly, the stock which
is over
and above what is necessary for the employment of their masters.
When
the landlord, annuitant, or monied man, has a greater revenue than what
he
judges sufficient to maintain his own family, he employs either the whole
or a
part of the surplus in maintaining one or more menial servants.
Increase
this surplus, and he will naturally increase the number of those
servants.
When an
independent workman, such as a weaver or shoemaker, has got more
stock
than what is sufficient to purchase the materials of his own work, and
to
maintain himself till he can dispose of it, he naturally employs one or
more
journeymen with the surplus, in order to make a profit by their work.
Increase
this surplus, and he will naturally increase the number of his
journeymen.
The
demand for those who live by wages, therefore, necessarily increases
with
the increase of the revenue and stock of every country, and cannot
possibly
increase without it. The increase of revenue and stock is the
increase
of national wealth. The demand for those who live by wages,
therefore,
naturally increases with the increase of national wealth, and
cannot
possibly increase without it.
It is
not the actual greatness of national wealth, but its continual
increase,
which occasions a rise in the wages of labour. It is not,
accordingly,
in the richest countries, but in the most thriving, or in those
which
are growing rich the fastest, that the wages of labour are highest.
England
is certainly, in the present times, a much richer country than any
part of
North America. The wages of labour, however, are much higher in
North
America than in any part of England. In the province of New York,
common
labourers earned in 1773, before the
commencement
of the
late disturbances, three shillings and sixpence currency, equal to
two
shillings sterling, a-day ; ship-carpenters, ten shillings and sixpence
currency,
with a pint of rum, worth sixpence sterling, equal in all to six
shillings
and sixpence sterling; house-carpenters and bricklayers, eight
shillings
currency, equal to four shillings and sixpence sterling ;
journeymen
tailors, five shillings currency, equal to about two shillings
and
tenpence sterling. These prices are all above the London price ; and
wages
are said to be as high in the other colonies as in New York. The price
of
provisions is everywhere in North America much lower than in England. A
dearth
has never been known there. In the worst seasons they have always had
a
sufficiency for themselves, though less for exportation. If the money
price
of labour, therefore, be higher than it is anywhere in the
mother-country,
its real price, the real command of the necessaries and
conveniencies
of life which it conveys to the labourer, must be higher in a
still
greater proportion.
But
though North America is not yet so rich as England, it is much more
thriving,
and advancing with much greater rapidity to the further
acquisition
of riches. The most decisive mark of the prosperity of any
country
is the increase of the number of its inhabitants. In Great
Britain,
and most other European countries, they are not supposed to double
in less
than five hundred years. In the
British colonies in North
America,
it has been found that they double in twenty or five-and-twenty
years.
Nor in the present times is this increase principally owing to the
continual
importation of new inhabitants, but to the great multiplication of
the
species. Those who live to old age, it is said, frequently see there
from
fifty to a hundred, and sometimes many more, descendants from their own
body.
Labour is there so well rewarded, that a numerous family of children,
instead
of being a burden, is a source of opulence and prosperity to the
parents.
The labour of each child, before it can leave their house, is
computed
to be worth a hundred pounds clear gain to them. A young widow with
four or
five young children, who, among the middling or inferior ranks of
people
in Europe, would have so little chance for a second husband, is there
frequently
courted as a sort of fortune. The value of children is the
greatest
of all encouragements to marriage. We cannot, therefore, wonder
that
the people in North America should generally marry very young.
Notwithstanding
the great increase occasioned by such early marriages, there
is a
continual complaint of the scarcity of hands in North America. The
demand
for labourers, the funds destined for maintaining them increase, it
seems,
still faster than they can find labourers to employ.
Though
the wealth of a country should be very great, yet if it has been long
stationary,
we must not expect to find the wages of labour very high in it.
The
funds destined for the payment of wages, the revenue and stock of its
inhabitants,
may be of the greatest extent; but if they have continued for
several
centuries of the same, or very nearly of the same extent, the number
of
labourers employed every year could easily supply, and even more than
supply,
the number wanted the following year. There could seldom be any
scarcity
of hands, nor could the masters be obliged to bid against one
another
in order to get them. The hands, on the contrary, would, in this
case,
naturally multiply beyond their employment. There would be a constant
scarcity
of employment, and the labourers would be obliged to bid against
one
another in order to get it. If in such a country the wages off labour had
ever
been more than sufficient to maintain the labourer, and to enable him
to
bring up a family, the competition of the labourers and the interest of
the
masters would soon reduce them to the lowest rate which is consistent
with
common humanity. China has been long one of the richest, that is, one
of the
most fertile, best cultivated, most industrious, and most populous,
countries
in the world. It seems, however, to have been long stationary.
Marco
Polo, who visited it more than five hundred years ago, describes its
cultivation,
industry, and populousness, almost in the same terms in which
they
are described by travellers in the present times. It had, perhaps, even
long
before his time, acquired that full complement of riches which the
nature
of its laws and institutions permits it to acquire. The accounts of
all
travellers, inconsistent in many other respects, agree in the low wages
of
labour, and in the difficulty which a labourer finds in bringing up a
family
in China. If by digging the ground a whole day he can get what will
purchase
a small quantity of rice in the evening, he is contented. The
condition
of artificers is, if possible, still worse. Instead of waiting
indolently
in their work-houses for the calls of their customers, as in
Europe,
they are continually running about the streets with the tools of
their
respective trades, offering their services, and, as it were, begging
employment.
The poverty of the lower ranks of people in China far surpasses
that of
the most beggarly nations in Europe. In the neighbourhood of Canton,
many
hundred, it is commonly said, many thousand families have no habitation
on the
land, but live constantly in little fishing-boats upon the rivers and
canals.
The subsistence which they find there is so scanty, that they are
eager
to fish up the nastiest garbage thrown overboard from any European
ship.
Any carrion, the carcase of a dead dog or cat, for example, though
half
putrid and stinking, is as welcome to them as the most wholesome food
to the
people of other countries. Marriage is encouraged in China, not by
the
profitableness of children, but by the liberty of destroying them. In
all
great towns, several are every night exposed in the street, or drowned
like
puppies in the water. The performance of this horrid office is even
said to
be the avowed business by which some people earn their subsistence.
China,
however, though it may, perhaps, stand still, does not seem to go
backwards.
Its towns are nowhere deserted by their inhabitants. The lands
which
had once been cultivated, are nowhere neglected. The same, or very
nearly
the same, annual labour, must, therefore, continue to be performed,
and the
funds destined for maintaining it must not, consequently, be
sensibly
diminished. The lowest class of labourers, therefore,
notwithstanding
their scanty subsistence, must some way or another make
shift
to continue their race so far as to keep up their usual numbers.
But it
would be otherwise in a country where the funds destined for the
maintenance
of labour were sensibly decaying. Every year the demand for
servants
and labourers would, in all the different classes of employments,
be less
than it had been the year before. Many who had been bred in the
superior
classes, not being able to find employment in their own business,
would
be glad to seek it in the lowest. The lowest class being not only
overstocked
with its own workmen, but with the overflowings of all the other
classes,
the competition for employment would be so great in it, as to
reduce
the wages of labour to the most miserable and scanty subsistence of
the
labourer. Many would not he able to find employment even upon these hard
terms,
but would either starve, or be driven to seek a subsistence, either
by
begging, or by the perpetration perhaps, of the greatest enormities.
Want,
famine, and mortality, would immediately prevail in that class, and
from
thence extend themselves to all the superior classes, till the number
of
inhabitants in the country was reduced to what could easily be maintained
by the
revenue and stock which remained in it, and which had escaped either
the
tyranny or calamity which had destroyed the rest. This, perhaps, is
nearly
the present state of Bengal, and of some other of the English
settlements
in the East Indies. In a fertile country, which had before been
much
depopulated, where subsistence, consequently, should not be very
difficult,
and where, notwithstanding, three or four hundred thousand people
die of
hunger in one year, we maybe assured that the funds destined for the
maintenance
of the labouring poor are fast decaying. The difference between
the
genius of the British constitution, which protects and governs North
America,
and that of the mercantile company which oppresses and domineers in
the
East Indies, cannot, perhaps, be better illustrated than by the
different
state of those countries.
The
liberal reward of labour, therefore, as it is the necessary effect, so
it is
the natural symptom of increasing national wealth. The scanty
maintenance
of the labouring poor, on the other hand, is the natural symptom
that
things are at a stand, and their starving condition, that they are
going
fast backwards.
In
Great Britain, the wages of labour seem, in the present times, to be
evidently
more than what is precisely necessary to enable the labourer to
bring
up a family. In order to satisfy ourselves upon this point, it will
not be
necessary to enter into any tedious or doubtful calculation of what
may be
the lowest sum upon winch it is possible to do this. There are many
plain
symptoms, that the wages of labour are nowhere in this country
regulated
by this lowest rate, which is consistent with common humanity.
First,
in almost every part of Great Britain there is a distinction, even in
the
lowest species of labour, between summer and winter wages. Summer wages
are
always highest. But, on account of the extraordinary expense of fuel,
the
maintenance of a family is most expensive in winter. Wages, therefore,
being
highest when this expense is lowest, it seems evident that they are
not
regulated by what is necessary for this expense, but by the quantity and
supposed
value of the work. A labourer, it may be said, indeed, ought to
save
part of his summer wages, in order to defray his winter expense; and
that,
through the whole year, they do not exceed what is necessary to
maintain
his family through the whole year. A slave, however, or one
absolutely
dependent on us for immediate subsistence, would not be treated
in this
manner. His daily subsistence would be proportioned to his daily
necessities.
Secondly, the wages of labour do not, in
Great Britain, fluctuate with
the
price of provisions. These vary everywhere from year to year, frequently
from
month to month. But in many places, the money price of labour remains
uniformly
the same, sometimes for half a century together. If, in these
places,
therefore, the labouring poor can maintain their families in dear
years,
they must be at their ease in times of moderate plenty, and in
affluence
in those of extraordinary cheapness. The high price of provisions
during
these ten years past, has not, in many parts of the kingdom, been
accompanied
with any sensible rise in the money price of labour. It has,
indeed,
in some ; owing, probably, more to the increase of the demand for
labour,
than to that of the price of provisions.
Thirdly,
as the price of provisions varies more from year to year than the
wages
of labour, so, on the other hand, the wages of labour vary more from
place
to place than the price of provisions. The prices of bread and
butchers'
meat are generally the same, or very nearly the same, through the
greater
part of the united kingdom. These, and most other things which are
sold by
retail, the way in which the labouring poor buy all things, are
generally
fully as cheap, or cheaper, in great towns than in the remoter
parts
of the country, for reasons which I shall have occasion to explain
hereafter.
But the wages of labour in a great town and its neighbourhood,
are
frequently a fourth or a fifth part, twenty or five-and--twenty per
cent.
higher than at a few miles distance. Eighteen pence a day may be
reckoned
the common price of labour in London and its neighbourhood. At a
few
miles distance. it falls to fourteen and fifteen pence. Tenpence may be
reckoned
its price in Edinburgh and its neighbourhood. At a few miles
distance,
it falls to eightpence, the usual price of common labour through
the
greater part of the low country of Scotland, where it varies a good deal
less
than in England. Such a difference of prices, which, it seems, is not
always
sufficient to transport a man from one parish to another, would
necessarily
occasion so great a transportation of the most bulky
commodities,
not only from one parish to another, but from one end of the
kingdom,
almost from one end of the world to the other, as would soon reduce
them
more nearly to a level. After all that has been said of the levity and
inconstancy
of human nature, it appears evidently from experience, that man
is, of
all sorts of luggage, the most difficult to be transported. If the
labouring
poor, therefore, can maintain their families in those parts of the
kingdom
where the price of labour is lowest, they must be in affluence where
it is
highest.
Fourthly,
the variations in the price of labour not only do not correspond,
either
in place or time, with those in the price of provisions, but they are
frequently
quite opposite.
Grain,
the food of the common people, is dearer in Scotland than in England,
whence
Scotland receives almost every year very large supplies. But English
corn
must be sold dearer in Scotland, the country to which it is brought,
than in
England, the country from which it comes; and in proportion to its
quality
it cannot be sold dearer in Scotland than the Scotch corn that comes
to the
same market in competition with it. The quality of grain depends
chiefly
upon the quantity of flour or meal which it yields at the mill ;
and, in
this respect, English grain is so much superior to the Scotch, that
though
often dearer in appearance, or in proportion to the measure of its
bulk,
it is generally cheaper in reality, or in proportion to its quality,
or even
to the measure of its weight. The price of labour, on the contrary,
is
dearer in England than in Scotland. If the labouring poor, therefore, can
maintain
their families in the one part of the united kingdom, they must be
in
affluence in the other. Oatmeal, indeed, supplies the common people in
Scotland
with the greatest and the best part of their food, which is, in
general,
much inferior to that of their neighbours of the same rank in
England.
This difference, however, in the mode of their subsistence, is not
the
cause, but the effect, of the difference in their wages; though, by a
strange
misapprehension, I have frequently heard it represented as the
cause.
It is not because one man keeps a coach, while his neighbour walks
a-foot,
that the one is rich, and the other poor; but because the one is
rich,
he keeps a coach, and because the other is poor, he walks a-foot.
During
the course of the last century, taking one year with another, grain
was
dearer in both parts of the united kingdom than during that of the
present.
This is a matter of fact which cannot now admit of any reasonable
doubt ;
and the proof of it is, if possible, still more decisive with regard
to
Scotland than with regard to England. It is in Scotland supported by the
evidence
of the public fiars, annual valuations made upon oath, according to
the
actual state of the markets, of all the different sorts of grain in
every
different county of Scotland. If such direct proof could require any
collateral
evidence to confirm it, I would observe, that this has likewise
been
the case in France, and probably in most other parts of Europe. With
regard
to France, there is the clearest proof. But though it is certain,
that in
both parts of the united kingdom grain was somewhat dearer in the
last
century than in the present, it is equally certain that labour was much
cheaper.
If the labouring poor, therefore, could bring up their families
then,
they must be much more at their ease now. In the last century, the
most
usual day-wages of common labour through the greater part of Scotland
were
sixpence in summer, and fivepence in winter. Three shillings a-week,
the
same price, very nearly still continues to be paid in some parts of the
Highlands
and Western islands. Through the greater part of the Low country,
the
most usual wages of common labour are now eight pence a-day ; tenpence,
sometimes
a shilling, about Edinburgh, in the counties which border upon
England,
probably on account of that neighbourhood, and in a few other
places
where there has lately been a considerable rise in the demand for
labour,
about Glasgow, Carron, Ayrshire, etc. In England, the improvements
of
agriculture, manufactures, and commerce, began much earlier than in
Scotland.
The demand for labour, and consequently its price, must
necessarily
have increased with those improvements. In the last century,
accordingly,
as well as in the present, the wages of labour were higher in
England
than in Scotland. They have risen, too, considerably since that
time,
though, on account of the greater variety of wages paid there in
different
places, it is more difficult to ascertain how much. In 1614, the
pay of
a foot soldier was the same as in the present times, eightpence
a-day.
When it was first established, it would naturally be regulated by the
usual
wages of common labourers, the rank of people from which foot soldiers
are
commonly drawn. Lord-chief-justice Hales, who wrote in the time of
Charles
II. computes the necessary expense of a labourer's family,
consisting
of six persons, the father and mother, two children able to do
something,
and two not able, at ten shillings a-week, or twenty-six pounds
a-year.
If they cannot earn this by their labour, they must make it up, he
supposes,
either by begging or stealing. He appears to have enquired very
carefully
into this subject {See his scheme for
the maintenance of the
poor,
in Burn's History of the Poor Laws.}. In 1688, Mr Gregory King, whose
skill
in political arithmetic is so much extolled by Dr Davenant, computed
the
ordinary income of labourers and out-servants to be fifteen pounds
a-year
to a family, which he supposed to consist, one with another, of three
and a
half persons. His calculation, therefore, though different in
appearance,
corresponds very nearly at bottom with that of Judge Hales. Both
suppose
the weekly expense of such families to be about twenty-pence a-head.
Both
the pecuniary income and expense of such families have increased
considerably
since that time through the greater part of the kingdom, in
some
places more, and in some less, though perhaps scarce anywhere so much
as some
exaggerated accounts of the present wages of labour have lately
represented
them to the public. The price of labour, it must be observed,
cannot
be ascertained very accurately anywhere, different prices being often
paid at
the same place and for the same sort of labour, not only according
to the
different abilities of the workman, but according to the easiness or
hardness
of the masters. Where wages are not regulated by law, all that we
can
pretend to determine is, what are the most usual; and experience seems
to shew
that law can never regulate them properly, though it has often
pretended
to do so.
The
real recompence of labour, the real quantity of the necessaries and
conveniencies
of life which it can procure to the labourer, has, during the
course
of the present century, increased perhaps in a still greater
proportion
than its money price. Not only grain has become somewhat cheaper,
but
many other things, from which the industrious poor derive an agreeable
and
wholesome variety of food, have become a great deal cheaper. Potatoes,
for
example, do not at present, through the greater part of the kingdom,
cost
half the price which they used to do thirty or forty years ago. The
same
thing may be said of turnips, carrots, cabbages ; things which were
formerly
never raised but by the spade, but which are now commonly raised by
the
plough. All sort of garden stuff, too, has become cheaper. The greater
part of
the apples, and even of the onions, consumed in Great Britain, were,
in the
last century, imported from Flanders. The great improvements in the
coarser
manufactories of both linen and woollen cloth furnish the labourers
with
cheaper and better clothing; and those in the manufactories of the
coarser
metals, with cheaper and better instruments of trade, as well as
with
many agreeable and convenient pieces of household furniture. Soap,
salt,
candles, leather, and fermented liquors, have, indeed, become a good
deal
dearer, chiefly from the taxes which have been laid upon them. The
quantity
of these, however, which the labouring poor an under any necessity
of
consuming, is so very small, that the increase in their price does not
compensate
the diminution in that of so many other things. The common
complaint,
that luxury extends itself even to the lowest ranks of the
people,
and that the labouring poor will not now be contented with the same
food,
clothing, and lodging, which satisfied them in former times, may
convince
us that it is not the money price of labour only, but its real
recompence,
which has augmented.
Is this
improvement in the circumstances of the lower ranks of the people to
be
regarded as an advantage, or as an inconveniency, to the society ? The
answer
seems at first abundantly plain. Servants, labourers, and workmen of
different
kinds, make up the far greater part of every great political
society.
But what improves the circumstances of the greater part, can never
be
regarded as any inconveniency to the whole. No society can surely be
flourishing
and happy, of which the far greater part of the members are poor
and
miserable. It is but equity, besides, that they who feed, clothe, and
lodge
the whole body of the people, should have such a share of the produce
of
their own labour as to be themselves tolerably well fed, clothed, and
lodged.
Poverty,
though it no doubt discourages, does not always prevent, marriage.
It
seems even to be favourable to generation. A half-starved Highland woman
frequently
bears more than twenty children, while a pampered fine lady is
often
incapable of bearing any, and is generally exhausted by two or three.
Barrenness,
so frequent among women of fashion, is very rare among those of
inferior
station. Luxury, in the fair sex, while it inflames, perhaps, the
passion
for enjoyment, seems always to weaken, and frequently to destroy
altogether,
the powers of generation.
But
poverty, though it does not prevent the generation, is extremely
unfavourable
to the rearing of children. The tender plant is produced ; but
in so
cold a soil, and so severe a climate, soon withers and dies. It is not
uncommon,
I have been frequently told, in the Highlands of Scotland, for a
mother
who has born twenty children not to have two alive. Several officers
of
great experience have assured me, that, so far from recruiting their
regiment,
they have never been able to supply it with drums and fifes, from
all the
soldiers' children that were born in it. A greater number of fine
children,
however, is seldom seen anywhere than about a barrack of soldiers.
Very
few of them, it seems, arrive at the age of thirteen or fourteen. In
some
places, one half the children die before they are four years of age, in
many
places before they are seven, and in almost all places before they are
nine or
ten. This great mortality, however will everywhere be found chiefly
among
the children of the common people, who cannot afford to tend them with
the
same care as those of better station. Though their marriages are
generally
more fruitful than those of people of fashion, a smaller
proportion
of their children arrive at maturity. In foundling hospitals, and
among
the children brought up by parish charities, the mortality is still
greater
than among those of the common people.
Every species of animals naturally
multiplies in proportion to the
means
of their subsistence, and no species can ever multiply be yond it. But
in
civilized society, it is only among the inferior ranks of people that the
scantiness
of subsistence can set limits to the further multiplication of
the
human species ; and it can do so in no other way than by destroying a
great
part of the children which their fruitful marriages produce.
The
liberal reward of labour, by enabling them to provide better for their
children,
and consequently to bring up a greater number, naturally tends to
widen
and extend those limits. It deserves to be remarked, too, that it
necessarily
does this as nearly as possible in the proportion which the
demand
for labour requires. If this demand is continually increasing, the
reward
of labour must necessarily encourage in such a manner the marriage
and
multiplication of labourers, as may enable them to supply that
continually
increasing demand by a continually increasing population. If the
reward
should at any time be less than what was requisite for this purpose,
the
deficiency of hands would soon raise it ; and if it should at any time
be
more, their excessive multiplication would soon lower it to this
necessary
rate. The market would be so much understocked with labour in the
one
case, and so much overstocked in the other, as would soon force back its
price
to that proper rate which the circumstances of the society required.
It is
in this manner that the demand for men, like that for any other
commodity,
necessarily regulates the production of men, quickens it when it
goes on
too slowly, and stops it when it advances too fast. It is this
demand
which regulates and determines the state of propagation in all the
different
countries of the world ; in North America, in Europe, and in China
; which
renders it rapidly progressive in the first, slow and gradual in the
second,
and altogether stationary in the last.
The
wear and tear of a slave, it has been said, is at the expense of his
master
; but that of a free servant is at his own expense. The wear and tear
of the
latter, however, is, in reality, as much at the expense of his master
as that
of the former. The wages paid to journeymen and servants of every
kind
must be such as may enable them, one with another to continue the race
of
journeymen and servants, according as the increasing, diminishing, or
stationary
demand of the society, may happen to require. But though the wear
and
tear of a free servant be equally at the expense of his master, it
generally
costs him much less than that of a slave. The fund destined for
replacing
or repairing, if I may say so, the wear and tear of the slave, is
commonly
managed by a negligent master or careless overseer. That destined
for
performing the same office with regard to the freeman is managed by the
freeman
himself. The disorders which generally prevail in the economy of the
rich,
naturally introduce themselves into the management of the former; the
strict
frugality and parsimonious attention of the poor as naturally
establish
themselves in that of the latter. Under such different management,
the
same purpose must require very different degrees of expense to execute
it. It
appears, accordingly, from the experience of all ages and nations, I
believe,
that the work done by freemen comes cheaper in the end than that
performed
by slaves. It is found to do so even at Boston, New-York, and
Philadelphia,
where the wages of common labour are so very high.
The
liberal reward of labour, therefore, as it is the effect of increasing
wealth,
so it is the cause of increasing population. To complain of it, is
to
lament over the necessary cause and effect of the greatest public
prosperity.
It
deserves to be remarked, perhaps, that it is in the progressive state,
while
the society is advancing to the further acquisition, rather than when
it has
acquired its full complement of riches, that the condition of the
labouring
poor, of the great body of the people, seems to be the happiest
and the
most comfortable. It is hard in the stationary, and miserable in the
declining
state. The progressive state is, in reality, the cheerful and the
hearty
state to all the different orders of the society; the stationary is
dull ;
the declining melancholy.
The
liberal reward of labour, as it encourages the propagation, so it
increases
the industry of the common people. The wages of labour are the
encouragement
of industry, which, like every other human quality, improves
in
proportion to the encouragement it receives. A plentiful subsistence
increases
the bodily strength of the labourer, and the comfortable hope of
bettering
his condition, and of ending his days, perhaps, in ease and
plenty,
animates him to exert that strength to the utmost. Where wages are
high,
accordingly, we shall always find the workmen more active, diligent,
and
expeditious, than where they are low ; in England, for example, than in
Scotland;
in the neighbourhood of great towns, than in remote country
places.
Some workmen, indeed, when they can earn in four days what will
maintain
them through the week, will be idle the other three. This, however,
is by
no means the case with the greater part. Workmen, on the contrary,
when
they are liberally paid by the piece, are very apt to overwork
themselves,
and to ruin their health and constitution in a few years. A
carpenter
in London, and in some other places, is not supposed to last in
his
utmost vigour above eight years. Something of the same kind happens in
many
other trades, in which the workmen are paid by the piece; as they
generally
are in manufactures, and even in country labour, wherever wages
are
higher than ordinary. Almost every class of artificers is subject to
some
peculiar infirmity occasioned by excessive application to their
peculiar
species of work. Ramuzzini, an eminent Italian physician, has
written
a particular book concerning such diseases. We do not reckon our
soldiers
the most industrious set of people among us; yet when soldiers have
been
employed in some particular sorts of work, and liberally paid by the
piece, their
officers have frequently been obliged to stipulate with the
undertaker,
that they should not be allowed to earn above a certain sum
every
day, according to the rate at which they were paid. Till this
stipulation
was made, mutual emulation, and the desire of greater gain,
frequently
prompted them to overwork themselves, and to hurt their health by
excessive
labour. Excessive application, during four days of the week, is
frequently
the real cause of the idleness of the other three, so much and so
loudly
complained of. Great labour, either of mind or body, continued for
several
days together is, in most men, naturally followed by a great desire
of
relaxation, which, if not restrained by force, or by some strong
necessity,
is almost irresistible. It is the call of nature, which requires
to be
relieved by some indulgence, sometimes of ease only, but sometimes too
of
dissipation and diversion. If it is not complied with, the consequences
are
often dangerous and sometimes fatal, and such as almost always, sooner
or
later, bring on the peculiar infirmity of the trade. If masters would
always
listen to the dictates of reason and humanity, they have frequently
occasion
rather to moderate, than to animate the application of many of
their
workmen. It will be found, I believe, in every sort of trade, that the
man who
works so moderately, as to be able to work constantly, not only
preserves
his health the longest, but, in the course of the year, executes
the
greatest quantity of work.
In
cheap years it is pretended, workmen are generally more idle, and in dear
times
more industrious than ordinary. A plentiful subsistence, therefore, it
has
been concluded, relaxes, and a scanty one quickens their industry. That
a
little more plenty than ordinary may render some workmen idle, cannot be
well
doubted; but that it should have this effect upon the greater part, or
that
men in general should work better when they are ill fed, than when they
are
well fed, when they are disheartened than when they are in good spirits,
when
they are frequently sick than when they are generally in good health,
seems
not very probable. Years of dearth, it is to be observed, are
generally
among the common people years of sickness and mortality, which
cannot
fail to diminish the produce of their industry.
In
years of plenty, servants frequently leave their masters, and trust their
subsistence
to what they can make by their own industry. But the same
cheapness
of provisions, by increasing the fund which is destined for the
maintenance
of servants, encourages masters, farmers especially, to employ a
greater
number. Farmers, upon such occasions, expect more profit from their
corn by
maintaining a few more labouring servants, than by selling it at a
low
price in the market. The demand for servants increases, while the number
of
those who offer to supply that demand diminishes. The price of labour,
therefore,
frequently rises in cheap years.
In
years of scarcity, the difficulty and uncertainty of subsistence make all
such
people eager to return to service. But the high price of provisions, by
diminishing
the funds destined for the maintenance of servants, disposes
masters
rather to diminish than to increase the number of those they have.
In dear
years, too, poor independent workmen frequently consume the little
stock
with which they had used to supply themselves with the materials of
their
work, and are obliged to become journeymen for subsistence. More
people
want employment than easily get it ; many are willing to take it upon
lower
terms than ordinary ; and the wages of both servants and journeymen
frequently
sink in dear years.
Masters
of all sorts, therefore, frequently make better bargains with their
servants
in dear than in cheap years, and find them more humble and
dependent
in the former than in the latter. They naturally, therefore,
commend
the former as more favourable to industry. Landlords and farmers,
besides,
two of the largest classes of masters, have another reason for
being
pleased with dear years. The rents of the one, and the profits of the
other,
depend very much upon the price of provisions. Nothing can be more
absurd,
however, than to imagine that men in general should work less when
they
work for themselves, than when they work for other people. A poor
independent
workman will generally be more industrious than even a
journeyman
who works by the piece. The one enjoys the whole produce of his
own
industry, the other shares it with his master. The one, in his separate
independent
state, is less liable to the temptations of bad company, which,
in
large manufactories, so frequently ruin the morals of the other. The
superiority
of the independent workman over those servants who are hired by
the
month or by the year, and whose wages and maintenance are the same,
whether
they do much or do little, is likely to be still greater. Cheap
years
tend to increase the proportion of independent workmen to journeymen
and
servants of all kinds, and dear years to diminish it.
A French
author of great knowledge and ingenuity, Mr Messance, receiver of
the
taillies in the election of St Etienne, endeavours to shew that the poor
do more
work in cheap than in dear years, by comparing the quantity and
value
of the goods made upon those different occasions in three different
manufactures;
one of coarse woollens, carried on at Elbeuf; one of linen,
and
another of silk, both which extend through the whole generality of
Rouen.
It appears from his account, which is copied from the registers of
the
public offices, that the quantity and value of the goods made in all
those
three manufactories has generally been greater in cheap than in dear
years,
and that it has always been; greatest in the cheapest, and least in
the
dearest years. All the three seem to be stationary manufactures, or
which,
though their produce may vary somewhat from year to year, are, upon
the
whole, neither going backwards nor forwards.
The
manufacture of linen in Scotland, and that of coarse woollens in the
West Riding
of Yorkshire, are growing manufactures, of which the produce is
generally,
though with some variations, increasing both in quantity and
value.
Upon examining, however, the accounts which have been published of
their
annual produce, I have not been able to observe that its variations
have
had any sensible connection with the dearness or cheapness of the
seasons.
In 1740, a year of great scarcity, both manufactures, indeed,
appear
to have declined very considerably. But in 1756, another year or
great
scarcity, the Scotch manufactures made more than ordinary advances.
The
Yorkshire manufacture, indeed, declined, and its produce did not rise to
what it
had been in 1755, till 1766, after the repeal of the American stamp
act. In
that and the following year, it greatly exceeded what it had ever
been
before, and it has continued to advance ever since.
The
produce of all great manufactures for distant sale must necessarily
depend,
not so much upon the dearness or cheapness of the seasons in the
countries
where they are carried on, as upon the circumstances which affect
the
demand in the countries where they are consumed; upon peace or war, upon
the
prosperity or declension of other rival manufactures and upon the good
or bad
humour of their principal customers. A great part of the
extraordinary
work, besides, which is probably done in cheap years, never
enters
the public registers of manufactures. The men-servants, who leave
their
masters, become independent labourers. The women return to their
parents,
and commonly spin, in order to make clothes for themselves and
their
families. Even the independent workmen do not always, work for public
sale,
but are employed by some of their neighbours in manufactures for
family
use. The produce of their labour, therefore, frequently makes no
figure
in those public registers, of which the records are sometimes
published
with so much parade, and from which our merchants and
manufacturers
would often vainly pretend to announce the prosperity or
declension
of the greatest empires.
Through
the variations in the price of labour not only do not always
correspond
with those in the price of provisions, but are frequently quite
opposite,
we must not, upon this account, imagine that the price of
provisions
has no influence upon that of labour. The money price of labour
is
necessarily regulated by two circumstances; the demand for labour, and
the
price of the necessaries and conveniencies of life. The demand for
labour,
according as it happens to be increasing, stationary, or declining,
or to
require an increasing, stationary, or declining population, determines
the
quantities of the necessaries and conveniencies of life which must be
given
to the labourer; and the money price of labour is determined by what
is
requisite for purchasing this quantity. Though the money price of labour,
therefore,
is sometimes high where the price of provisions is low, it would
be
still higher, the demand continuing the same, if the price of provisions
was
high.
It is
because the demand for labour increases in years of sudden and
extraordinary
plenty, and diminishes in those of sudden and extraordinary
scarcity,
that the money price of labour sometimes rises in the one, and
sinks
in the other.
In a
year of sudden and extraordinary plenty, there are funds in the hands
of many
of the employers of industry, sufficient to maintain and employ a
greater
number of industrious people than had been employed the year before
; and
this extraordinary number cannot always be had. Those masters,
therefore,
who want more workmen, bid against one another, in order to get
them,
which sometimes raises both the real and the money price of their
labour.
The
contrary of this happens in a year of sudden and extraordinary scarcity.
The
funds destined for employing industry are less than they had been the
year
before. A considerable number of people are thrown out of employment,
who bid
one against another, in order to get it, which sometimes lowers both
the
real and the money price of labour. In 1740, a year of extraordinary
scarcity,
many people were willing to work for bare subsistence. In the
succeeding
years of plenty, it was more difficult to get labourers and
servants.
The scarcity of a dear year, by diminishing the demand for labour,
tends
to lower its price, as the high price of provisions tends to raise it.
The
plenty of a cheap year, on the contrary, by increasing the demand, tends
to
raise the price of labour, as the cheapness of provisions tends to lower
it. In
the ordinary variations of the prices of provisions, those two
opposite
causes seem to counterbalance one another, which is probably, in
part,
the reason why the wages of labour are everywhere so much more steady
and
permanent than the price of provisions.
The
increase in the wages of labour necessarily increases the price of many
commodities,
by increasing that part of it which resolves itself into wages,
and so
far tends to diminish their consumption, both at home and abroad. The
same
cause, however, which raises the wages of labour, the increase of
stock,
tends to increase its productive powers, and to make a smaller
quantity
of labour produce a greater quantity of work. The owner of the
stock
which employs a great number of labourers necessarily endeavours, for
his own
advantage, to make such a proper division and distribution of
employment,
that they may be enabled to produce the greatest quantity of
work
possible. For the same reason, he endeavours to supply them with the
best
machinery which either he or they can think of. What takes place among
the
labourers in a particular workhouse, takes place, for the same reason,
among
those of a great society. The greater their number, the more they
naturally
divide themselves into different classes and subdivisions of
employments.
More heads are occupied in inventing the most proper machinery
for
executing the work of each, and it is, therefore, more likely to be
invented.
There me many commodities, therefore, which, in consequence of
these
improvements, come to be produced by so much less labour than be.
fore,
that the increase of its price is more than compensated by the
diminution
of its quantity.
CHAPTER IX.
OF THE
PROFITS OF STOCK.
The
rise and fall in the profits of stock depend upon the same causes with
the
rise and fall in the wages of labour, the increasing or declining state
of the
wealth of the society ; but those causes affect the one and the other
very
differently.
The
increase of stock, which raises wages, tends to lower profit. When the
stocks
of many rich merchants are turned into the same trade, their mutual
competition
naturally tends to lower its profit; and when there is a like
increase
of stock in all the different trades carried on in the same
society,
the same competition must produce the same effect in them all.
It is
not easy, it has already been observed, to ascertain what are the
average
wages of labour, even in a particular place, and at a particular
time.
We can, even in this case, seldom determine more than what are the
most
usual wages. But even this can seldom be done with regard to the
profits
of stock. Profit is so very fluctuating, that the person who carries
on a
particular trade, cannot always tell you himself what is the average of
his
annual profit. It is affected, not only by every variation of price in
the
commodities which he deals in, but by the good or bad fortune both of
his
rivals and of his customers, and by a thousand other accidents, to which
goods,
when carried either by sea or by land, or even when stored in a
warehouse,
are liable. It varies, therefore, not only from year to year, but
from
day to day, and almost from hour to hour. To ascertain what is the
average
profit of all the different trades carried on in a great kingdom,
must be
much more difficult; and to judge of what it may have been formerly,
or in
remote periods of time, with any degree of precision, must be
altogether
impossible.
But
though it may be impossible to determine, with any degree of precision,
what
are or were the average profits of stock, either in the present or in
ancient
times, some notion may be formed of them from the interest of money.
It may
be laid down as a maxim, that wherever a great deal can be made by
the use
of money, a great deal will commonly be given for the use of it; and
that,
wherever little can be made by it, less will commonly he given for it.
Accordingly,
therefore, as the usual market rate of interest varies in any
country,
we may be assured that the ordinary profits of stock must vary with
it,
must sink as it sinks, and rise as it rises. The progress of interest,
therefore,
may lead us to form some notion of the progress of profit.
By the
37th of Henry VIII. all interest above ten per cent. was declared
unlawful.
More, it seems, had sometimes been taken before that. In the reign
of
Edward VI. religious zeal prohibited all interest. This prohibition,
however,
like all others of the same kind, is said to have produced no
effect,
and probably rather increased than diminished the evil of usury. The
statute
of Henry VIII. was revived by the 13th of Elizabeth, cap. 8. and ten
per
cent. continued to be the legal rate of interest till the 21st of James
I. when
it was restricted to eight per cent. It was reduced to six per cent.
soon
after the Restoration, and by the 12th of Queen Anne, to five per cent.
All
these different statutory regulations seem to have been made with great
propriety.
They seem to have followed, and not to have gone before, the
market
rate of interest, or the rate at which people of good credit usually
borrowed.
Since the time of Queen Anne, five per cent. seems to have been
rather
above than below the market rate. Before the late war, the government
borrowed
at three per cent. ; and people of good credit in the capital, and
in many
other parts of the kingdom, at three and a-half, four, and four and
a-half
per cent.
Since
the time of Henry VIII. the wealth and revenue of the country have
been
continually advancing, and in the course of their progress, their pace
seems
rather to have been gradually accelerated than retarded. They seem not
only to
have been going on, but to have been going on faster and faster. The
wages
of labour have been continually increasing during the same period,
and, in
the greater part of the different branches of trade and
manufactures,
the profits of stock have been diminishing.
It
generally requires a greater stock to carry on any sort of trade in a
great
town than in a country village. The great stocks employed in every
branch
of trade, and the number of rich competitors, generally reduce the
rate of
profit in the former below what it is in the latter. But the wages
of
labour are generally higher in a great town than in a country village. In
a
thriving town, the people who have great stocks to employ, frequently
cannot
get the number of workmen they want, and therefore bid against one
another,
in order to get as many as they can, which raises the wages of
labour,
and lowers the profits of stock. In the remote parts of the
country,
there is frequently not stock sufficient to employ all the people,
who
therefore bid against one another, in order to get employment, which
lowers
the wages of labour, and raises the profits of stock.
In
Scotland, though the legal rate of interest is the same as in England,
the
market rate is rather higher. People of the best credit there seldom
borrow
under five per cent. Even private bankers in Edinburgh give four per
cent.
upon their promissory-notes, of which payment, either in whole or in
part
may be demanded at pleasure. Private bankers in London give no interest
for the
money which is deposited with them. There are few trades which
cannot
be carried on with a smaller stock in Scotland than in England. The
common
rate of profit, therefore, must be somewhat greater. The wages of
labour,
it has already been observed, are lower in Scotland than in England.
The
country, too, is not only much poorer, but the steps by which it
advances
to a better condition, for it is evidently advancing, seem to be
much
slower and more tardy.
The
legal rate of interest in France has not during the course of the present
century, been
always
regulated by the market rate { See Denisart, Article Taux des Interests, tom.
iii, p.13}.
In
1720, interest was reduced from the twentieth to the fiftieth penny, or from
five to two per
cent.
In 1724, it was raised to the thirtieth penny, or to three and a third per
cent. In 1725, it
was
again raised to the twentieth penny, or to five per cent. In 1766, during the
administration
of Mr
Laverdy, it was reduced to the twenty-fifth penny, or to four per cent. The
Abbé Terray
raised
it afterwards to the old rate of five per cent. The supposed purpose of many of
those
violent
reductions of interest was to prepare the way for reducing that of the public
debts ; a
purpose
which has sometimes been executed. France is, perhaps, in the present times,
not so
rich a
country as England; and though the legal rate of interest has in France
frequently been
lower
than in England, the market rate has generally been higher; for there, as in
other
countries,
they have several very safe and easy methods of evading the law. The profits of
trade,
I have been assured by British merchants who had traded in both countries, are
higher
in
France than in England ; and it is no doubt upon this account, that many
British subjects
chuse
rather to employ their capitals in a country where trade is in disgrace, than
in one where
it is
highly respected. The wages of labour are lower in France than in England. When
you go
from
Scotland to England, the difference which you may remark between the dress and
countenance
of the common people in the one country and in the other, sufficiently
indicates
the
difference in their condition. The contrast is still greater when you return
from France.
France,
though no doubt a richer country than Scotland, seems not to be going forward
so fast.
It is a
common and even a popular opinion in the country, that it is going backwards ;
an
opinion
which I apprehend, is ill-founded, even with regard to France, but which nobody
can
possibly
entertain with regard to Scotland, who sees the country now, and who saw it
twenty
or
thirty years ago.
The
province of Holland, on the other hand, in proportion to the extent of
its
territory and the number of its people, is a richer country than
England.
The government there borrow at two per cent. and private people of
good
credit at three. The wages of labour are said to be higher in Holland
than in
England, and the Dutch, it is well known, trade upon lower profits
than
any people in Europe. The trade of Holland, it has been pretended by
some
people, is decaying, and it may perhaps be true that some particular
branches
of it are so; but these symptoms seem to indicate sufficiently that
there
is no general decay. When profit diminishes, merchants are very apt to
complain
that trade decays, though the diminution of profit is the natural
effect
of its prosperity, or of a greater stock being employed in it than
before.
During the late war, the Dutch gained the whole carrying trade of
France,
of which they still retain a very large share. The great property
which
they possess both in French and English funds, about forty millions,
it is
said in the latter (in which, I suspect, however, there is a
considerable
exaggeration ), the great sums which they lend to private
people,
in countries where the rate of interest is higher than in their own,
are
circumstances which no doubt demonstrate the redundancy of their stock,
or that
it has increased beyond what they can employ with tolerable profit
in the
proper business of their own country; but they do not demonstrate
that
that business has decreased. As the capital of a private man, though
acquired
by a particular trade, may increase beyond what he can employ in
it, and
yet that trade continue to increase too, so may likewise the capital
of a
great nation.
In our
North American and West Indian colonies, not only the wages of
labour,
but the interest of money, and consequently the profits of stock,
are
higher than in England. In the different colonies, both the legal and
the
market rate of interest run from six to eight percent. High wages of
labour
and high profits of stock, however, are things, perhaps, which scarce
ever go
together, except in the peculiar circumstances of new colonies. A
new
colony must always, for some time, be more understocked in proportion to
the
extent of its territory, and more underpeopled in proportion to the
extent
of its stock, than the greater part of other countries. They have
more
land than they have stock to cultivate. What they have, therefore, is
applied
to the cultivation only of what is most fertile and most favourably
situated,
the land near the sea-shore, and along the banks of navigable
rivers.
Such land, too, is frequently purchased at a price below the value
even of
its natural produce. Stock employed in the purchase and improvement
of such
lands, must yield a very large profit, and, consequently, afford to
pay a
very large interest. Its rapid accumulation in so profitable an
employment
enables the planter to increase the number of his hands faster
than he
can find them in a new settlement. Those whom he can find,
therefore,
are very liberally rewarded. As the colony increases, the profits
of
stock gradually diminish. When the most fertile and best situated lands
have
been all occupied, less profit can be made by the cultivation of what
is
inferior both in soil and situation, and less interest can be afforded
for the
stock which is so employed. In the greater part of our colonies,
accordingly,
both the legal and the market rate of interest have been
considerably
reduced during the course of the present century. As riches,
improvement,
and population, have increased, interest has declined. The
wages
of labour do not sink with the profits of stock. The demand for labour
increases
with the increase of stock, whatever be its profits; and after
these
are diminished, stock may not only continue to increase, but to
increase
much faster than before. It is with industrious nations, who are
advancing
in the acquisition of riches, as with industrious individuals. A
great
stock, though with small profits, generally increases faster than a
small
stock with great profits. Money, says the proverb, makes money. When
you
have got a little, it is often easy to get more. The great difficulty is
to get
that little. The connection between the increase of stock and that of
industry,
or of the demand for useful labour, has partly been explained
already,
but will be explained more fully hereafter, in treating of the
accumulation
of stock.
The
acquisition of new territory, or of new branches of trade, may sometimes
raise
the profits of stock, and with them the interest of money, even in a
country
which is fast advancing in the acquisition of riches. The stock of
the
country, not being sufficient for the whole accession of business which
such
acquisitions present to the different people among whom it is divided,
is
applied to those particular branches only which afford the greatest
profit.
Part of what had before been employed in other trades, is
necessarily
withdrawn from them, and turned into some of the new and more
profitable
ones. In all those old trades, therefore, the competition comes
to be
Jess than before. The market comes to be less fully supplied with many
different
sorts of goods. Their price necessarily rises more or less, and
yields
a greater profit to those who deal in them, who can, therefore,
afford
to borrow at a higher interest. For some time after the conclusion of
the
late war, not only private people of the best credit, but some of the
greatest
companies in London, commonly borrowed at five per cent. who,
before
that, had not been used to pay more than four, and four and a half
per
cent. The great accession both of territory and trade by our
acquisitions
in North America and the West Indies, will sufficiently account
for this,
without supposing any diminution in the capital stock of the
society.
So great an accession of new business to be carried on by the old
stock,
must necessarily have diminished the quantity employed in a great
number
of particular branches, in which the competition being less, the
profits
must have been greater. I shall hereafter have occasion to mention
the
reasons which dispose me to believe that the capital stock of Great
Britain
was not diminished, even by the enormous expense of the late war.
The
diminution of the capital stock of the society, or of the funds destined
for the
maintenance of industry, however, as it lowers the wages of labour,
so it
raises the profits of stock, and consequently the interest of money.
By the
wages of labour being lowered, the owners of what stock remains in
the
society can bring their goods at less expense to market than before ;
and
less stock being employed in supplying the market than before, they can
sell
them dearer. Their goods cost them less, and they get more for them.
Their
profits, therefore, being augmented at both ends, can well afford a
large
interest. The great fortunes so suddenly and so easily acquired in
Bengal
and the other British settlements in the East Indies, may satisfy us,
that as
the wages of labour are very low, so the profits of stock are very
high in
those ruined countries. The interest of money is proportionably so.
In
Bengal, money is frequently lent to the farmers at forty, fifty, and
sixty
per cent. and the succeeding crop is mortgaged for the payment. As the
profits
which can afford such an interest must eat up almost the whole rent
of the
landlord, so such enormous usury must in its turn eat up the greater
part of
those profits. Before the fall of the Roman republic, a usury of the
same
kind seems to have been common in the provinces, under the ruinous
administration
of their proconsuls. The virtuous Brutus lent money in Cyprus
at
eight-and-forty per cent. as we learn from the letters of Cicero.
In a
country which had acquired that full complement of riches which the
nature
of its soil and climate, and its situation with respect to other
countries,
allowed it to acquire, which could, therefore, advance no
further,
and which was not going backwards, both the wages of labour and the
profits
of stock would probably be very low. In a country fully peopled in
proportion
to what either its territory could maintain, or its stock employ,
the
competition for employment would necessarily be so great as to reduce
the
wages of labour to what was barely sufficient to keep up the number of
labourers,
and the country being already fully peopled, that number could
never
be augmented. In a country fully stocked in proportion to all the
business
it had to transact, as great a quantity of stock would be employed
in
every particular branch as the nature and extent of the trade would
admit.
The competition, therefore, would everywhere be as great, and,
consequently,
the ordinary profit as low as possible.
But,
perhaps, no country has ever yet arrived at this degree of opulence.
China
seems to have been long stationary, and had, probably, long ago
acquired
that full complement of riches which is consistent with the nature
of its
laws and institutions. But this complement may be much inferior to
what,
with other laws and institutions, the nature of its soil, climate, and
situation,
might admit of. A country which neglects or despises foreign
commerce,
and which admits the vessel of foreign nations into one or two of
its
ports only, cannot transact the same quantity of business which it might
do with
different laws and institutions. In a country, too, where, though
the
rich, or the owners of large capitals, enjoy a good deal of security,
the
poor, or the owners of small capitals, enjoy scarce any, but are liable,
under
the pretence of justice, to be pillaged and plundered at any time by
the
inferior mandarins, the quantity of stock employed in all the different
branches
of business transacted within it, can never be equal to what the
nature
and extent of that business might admit. In every different branch,
the
oppression of the poor must establish the monopoly of the rich, who, by
engrossing
the whole trade to themselves, will be able to make very large
profits.
Twelve per cent. accordingly, is said to be the common interest of
money
in China, and the ordinary profits of stock must be sufficient to
afford
this large interest.
A
defect in the law may sometimes raise the rate of interest considerably
above
what the condition of the country, as to wealth or poverty, would
require.
When the law does not enforce the performance of contracts, it puts
all
borrowers nearly upon the same footing with bankrupts, or people of
doubtful
credit, in better regulated countries. The uncertainty of
recovering
his money makes the lender exact the same usurious interest which
is
usually required from bankrupts. Among the barbarous nations who overran
the
western provinces of the Roman empire, the performance of contracts was
left
for many ages to the faith of the contracting parties. The courts of
justice
of their kings seldom intermeddled in it. The high rate of interest
which
took place in those ancient times, may, perhaps, be partly accounted
for
from this cause.
When
the law prohibits interest altogether, it does not prevent it. Many
people
must borrow, and nobody will lend without such a consideration for
the use
of their money as is suitable, not only to what can be made by the
use of
it, but to the difficulty and danger of evading the law. The high
rate of
interest among all Mahometan nations is accounted for by M.
Montesquieu,
not from their poverty, but partly from this, and partly from
the
difficulty of recovering the money.
The
lowest ordinary rate of profit must always be something more than what
is
sufficient to compensate the occasional losses to which every employment
of
stock is exposed. It is this surplus only which is neat or clear profit.
What is
called gross profit, comprehends frequently not only this surplus,
but
what is retained for compensating such extraordinary losses. The
interest
which the borrower can afford to pay is in proportion to the clear
profit
only. The lowest ordinary rate of interest must, in the same manner,
be something
more than sufficient to compensate the occasional losses to
which
lending, even with tolerable prudence, is exposed. Were it not, mere
charity
or friendship could be the only motives for lending.
In a
country which had acquired its full complement of riches, where, in
every
particular branch of business, there was the greatest quantity of
stock
that could be employed in it, as the ordinary rate of clear profit
would
be very small, so the usual market rate of interest which could be
afforded
out of it would be so low as to render it impossible for any but
the
very wealthiest people to live upon the interest of their money. All
people
of small or middling fortunes would be obliged to superintend
themselves
the employment of their own stocks. It would be necessary that
almost
every man should be a man of business, or engage in some sort of
trade.
The province of Holland seems to be approaching near to this state.
It is
there unfashionable not to be a man of business. Necessity makes it
usual
for almost every man to be so, and custom everywhere regulates
fashion.
As it is ridiculous not to dress, so is it, in some measure, not to
be
employed like other people. As a man of a civil profession seems awkward
in a
camp or a garrison, and is even in some danger of being despised there,
so does
an idle man among men of business.
The
highest ordinary rate of profit may be such as, in the price of the
greater
part of commodities, eats up the whole of what should go to the rent
of the
land, and leaves only what is sufficient to pay the labour of
preparing
and bringing them to market, according to the lowest rate at which
labour
can anywhere be paid, the bare subsistence of the labourer. The
workman
must always have been fed in some way or other while he was about
the
work, but the landlord may not always have been paid. The profits of the
trade
which the servants of the East India Company carry on in Bengal may
not,
perhaps, be very far from this rate.
The
proportion which the usual market rate of interest ought to bear to the
ordinary
rate of clear profit, necessarily varies as profit rises or falls.
Double
interest is in Great Britain reckoned what the merchants call a good,
moderate,
reasonable profit; terms which, I apprehend, mean no more than a
common
and usual profit. In a country where the ordinary rate of clear profit
is
eight or ten per cent. it may be reasonable that one half of it should go
to
interest, wherever business is carried on with borrowed money. The stock
is at
the risk of the borrower, who, as it were, insures it to the lender ;
and
four or five per cent. may, in the greater part of trades, be both a
sufficient
profit upon the risk of this insurance, and a sufficient
recompence
for the trouble of employing the stock. But the proportion
between
interest and clear profit might not be the same in countries where
the
ordinary rate of profit was either a good deal lower, or a good deal
higher.
If it were a good deal lower, one half of it, perhaps, could not be
afforded
for interest ; and more might be afforded if it were a good deal
higher.
In
countries which are fast advancing to riches, the low rate of profit may,
in the
price of many commodities, compensate the high wages of labour, and
enable
those countries to sell as cheap as their less thriving neighbours,
among
whom the wages of labour may be lower.
In
reality, high profits tend much more to raise the price of work than high
wages.
If, in the linen manufacture, for example, the wages of the different
working
people, the flax-dressers, the spinners, the weavers, etc. should all
of them
be advanced twopence a-day, it would be necessary to heighten the
price
of a piece of linen only by a number of twopences equal to the number
of
people that had been employed about it, multiplied by the number of days
during
which they had been so employed. That part of the price of the
commodity
which resolved itself into the wages, would, through all the
different
stages of the manufacture, rise only in arithmetical proportion to
this
rise of wages. But if the profits of all the different employers of
those
working people should be raised five per cent. that part of the price
of the
commodity which resolved itself into profit would, through all the
different
stages of the manufacture, rise in geometrical proportion to this
rise of
profit. The employer of the flax dressers would, in selling his
flax,
require an additional five per cent. upon the whole value of the
materials
and wages which he advanced to his workmen. The employer of the
spinners
would require an additional five per cent. both upon the advanced
price
of the flax, and upon the wages of the spinners. And the employer of
the
weavers would require alike five per cent. both upon the advanced price
of the
linen-yarn, and upon the wages of the weavers. In raising the price of
commodities,
the rise of wages operates in the same manner as simple
interest
does in the accumulation of debt. The rise of profit operates like
compound
interest. Our merchants and master manufacturers complain much of
the bad
effects of high wages in raising the price, and thereby lessening
the
sale of their goods, both at home and abroad. They say nothing
concerning
the bad effects of high profits ; they are silent with regard to
the
pernicious effects of their own gains; they complain only of those of
other
people.
CHAPTER X.
OF
WAGES AND PROFIT IN THE DIFFERENT EMPLOYMENTS OF LABOUR AND
STOCK.
The
whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different employments of
labour and
stock,
must, in the same neighbourhood, be either perfectly equal, or continually
tending to
equality.
If, in the same neighbourhood, there was any employment evidently either more
or
less
advantageous than the rest, so many people would crowd into it in the one case,
and so
many
would desert it in the other, that its advantages would soon return to the
level of other
employments.
This, at least, would be the case in a society where things were left to follow
their
natural course, where there was perfect liberty, and where every man was
perfectly free
both to
choose what occupation he thought proper, and to change it as often as he
thought
proper.
Every man's interest would prompt him to seek the advantageous, and to shun the
disadvantageous
employment.
Pecuniary
wages and profit, indeed, are everywhere in Europe extremely different,
according
to the
different employments of labour and stock. But this difference arises, partly
from
certain
circumstances in the employments themselves, which, either really, or at least
in the
imagination
of men, make up for a small pecuniary gain in some, and counterbalance a great
one in
others, and partly from the policy of Europe, which nowhere leaves things at
perfect
liberty.
The
particular consideration of those circumstances, and of that policy, will
divide this
Chapter
into two parts.
PART I.
Inequalities arising from the nature of the employments themselves.
The
five following are the principal circumstances which, so far as I have been
able to
observe,
make up for a small pecuniary gain in some employments, and counterbalance a
great
one in others. First, the agreeableness or disagreeableness of the employments
themselves;
secondly, the easiness and cheapness, or the difficulty and expense of learning
them ;
thirdly, the constancy or inconstancy of employment in them ; fourthly, the
small or
great
trust which must be reposed in those who exercise them; and, fifthly, the
probability or
improbability
of success in them.
First,
the wages of labour vary with the ease or hardship, the cleanliness or
dirtiness, the
honourableness
or dishonourableness, of the employment. Thus in most places, take the year
round,
a journeyman tailor earns less than a journeyman weaver. His work is much
easier. A
journeyman
weaver earns less than a journeyman smith. His work is not always easier, but
it
is much
cleanlier. A journeyman blacksmith, though an artificer, seldom earns so much
in
twelve
hours, as a collier, who is only a labourer, does in eight. His work is not
quite so dirty,
is less
dangerous, and is carried on in day-light, and above ground. Honour makes a
great part
of the
reward of all honourable professions. In point of pecuniary gain, all things considered,
they
are generally under-recompensed, as I shall endeavour to shew by and by.
Disgrace has
the
contrary effect. The trade of a butcher is a brutal and an odious business ;
but it is in most
places
more profitable than the greater part of common trades. The most detestable of
all
employments,
that of public executioner, is, in proportion to the quantity of work done,
better
paid
than any common trade whatever.
Hunting
and fishing, the most important employments of mankind in the rude state of
society,
become,
in its advanced state, their most agreeable amusements, and they pursue for
pleasure
what
they once followed from necessity. In the advanced state of society, therefore,
they are
all
very poor people who follow as a trade, what other people pursue as a pastime.
Fishermen
have
been so since the time of Theocritus. {See Idyllium xxi.}. A poacher is
everywhere a
very
poor man in Great Britain. In countries where the rigour of the law suffers no
poachers,
the
licensed hunter is not in a much better condition. The natural taste for those
employments
makes
more people follow them, than can live comfortably by them; and the produce of
their
labour,
in proportion to its quantity, comes always too cheap to market, to afford any
thing but
the
most scanty subsistence to the labourers.
Disagreeableness
and disgrace affect the profits of stock in the same manner as the wages of
labour.
The keeper of an inn or tavern, who is never master of his own house, and who
is
exposed
to the brutality of every drunkard, exercises neither a very agreeable nor a
very
creditable
business. But there is scarce any common trade in which a small stock yields so
great a
profit.
Secondly,
the wages of labour vary with the easiness and cheapness, or the difficulty and
expense,
of learning the business.
When
any expensive machine is erected, the extraordinary work to be performed by it
before
it is
worn out, it must be expected, will replace the capital laid out upon it, with
at least the
ordinary
profits. A man educated at the expense of much labour and time to any of those
employments
which require extraordinary dexterity and skill, may be compared to one of
those
expensive machines. The work which he learns to perform, it must be expected,
over
and
above the usual wages of common labour, will replace to him the whole expense
of his
education,
with at least the ordinary profits of an equally valuable capital. It must do
this too
in a
reasonable time, regard being had to the very uncertain duration of human life,
in the
same
manner as to the more certain duration of the machine.
The
difference between the wages of skilled labour and those of common labour, is
founded
upon
this principle.
The
policy of Europe considers the labour of all mechanics, artificers, and
manufacturers, as
skilled
labour ; and that of all country labourers us common labour. It seems to
suppose that
of the
former to be of a more nice and delicate nature than that of the latter. It is
so perhaps in
some
cases ; but in the greater part it is quite otherwise, as I shall endeavour to
shew by and
by. The
laws and customs of Europe, therefore, in order to qualify any person for
exercising
the one
species of labour, impose the necessity of an apprenticeship, though with different
degrees
of rigour in different places. They leave the other free and open to every
body. During
the
continuance of the apprenticeship, the whole labour of the apprentice belongs
to his
master.
In the meantime he must, in many cases, be maintained by his parents or
relations,
and, in
almost all cases, must be clothed by them. Some money, too, is commonly given
to the
master
for teaching him his trade. They who cannot give money, give time, or become
bound
for
more than the usual number of years ; a consideration which, though it is not
always
advantageous
to the master, on account of the usual idleness of apprentices, is always
disadvantageous
to the apprentice. In country labour, on the contrary, the labourer, while he
is
employed
about the easier, learns the more difficult parts of his business, and his own
labour
maintains
him through all the different stages of his employment. It is reasonable,
therefore,
that in
Europe the wages of mechanics, artificers, and manufacturers, should be somewhat
higher
than those of common labourers. They are so accordingly, and their superior
gains
make
them, in most places, be considered as a superior rank of people. This
superiority,
however,
is generally very small: the daily or weekly earnings of journeymen in the more
common
sorts of manufactures, such as those of plain linen and woollen cloth, computed
at an
average,
are, in most places, very little more than the day-wages of common labourers.
Their
employment,
indeed, is more steady and uniform, and the superiority of their earnings,
taking
the
whole year together, may be somewhat greater. It seems evidently, however, to
be no
greater
than what is sufficient to compensate the superior expense of their education.
Education
in the ingenious arts, and in the liberal professions, is still more tedious
and
expensive.
The pecuniary recompence, therefore, of painters and sculptors, of lawyers and
physicians,
ought to be much more liberal; and it is so accordingly.
The
profits of stock seem to be very little affected by the easiness or difficulty
of learning the
trade
in which it is employed. All the different ways in which stock is commonly
employed in
great
towns seem, in reality, to be almost equally easy and equally difficult to
learn. One
branch,
either of foreign or domestic trade, cannot well be a much more intricate
business than
another.
Thirdly,
the wages of labour in different occupations vary with the constancy or
inconstancy
of
employment.
Employment
is much more constant in some trades than in others. In the greater part of
manufactures,
a journeyman maybe pretty sure of employment almost every day in the year
that he
is able to work. A mason or bricklayer, on the contrary, can work neither in
hard frost
nor in
foul weather, and his employment at all other times depends upon the occasional
calls
of his
customers. He is liable, in consequence, to be frequently without any. What he
earns,
therefore,
while he is employed, must not only maintain him while he is idle, but make him
some
compensation for those anxious and desponding moments which the thought of so
precarious
a situation must sometimes occasion. Where the computed earnings of the greater
part of
manufacturers, accordingly, are nearly upon a level with the day-wages of
common
labourers,
those of masons and bricklayers are generally from one-half more to double
those
wages.
Where common labourers earn four or five shillings a-week, masons and
bricklayers
frequently
earn seven and eight; where the former earn six, the latter often earn nine and
ten ;
and
where the former earn nine and ten, as in London, the latter commonly earn
fifteen and
eighteen.
No species of skilled labour, however, seems more easy to learn than that of
masons
and
bricklayers. Chairmen in London, during the summer season, are said sometimes
to be
employed
as bricklayers. The high wages of those workmen, therefore, are not so much the
recompence
of their skill, as the compensation for the inconstancy of their employment.
A
house-carpenter seems to exercise rather a nicer and a more ingenious trade
than a mason.
In most
places, however, for it is not universally so, his day-wages are somewhat
lower. His
employment,
though it depends much, does not depend so entirely upon the occasional calls
of his
customers; and it is not liable to be interrupted by the weather.
When
the trades which generally afford constant employment, happen in a particular
place not
to do
so, the wages of the workmen always rise a good deal above their ordinary
proportion to
those
of common labour. In London, almost all journeymen artificers are liable to be
called
upon
and dismissed by their masters from day to day, and from week to week, in the
same
manner
as day-labourers in other places. The lowest order of artificers, journeymen
tailors,
accordingly,
earn their half-a-crown a-day, though eighteen pence may be reckoned the wages
of
common labour. In small towns and country villages, the wages of journeymen
tailors
frequently
scarce equal those of common labour ; but in London they are often many weeks
without
employment, particularly during the summer.
When
the inconstancy of employment is combined with the hardship, disagreeableness,
and
dirtiness
of the work, it sometimes raises the wages of the most common labour above
those
of the
most skilful artificers. A collier working by the piece is supposed, at
Newcastle, to earn
commonly
about double, and, in many parts of Scotland, about three times, the wages of
common
labour. His high wages arise altogether from the hardship, disagreeableness,
and
dirtiness
of his work. His employment may, upon most occasions, be as constant as he
pleases.
The coal-heavers in London exercise a trade which, in hardship, dirtiness, and
disagreeableness,
almost equals that of colliers ; and, from the unavoidable irregularity in the
arrivals
of coal-ships, the employment of the greater part of them is necessarily very
inconstant.
If colliers, therefore, commonly earn double and triple the wages of common
labour,
it ought not to seem unreasonable that coal-heavers should sometimes earn four
and
five
times those wages. In the inquiry made into their condition a few years ago, it
was found
that,
at the rate at which they were then paid, they could earn from six to ten
shillings a-day.
Six
shillings are about four times the wages of common labour in London; and, in
every
particular
trade, the lowest common earnings may always be considered as those of the far
greater
number. How extravagant soever those earnings may appear, if they were more
than
sufficient
to compensate all the disagreeable circumstances of the business, there would
soon
be so
great a number of competitors, as, in a trade which has no exclusive privilege,
would
quickly
reduce them to a lower rate.
The
constancy or inconstancy of employment cannot affect the ordinary profits of
stock in any
particular
trade. Whether the stock is or is not constantly employed, depends, not upon
the
trade,
but the trader.
Fourthly,
the wages of labour vary according to the small or great trust which must be
reposed
in the
workmen.
The
wages of goldsmiths and jewellers are everywhere superior to those of many
other
workmen,
not only of equal, but of much superior ingenuity, on account of the precious
materials
with which they are entrusted. We trust our health to the physician, our
fortune, and
sometimes
our life and reputation, to the lawyer and attorney. Such confidence could not
safely
be reposed in people of a very mean or low condition. Their reward must be
such,
therefore,
as may give them that rank in the society which so important a trust requires.
The
long
time and the great expense which must be laid out in their education, when
combined
with
this circumstance, necessarily enhance still further the price of their labour.
When a
person employs only his own stock in trade, there is no trust; and the credit
which he
may get
from other people, depends, not upon the nature of the trade, but upon their
opinion
of his
fortune, probity and prudence. The different rates of profit, therefore, in the
different
branches
of trade, cannot arise from the different degrees of trust reposed in the
traders.
Fifthly,
the wages of labour in different employments vary according to the probability
or
improbability
of success in them.
The
probability that any particular person shall ever be qualified for the
employments to
which
he is educated, is very different in different occupations. In the greatest
part of
mechanic
trades success is almost certain; but very uncertain in the liberal
professions. Put
your
son apprentice to a shoemaker, there is little doubt of his learning to make a
pair of
shoes;
but send him to study the law, it as at least twenty to one if he ever makes
such
proficiency
as will enable him to live by the business. In a perfectly fair lottery, those
who
draw
the prizes ought to gain all that is lost by those who draw the blanks. In a
profession,
where
twenty fail for one that succeeds, that one ought to gain all that should have been
gained
by the unsuccessful twenty. The counsellor at law, who, perhaps, at near forty
years of
age,
begins to make something by his profession, ought to receive the retribution,
not only of
his own
so tedious and expensive education, but of that of more than twenty others, who
are
never
likely to make any thing by it. How extravagant soever the fees of counsellors
at law
may
sometimes appear, their real retribution is never equal to this. Compute, in
any particular
place,
what is likely to be annually gained, and what is likely to be annually spent,
by all the
different
workmen in any common trade, such as that of shoemakers or weavers, and you
will
find
that the former sum will generally exceed the latter. But make the same
computation with
regard
to all the counsellors and students of law, in all the different Inns of Court,
and you
will
find that their annual gains bear but a very small proportion to their annual
expense, even
though
you rate the former as high, and the latter as low, as can well be done. The
lottery of
the
law, therefore, is very far from being a perfectly fair lottery ; and that as
well as many
other
liberal and honourable professions, is, in point of pecuniary gain, evidently
under-recompensed.
Those professions keep their level,
however, with other occupations ; and,
notwithstanding
these discouragements, all the most generous and liberal spirits are eager to
crowd
into them. Two different causes contribute to recommend them. First, the desire
of the
reputation
which attends upon superior excellence in any of them ; and, secondly, the
natural
confidence
which every man has, more or less, not only in his own abilities, but in his
own
good
fortune.
To
excel in any profession, in which but few arrive at mediocrity, it is the most
decisive mark
of what
is called genius, or superior talents. The public admiration which attends upon
such
distinguished
abilities makes always a part of their reward; a greater or smaller, in
proportion
as it
is higher or lower in degree. It makes a considerable part of that reward in
the profession
of
physic ; a still greater, perhaps, in that of law; in poetry and philosophy it
makes almost the
whole.
There
are some very agreeable and beautiful talents, of which the possession commands
a
certain
sort of admiration, but of which the exercise, for the sake of gain, is
considered,
whether
from reason or prejudice, as a sort of public prostitution. The pecuniary
recompence,
therefore,
of those who exercise them in this manner, must be sufficient, not only to pay
for
the
time, labour, and expense of acquiring the talents, but for the discredit which
attends the
employment
of them as the means of subsistence. The exorbitant rewards of players,
opera-singers,
opera-dancers, etc. are founded upon those two principles ; the rarity and
beauty
of the talents, and the discredit of employing them in this manner. It seems
absurd at
first
sight, that we should despise their persons, and yet reward their talents with
the most
profuse
liberality. While we do the one, however, we must of necessity do the other,
Should
the
public opinion or prejudice ever alter with regard to such occupations, their
pecuniary
recompence
would quickly diminish. More people would apply to them, and the competition
would
quickly reduce the price of their labour. Such talents, though far from being
common,
are by
no means so rare as imagined. Many people possess them in great perfection, who
disdain
to make this use of them; and many more are capable of acquiring them, if any
thing
could
be made honourably by them.
The
over-weening conceit which the greater part of men have of their own abilities,
is an
ancient
evil remarked by the philosophers and moralists of all ages. Their absurd
presumption
in
their own good fortune has been less taken notice of. It is, however, if
possible, still more
universal.
There is no man living, who, when in tolerable health and spirits, has not some
share
of it. The chance of gain is by every man more or less over-valued, and the
chance of
loss is
by most men under-valued, and by scarce any man, who is in tolerable health and
spirits,
valued more than it is worth.
That
the chance of gain is naturally overvalued, we may learn from the universal
success of
lotteries.
The world neither ever saw, nor ever will see, a perfectly fair lottery, or one
in which
the
whole gain compensated the whole loss; because the undertaker could make
nothing by it.
In the
state lotteries, the tickets are really not worth the price which is paid by
the original
subscribers,
and yet commonly sell in the market for twenty, thirty, and sometimes forty per
cent.
advance. The vain hopes of gaining some of the great prizes is the sole cause
of this
demand.
The soberest people scarce look upon it as a folly to pay a small sum for the
chance
of
gaining ten or twenty thousand pounds, though they know that even that small
sum is
perhaps
twenty or thirty per cent. more than the chance is worth. In a lottery in which
no prize
exceeded
twenty pounds, though in other respects it approached much nearer to a
perfectly
fair
one than the common state lotteries, there would not be the same demand for
tickets. In
order
to have a better chance for some of the great prizes, some people purchase
several
tickets
; and others, small shares in a still greater number. There is not, however, a
more
certain
proposition in mathematics, than that the more tickets you adventure upon, the
more
likely
you are to be a loser. Adventure upon all the tickets in the lottery, and you
lose for
certain
; and the greater the number of your tickets, the nearer you approach to this
certainty.
That
the chance of loss is frequently undervalued, and scarce ever valued more than
it is
worth,
we may learn from the very moderate profit of insurers. In order to make
insurance,
either
from fire or sea-risk, a trade at all, the common premium must be sufficient to
compensate
the common losses, to pay the expense of management, and to afford such a
profit
as
might have been drawn from an equal capital employed in any common trade. The
person
who
pays no more than this, evidently pays no more than the real value of the risk,
or the
lowest
price at which he can reasonably expect to insure it. But though many people
have
made a
little money by insurance, very few have made a great fortune; and, from this
consideration
alone, it seems evident enough that the ordinary balance of profit and loss is
not
more
advantageous in this than in other common trades, by which so many people make
fortunes.
Moderate, however, as the premium of insurance commonly is, many people despise
the
risk too much to care to pay it. Taking the whole kingdom at an average,
nineteen houses
in
twenty, or rather, perhaps, ninety-nine in a hundred, are not insured from
fire. Sea-risk is
more
alarming to the greater part of people ; and the proportion of ships insured to
those not
insured
is much greater. Many sail, however,
at all seasons, and even in time of war,
without
any insurance. This may sometimes, perhaps, be done without any imprudence.
When
a great
company, or even a great merchant, has twenty or thirty ships at sea, they may,
as it
were,
insure one another. The premium saved up on them all may more than compensate
such
losses
as they are likely to meet with in the common course of chances. The neglect of
insurance
upon shipping, however, in the same manner as upon houses, is, in most cases,
the
effect
of no such nice calculation, but of mere thoughtless rashness, and presumptuous
contempt
of the risk.
The
contempt of risk, and the presumptuous hope of success, are in no period of
life more
active
than at the age at which young people choose their professions. How little the
fear of
misfortune
is then capable of balancing the hope of good luck, appears still more
evidently in
the
readiness of the common people to enlist as soldiers, or to go to sea, than in
the eagerness
of
those of better fashion to enter into what are called the liberal professions.
What a
common soldier may lose is obvious enough. Without regarding the danger,
however,
young
volunteers never enlist so readily as at the beginning of a new war ; and
though they
have
scarce any chance of preferment, they figure to themselves, in their youthful
fancies, a
thousand
occasions of acquiring honour and distinction which never occur. These romantic
hopes
make the whole price of their blood. Their pay is less than that of common
labourers,
and, in
actual service, their fatigues are much greater.
The
lottery of the sea is not altogether so disadvantageous as that of the army.
The son of a
creditable
labourer or artificer may frequently go to sea with his father's consent ; but
if he
enlists
as a soldier, it is always without it. Other people see some chance of his
making
something
by the one trade; nobody but himself sees any of his making any thing by the
other.
The
great admiral is less the object of public admiration than the great general ;
and the
highest
success in the sea service promises a less brilliant fortune and reputation
than equal
success
in the land. The same difference runs through all the inferior degrees of
preferment in
both.
By the rules of precedency, a captain in the navy ranks with a colonel in the
army ; but
he does
not rank with him in the common estimation. As the great prizes in the lottery
are
less,
the smaller ones must be more numerous. Common sailors, therefore, more
frequently
get
some fortune and preferment than common soldiers ; and the hope of those prizes
is what
principally
recommends the trade. Though their skill and dexterity are much superior to
that
of
almost any artificers; and though their whole life is one continual scene of
hardship and
danger
; yet for all this dexterity and skill, for all those hardships and dangers,
while they
remain
in the condition of common sailors, they receive scarce any other recompence
but the
pleasure
of exercising the one and of surmounting the other. Their wages are not greater
than
those of common labourers at the port which regulates the rate of seamen's
wages. As
they
are continually going from port to port, the monthly pay of those who sail from
all the
different
ports of Great Britain, is more nearly upon a level than that of any other
workmen in
those
different places ; and the rate of the port to and from which the greatest
number sail, that
is, the
port of London, regulates that of all the rest. At London, the wages of the
greater part of
the
different classes of workmen are about double those of the same classes at
Edinburgh. But
the
sailors who sail from the port of London, seldom earn above three or four
shillings a
month
more than those who sail from the port of Leith, and the difference is
frequently not so
great.
In time of peace, and in the merchant-service, the London price is from a
guinea to
about
seven-and-twenty shillings the calendar month. A common labourer in London, at
the
rate of
nine or ten shillings a week, may earn in the calendar month from forty to
five-and-forty
shillings. The sailor, indeed, over and above his pay, is supplied with
provisions.
Their value, however, may not perhaps always exceed the difference between his
pay and
that of the common labourer ; and though it sometimes should, the excess will
not be
clear
gain to the sailor, because he cannot share it with his wife and family, whom
he must
maintain
out of his wages at home.
The
dangers and hair-breadth escapes of a life of adventures, instead of
disheartening young
people,
seem frequently to recommend a trade to them. A tender mother, among the
inferior
ranks
of people, is often afraid to send her son to school at a sea-port town, lest
the sight of
the
ships, and the conversation and adventures of the sailors, should entice him to
go to sea.
The
distant prospect of hazards, from which we can hope to extricate ourselves by
courage
and
address, is not disagreeable to us, and does not raise the wages of labour in
any
employment.
It is otherwise with those in which courage and address can be of no avail. In
trades
which are known to be very unwholesome, the wages of labour are always
remarkably
high.
Unwholesomeness is a species of disagreeableness, and its effects upon the
wages of
labour
are to be ranked under that general head.
In all
the different employments of stock, the ordinary rate of profit varies more or
less with
the
certainty or uncertainty of the returns. These are, in general, less uncertain
in the inland
than in
the foreign trade, and in some branches of foreign trade than in others ; in
the trade to
North
America, for example, than in that to Jamaica. The ordinary rate of profit
always rises
more or
less with the risk. it does not, however, seem to rise in proportion to it, or
so as to
compensate
it completely. Bankruptcies are most frequent in the most hazardous trades. The
most
hazardous of all trades, that of a smuggler, though, when the adventure
succeeds, it is
likewise
the most profitable, is the infallible road to bankruptcy. The presumptuous
hope of
success
seems to act here as upon all other occasions, and to entice so many
adventurers into
those
hazardous trades, that their competition reduces the profit below what is
sufficient to
compensate
the risk. To compensate it completely, the common returns ought, over and above
the
ordinary profits of stock, not only to make up for all occasional losses, but
to afford a
surplus
profit to the adventurers, of the same nature with the profit of insurers. But
if the
common
returns were sufficient for all this, bankruptcies would not be more frequent
in these
than in
other trades.
Of the
five circumstances, therefore, which vary the wages of labour, two only affect
the
profits
of stock ; the agreeableness or disagreeableness of the business, and the risk
or security
with
which it is attended. In point of agreeableness or disagreeableness, there is
little or no
difference
in the far greater part of the different employments of stock, but a great deal
in
those
of labour ; and the ordinary profit of stock, though it rises with the risk, does
not always
seem to
rise in proportion to it. It should follow from all this, that, in the same
society or
neighbourhood,
the average and ordinary rates of profit in the different employments of stock
should
he more nearly upon a level than the pecuniary wages of the different sorts of
labour.
They
are so accordingly. The difference between the earnings of a common labourer
and those
of a
well employed lawyer or physician, is evidently much greater than that between
the
ordinary
profits in any two different branches of trade. The apparent difference,
besides, in the
profits
of different trades, is generally a deception arising from our not always
distinguishing
what
ought to be considered as wages, from what ought to be considered as profit.
Apothecaries'
profit is become a bye-word, denoting something uncommonly extravagant.
This
great apparent profit, however, is frequently no more than the reasonable wages
of
labour.
The skill of an apothecary is a much nicer and more delicate matter than that
of any
artificer
whatever ; and the trust which is reposed in him is of much greater importance.
He is
the
physician of the poor in all cases, and of the rich when the distress or danger
is not very
great.
His reward, therefore, ought to be suitable to his skill and his trust ; and it
arises
generally
from the price at which he sells his drugs. But the whole drugs which the best
employed
apothecary in a large market-town, will sell in a year, may not perhaps cost
him
above
thirty or forty pounds. Though he should sell them, therefore, for three or
four hundred,
or at a
thousand per cent. profit, this may frequently be no more than the reasonable
wages of
his
labour, charged, in the only way in which he can charge them, upon the price of
his drugs.
The
greater part of the apparent profit is real wages disguised in the garb of
profit.
In a
small sea-port town, a little grocer will make forty or fifty per cent. upon a
stock of a
single
hundred pounds, while a considerable wholesale merchant in the same place will
scarce
make
eight or ten per cent. upon a stock of ten thousand. The trade of the grocer
may be
necessary
for the conveniency of the inhabitants, and the narrowness of the market may
not
admit
the employment of a larger capital in the business. The man, however, must not
only
live by
his trade, but live by it suitably to the qualifications which it requires.
Besides
possessing
a little capital, he must be able to read, write, and account and must be a
tolerable
judge,
too, of perhaps fifty or sixty different sorts of goods, their prices,
qualities, and the
markets
where they are to be had cheapest. He must have all the knowledge, in short,
that is
necessary
for a great merchant, which nothing hinders him from becoming but the want of a
sufficient
capital. Thirty or forty pounds a year cannot be considered as too great a
recompence
for the labour of a person so accomplished. Deduct this from the seemingly
great
profits
of his capital, and little more will remain, perhaps, than the ordinary profits
of stock.
The
greater part of the apparent profit is, in this case too, real wages.
The
difference between the apparent profit of the retail and that of the wholesale
trade, is
much
less in the capital than in small towns and country villages. Where ten
thousand pounds
can be
employed in the grocery trade, the wages of the grocer's labour must be a very
trifling
addition
to the real profits of so great a stock. The apparent profits of the wealthy
retailer,
therefore,
are there more nearly upon a level with those of the wholesale merchant. It is
upon
this
account that goods sold by retail are generally as cheap, and frequently much
cheaper, in
the
capital than in small towns and country villages. Grocery goods, for example,
are
generally
much cheaper ; bread and butchers' meat frequently as cheap. It costs no more
to
bring
grocery goods to the great town than to the country village ; but it costs a
great deal
more to
bring corn and cattle, as the greater part of them must be brought from a much
greater
distance.
The prime cost of grocery goods, therefore, being the same in both places, they
are
cheapest
where the least profit is charged upon them. The prime cost of bread and
butchers'
meat is
greater in the great town than in the country village; and though the profit is
less,
therefore
they are not always cheaper there, but often equally cheap. In such articles as
bread
and
butchers' meat, the same cause which diminishes apparent profit, increases
prime cost.
The
extent of the market, by giving employment to greater stocks, diminishes
apparent profit;
but by
requiring supplies from a greater distance, it increases prime cost. This
diminution of
the one
and increase of the other, seem, in most cases, nearly to counterbalance one
another ;
which
is probably the reason that, though the prices of corn and cattle are commonly
very
different
in different parts of the kingdom, those of bread and butchers' meat are
generally
very
nearly the same through the greater part of it.
Though
the profits of stock, both in the wholesale and retail trade, are generally
less in the
capital
than in small towns and country villages, yet great fortunes are frequently
acquired
from
small beginnings in the former, and scarce ever in the latter. In small towns
and country
villages,
on account of the narrowness of the market, trade cannot always be extended as
stock
extends.
In such places, therefore, though the rate of a particular person's profits may
be very
high,
the sum or amount of them can never be very great, nor consequently that of his
annual
accumulation.
In great towns, on the contrary, trade can be extended as stock increases, and
the
credit of a frugal and thriving man increases much faster than his stock. His
trade is
extended
in proportion to the amount of both ; and the sum or amount of his profits is
in
proportion
to the extent of his trade, and his annual accumulation in proportion to the
amount
of his
profits. It seldom happens, however, that great fortunes are made, even in
great towns,
by any
one regular, established, and well-known branch of business, but in consequence
of a
long
life of industry, frugality, and attention. Sudden fortunes, indeed, are
sometimes made in
such
places, by what is called the trade of speculation. The speculative merchant
exercises no
one
regular, established, or well-known branch of business. He is a corn merchant
this year,
and a
wine merchant the next, and a sugar, tobacco, or tea merchant the year after.
He enters
into
every trade, when he foresees that it is likely to lie more than commonly
profitable, and
he
quits it when he foresees that its profits are likely to return to the level of
other trades. His
profits
and losses, therefore, can bear no regular proportion to those of any one
established
and
well-known branch of business. A bold adventurer may sometimes acquire a
considerable
fortune
by two or three successful speculations, but is just as likely to lose one by
two or three
unsuccessful
ones. This trade can be carried on nowhere but in great towns. It is only in
places
of the
most extensive commerce and correspondence that the intelligence requisite for
it can
be had.
The
five circumstances above mentioned, though they occasion considerable
inequalities in
the wages
of labour and profits of stock, occasion none in the whole of the advantages
and
disadvantages,
real or imaginary, of the different employments of either. The nature of those
circumstances
is such, that they make up for a small pecuniary gain in some, and
counterbalance
a great one in others.
In
order, however, that this equality may take place in the whole of their
advantages or
disadvantages,
three things are requisite, even where there is the most perfect freedom. First
the
employments must be well known and long established in the neighbourhood;
secondly,
they
must be in their ordinary, or what may be called their natural state ; and,
thirdly, they
must be
the sole or principal employments of those who occupy them.
First,
This equality can take place only in those employments which are well known,
and have
been
long established in the neighbourhood.
Where
all other circumstances are equal, wages are generally higher in new than in
old trades.
When a
projector attempts to establish a new manufacture, he must at first entice his
workmen
from
other employments, by higher wages than they can either earn in their own
trades, or
than
the nature of his work would otherwise require ; and a considerable time must
pass away
before
he can venture to reduce them to the common level. Manufactures for which the
demand
arises altogether from fashion and fancy, are continually changing, and seldom
last
long
enough to be considered as old established manufactures. Those, on the
contrary, for
which
the demand arises chiefly from use or necessity, are less liable to change, and
the same
form or
fabric may continue in demand for whole centuries together. The wages of
labour,
therefore,
are likely to be higher in manufactures of the former, than in those of the
latter kind.
Birmingham
deals chiefly in manufactures of the former kind ; Sheffield in those of the
latter ;
and the
wages of labour in those two different places are said to be suitable to this
difference
in the
nature of their manufactures.
The
establishment of any new manufacture, of any new branch of commerce, or of any
new
practice
in agriculture, is always a speculation from which the projector promises
himself
extraordinary
profits. These profits sometimes are very great, and sometimes, more
frequently,
perhaps, they are quite otherwise ; but, in general, they bear no regular
proportion
to
those of other old trades in the neighbourhood. If the project succeeds, they
are commonly
at
first very high. When the trade or practice becomes thoroughly established and
well known,
the
competition reduces them to the level of other trades.
Secondly,
this equality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different
employments
of labour and stock, can take place only in the ordinary, or what may be called
the
natural state of those employments.
The
demand for almost every different species of labour is sometimes greater, and
sometimes
less
than usual. In the one case, the advantages of the employment rise above, in
the other
they
fall below the common level. The demand for country labour is greater at
hay-time and
harvest
than during the greater part of the year ; and wages rise with the demand. In
time of
war,
when forty or fifty thousand sailors are forced from the merchant service into
that of the
king,
the demand for sailors to merchant ships necessarily rises with their scarcity
; and their
wages,
upon such occasions, commonly rise from a guinea and seven-and-twenty shillings
to
forty
shilling's and three pounds a-month. In a decaying manufacture, on the
contrary, many
workmen,
rather than quit their own trade, are contented with smaller wages than would
otherwise
be suitable to the nature of their employment.
The
profits of stock vary with the price of the commodities in which it is
employed. As the
price
of any commodity rises above the ordinary or average rate, the profits of at
least some
part of
the stock that is employed in bringing it to market, rise above their proper
level, and as
it
falls they sink below it. All commodities are more or less liable to variations
of price, but
some
are much more so than others. In all commodities which are produced by human
industry,
the quantity of industry annually employed is necessarily regulated by the annual
demand,
in such a manner that the average annual produce may, as nearly as possible, be
equal
to the average annual consumption. In some employments, it has already been
observed,
the
same quantity of industry will always produce the same, or very nearly the same
quantity
of
commodities. In the linen or woollen manufactures, for example, the same number
of hands
will
annually work up very nearly the same quantity of linen and woollen cloth. The
variations
in the market price of such commodities, therefore, can arise only from some
accidental
variation in the demand. A public mourning raises the price of black cloth. But
as
the
demand for most sorts of plain linen and woollen cloth is pretty uniform. so is
likewise the
price.
But there are other employments in which the same quantity of industry will not
always
produce
the same quantity of commodities. The same quantity of industry, for example,
will,
in
different years, produce very different quantities of corn, wine, hops, sugar
tobacco, etc.
The
price of such commodities, therefore, varies not only with the variations of
demand, but
with
the much greater and more frequent variations of quantity, and is consequently
extremely
fluctuating;
but the profit of some of the dealers must necessarily fluctuate with the price
of
the
commodities. The operations of the speculative merchant are principally
employed about
such
commodities. He endeavours to buy them up when he foresees that their price is
likely to
rise,
and to sell them when it is likely to fall.
Thirdly,
this equality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different
employments
of labour and stock, can take place only in such as are the sole or principal
employments
of those who occupy them.
When a
person derives his subsistence from one employment, which does not occupy the
greater
part of his time, in the intervals of his leisure he is often willing to work
at another for
less
wages than would otherwise suit the nature of the employment.
There
still subsists, in many parts of Scotland, a set of people called cottars or
cottagers,
though
they were more frequent some years ago than they are now. They are a sort of
out-servants
of the landlords and farmers. The usual reward which they receive from their
master
is a house, a small garden for pot-herbs, as much grass as will feed a cow,
and,
perhaps,
an acre or two of bad arable land. When their master has occasion for their
labour, he
gives
them, besides, two pecks of oatmeal a-week, worth about sixteen pence sterling.
During
a great
part of the year, he has little or no occasion for their labour, and the
cultivation of their
own
little possession is not sufficient to occupy the time which is left at their
own disposal.
When
such occupiers were more numerous than they are at present, they are said to
have been
willing
to give their spare time for a very small recompence to any body, and to have
wrought
for
less wages than other labourers. In
ancient times, they seem to have been common all
over Europe.
In countries ill cultivated, and worse inhabited, the greater part of landlords
and
farmers
could not otherwise provide themselves with the extraordinary number of hands
which
country labour requires at certain seasons. The daily or weekly recompence
which such
labourers
occasionally received from their masters, was evidently not the whole price of
their
labour.
Their small tenement made a considerable part of it. This daily or weekly
recompence,
however,
seems to have been considered as the whole of it, by many writers who have
collected
the prices of labour and provisions in ancient times, and who have taken
pleasure in
representing
both as wonderfully low.
The
produce of such labour comes frequently cheaper to market than would otherwise
be
suitable
to its nature. Stockings, in many parts of Scotland, are knit much cheaper than
they
can
anywhere be wrought upon the loom. They are the work of servants and labourers
who
derive
the principal part of their subsistence from some other employment. More than a
thousand
pair of Shetland stockings are annually imported into Leith, of which the price
is
from
fivepence to seven-pence a pair. At Lerwick, the small capital of the Shetland
islands,
tenpence
a-day, I have been assured, is a common price of common labour. In the same
islands,
they knit worsted stockings to the value of a guinea a pair and upwards.
The
spinning of linen yarn is carried on in Scotland nearly in the same way as the
knitting of
stockings,
by servants, who are chiefly hired for other purposes. They earn but a very
scanty
subsistence,
who endeavour to get their livelihood by either of those trades. In most parts
of
Scotland,
she is a good spinner who can earn twentypence a-week.
In
opulent countries, the market is generally so extensive, that any one trade is
sufficient to
employ
the whole labour and stock of those who occupy it. Instances of people living
by one
employment, and,
at the same time, deriving some little advantage from another, occur
chiefly
in pour countries. The following instance, however, of something of the same
kind, is
to be
found in the capital of a very rich one. There is no city in Europe, I believe,
in which
house-rent
is dearer than in London, and yet I know no capital in which a furnished
apartment
can be
hired so cheap. Lodging is not only much cheaper in London than in Paris; it is
much
cheaper
than in Edinburgh, of the same degree of goodness ; and, what may seem
extraordinary,
the dearness of house-rent is the cause of the cheapness of lodging. The
dearness
of house-rent in London arises, not only from those causes which render it dear
in all
great
capitals, the dearness of labour, the dearness of all the materials of
building, which must
generally
be brought from a great distance, and, above all, the dearness of ground-rent,
every
landlord
acting the part of a monopolist, and frequently exacting a higher rent for a
single acre
of bad
land in a town, than can be had for a hundred of the best in the country; but
it arises in
part
from the peculiar manners and customs of the people, which oblige every master
of a
family
to hire a whole house from top to bottom. A dwelling-house in England means
every
thing
that is contained under the same roof. In France, Scotland, and many other
parts of
Europe,
it frequently means no more than a single storey. A tradesman in London is
obliged to
hire a
whole house in that part of the town where his customers live. His shop is upon
the
ground
floor, and he and his family sleep in the garret ; and he endeavours to pay a
part of his
house-rent
by letting the two middle storeys to lodgers. He expects to maintain his family
by
his
trade, and not by his lodgers. Whereas at Paris and Edinburgh, people who let lodgings
have
commonly no other means of subsistence ; and the price of the lodging must pay,
not
only
the rent of the house, but the whole expense of the family.
PART
II. ˜ Inequalities occasioned by the
Policy of Europe.
Such
are the inequalities in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the
different
employments
of labour and stock, which the defect of any of the three requisites above
mentioned
must occasion, even where there is the most perfect liberty. But the policy of
Europe,
by not leaving things at perfect liberty, occasions other inequalities of much
greater
importance.
It does
this chiefly in the three following ways. First, by restraining the competition
in some
employments
to a smaller number than would otherwise be disposed to enter into them ;
secondly,
by increasing it in others beyond what it naturally would be; and, thirdly, by
obstructing
the free circulation of labour and stock, both from employment to employment,
and
from place to place.
First,
The policy of Europe occasions a very important inequality in the whole of the
advantages
and disadvantages of the different employments of labour and stock, by
restraining
the
competition in some employments to a smaller number than might otherwise be
disposed
to
enter into them.
The
exclusive privileges of corporations are the principal means it makes use of
for this
purpose.
The
exclusive privilege of an incorporated trade necessarily restrains the
competition, in the
town
where it is established, to those who are free of the trade. To have served an
apprenticeship
in the town, under a master properly qualified, is commonly the necessary
requisite
for obtaining this freedom. The bye-laws of the corporation regulate sometimes
the
number
of apprentices which any master is allowed to have, and almost always the
number of
years
which each apprentice is obliged to serve. The intention of both regulations is
to restrain
the
competition to a much smaller number than might otherwise be disposed to enter
into the
trade.
The limitation of the number of apprentices restrains it directly. A long term
of
apprenticeship
restrains it more indirectly, but as effectually, by increasing the expense of
education.
In
Sheffield, no master cutler can have more than one apprentice at a time, by a
bye-law of the
corporation.
In Norfolk and Norwich, no master weaver can have more than two apprentices,
under
pain of forfeiting five pounds a-month to the king. No master hatter can have
more than
two
apprentices anywhere in England, or in the English plantations, under pain of
forfeiting;
five
pounds a-month, half to the king, and half to him who shall sue in any court of
record.
Both
these regulations, though they have been confirmed by a public law of the
kingdom, are
evidently
dictated by the same corporation-spirit which enacted the bye-law of Sheffield.
The
silk-weavers
in London had scarce been incorporated a year, when they enacted a bye-law,
restraining
any master from having more than two apprentices at a time. It required a
particular
act of parliament to rescind this bye-law.
Seven
years seem anciently to have been, all over Europe, the usual term established
for the
duration
of apprenticeships in the greater part of incorporated trades. All such
incorporations
were
anciently called universities, which, indeed, is the proper Latin name for any
incorporation
whatever. The university of smiths, the university of tailors, etc. are
expressions
which
we commonly meet with in the old charters of ancient towns. When those
particular
incorporations,
which are now peculiarly called universities, were first established, the term
of
years
which it was necessary to study, in order to obtain the degree of master of
arts, appears
evidently
to have been copied from the term of apprenticeship in common trades, of which
the
incorporations
were much more ancient. As to have wrought seven years under a master
properly
qualified, was necessary, in order to entitle my person to become a master, and
to
have
himself apprentices in a common trade ; so to have studied seven years under a
master
properly
qualified. was necessary to entitle him to become a master, teacher, or doctor
(words
anciently
synonymous), in the liberal arts, and to have scholars or apprentices (words
likewise
originally
synonymous) to study under him.
By the
5th of Elizabeth, commonly called the Statute of Apprenticeship, it was
enacted, that
no
person should, for the future, exercise any trade, craft, or mystery, at that
time exercised in
England,
unless he had previously served to it an apprenticeship of seven years at least
; and
what
before had been the bye-law of many particular corporations, became in England
the
general
and public law of all trades carried on in market towns. For though the words
of the
statute
are very general, and seem plainly to include the whole kingdom, by
interpretation its
operation
has been limited to market towns; it having been held that, in country
villages, a
person
may exercise several different trades, though he has not served a seven years
apprenticeship
to each, they being necessary for the conveniency of the inhabitants, and the
number
of people frequently not being sufficient to supply each with a particular set
of hands.
By a
strict interpretation of the words, too, the operation of this statute has been
limited to
those
trades which were established in England before the 5th of Elizabeth, and has
never
been
extended to such as have been introduced since that time. This limitation has
given
occasion
to several distinctions, which, considered as rules of police, appear as
foolish as can
well be
imagined. It has been adjudged, for example, that a coach-maker can neither
himself
make
nor employ journeymen to make his coach-wheels, but must buy them of a master
wheel-wright;
this latter trade having been exercised in England before the 5th of Elizabeth.
But a
wheel-wright, though he has never served an apprenticeship to a coachmaker, may
either
himself make or employ journeymen to make coaches; the trade of a coachmaker
not
being
within the statute, because not exercised in England at the time when it was
made. The
manufactures
of Manchester, Birmingham, and Wolverhampton, are many of them, upon this
account,
not within the statute, not having been exercised in England before the 5th of
Elizabeth.
In
France, the duration of apprenticeships is different in different towns and in
different
trades.
In Paris, five years is the term required in a great number; but, before any
person can
be
qualified to exercise the trade as a master, he must, in many of them, serve
five years more
as a
journeyman. During this latter term, he is called the companion of his master,
and the
term
itself is called his companionship.
In
Scotland, there is no general law which regulates universally the duration of
apprenticeships.
The term is different in different corporations. Where it is long, a part of it
may
generally be redeemed by paying a small fine. In most towns, too, a very small
fine is
sufficient
to purchase the freedom of any corporation. The weavers of linen and hempen
cloth,
the
principal manufactures of the country, as well as all other artificers
subservient to them,
wheel-makers,
reel-makers, etc. may exercise their trades in any town-corporate without
paying
any fine. In all towns-corporate, all persons are free to sell butchers' meat
upon any
lawful
day of the week. Three years is, in Scotland, a common term of apprenticeship,
even in
some
very nice trades; and, in general, I know of no country in Europe, in which
corporation
laws
are so little oppressive.
The
property which every man has in his own labour, as it is the original
foundation of all
other
property, so it is the most sacred and inviolable. The patrimony of a poor man
lies in the
strength
and dexterity of his hands ; and to hinder him from employing this strength and
dexterity
in what manner he thinks proper, without injury to his neighbour. is a plain
violation
of this
most sacred property. It is a
manifest encroachment upon the just liberty, both of the
workman,
and of those who might be disposed to employ him. As it hinders the one from
working
at what he thinks proper, so it hinders the others from employing whom they
think
proper.
To judge whether he is fit to be employed, may surely be trusted to the
discretion of
the
employers, whose interest it so much concerns. The affected anxiety of the
lawgiver, lest
they
should employ an improper person, is evidently as impertinent as it is
oppressive.
The
institution of long apprenticeships can give no security that insufficient
workmanship
shall
not frequently be exposed to public sale. When this is done, it is generally
the effect of
fraud,
and not of inability ; and the longest apprenticeship can give no security
against fraud.
Quite
different regulations are necessary to prevent this abuse. The sterling mark
upon plate,
and the
stamps upon linen and woollen cloth, give the purchaser much greater security
than
any
statute of apprenticeship. He generally looks at these, but never thinks it
worth while to
enquire
whether the workman had served a seven years apprenticeship.
The
institution of long apprenticeships has no tendency to form young people to
industry. A
journeyman
who works by the piece is likely to be industrious, because he derives a
benefit
from
every exertion of his industry. An apprentice is likely to be idle, and almost
always is so,
because
he has no immediate interest to be otherwise. In the inferior employments, the
sweets
of
labour consist altogether in the recompence of labour. They who are soonest in
a condition
to
enjoy the sweets of it, are likely soonest to conceive a relish for it, and to
acquire the early
habit
of industry. A young man naturally conceives an aversion to labour, when for a
long
time he
receives no benefit from it. The boys who are put out apprentices from public
charities
are
generally bound for more than the usual number of years, and they generally
turn out very
idle
and worthless.
Apprenticeships
were altogether unknown to the ancients. The reciprocal duties of master and
apprentice
make a considerable article in every modern code. The Roman law is perfectly
silent
with regard to them. I know no Greek or Latin word (I might venture, I believe,
to assert
that
there is none) which expresses the idea we now annex to the word apprentice, a
servant
bound
to work at a particular trade for the benefit of a master, during a term of
years, upon
condition
that the master shall teach him that trade.
Long
apprenticeships are altogether unnecessary. The arts, which are much superior
to
common
trades, such as those of making clocks and watches, contain no such mystery as
to
require
a long course of instruction. The first invention of such beautiful machines,
indeed,
and
even that of some of the instruments employed in making them, must no doubt
have been
the
work of deep thought and long time, and may justly be considered as among the
happiest
efforts
of human ingenuity. But when both have been fairly invented, and are well
understood,
to
explain to any young man, in the completest manner, how to apply the
instruments, and
how to
construct the machines, cannot well require more than the lessons of a few
weeks;
perhaps
those of a few days might be sufficient. In the common mechanic trades, those
of a
few
days might certainly be sufficient. The dexterity of hand, indeed, even in
common trades,
cannot
be acquired without much practice and experience. But a young man would
practice
with
much more diligence and attention, if from the beginning he wrought as a
journeyman,
being
paid in proportion to the little work which he could execute, and paying in his
turn for
the
materials which he might sometimes spoil through awkwardness and inexperience.
His
education
would generally in this way be more effectual, and always less tedious and
expensive.
The master, indeed, would be a loser. He would lose all the wages of the
apprentice,
which he now saves, for seven years together. In the end, perhaps, the
apprentice
himself
would he a loser. In a trade so easily learnt he would have more competitors,
and his
wages,
when he came to be a complete workman, would be much less than at present. The
same
increase of competition would reduce the profits of the masters, as well as the
wages of
workmen.
The trades, the crafts, the mysteries, would all be losers. But the public
would be a
gainer,
the work of all artificers coming in this way much cheaper to market.
It is
to prevent his reduction of price, and consequently of wages and profit, by
restraining that
free
competition which would most certainly occasion it, that all corporations, and
the greater
part of
corporation laws have been established. In order to erect a corporation, no
other
authority
in ancient times was requisite, in many parts of Europe, but that of the
town-corporate
in which it was established. In
England, indeed, a charter from the king was
likewise
necessary. But this prerogative of
the crown seems to have been reserved rather for
extorting
money from the subject, than for the defence of the common liberty against such
oppressive
monopolies. Upon paying a fine to the king, the charter seems generally to have
been
readily granted ; and when any particular class of artificers or traders
thought proper to
act as a
corporation, without a charter, such adulterine guilds, as they were called,
were not
always
disfranchised upon that account, but obliged to fine annually to the king, for
permission
to exercise their usurped privileges {See Madox Firma Burgi p. 26 etc.}. The
immediate
inspection of all corporations, and of the bye-laws which they might think
proper
to
enact for their own government, belonged to the town-corporate in which they
were
established;
and whatever discipline was exercised over them, proceeded commonly, not from
the
king, but from that greater incorporation of which those subordinate ones were
only parts
or
members.
The
government of towns-corporate was altogether in the hands of traders and
artificers, and it
was the
manifest interest of every particular class of them, to prevent the market from
being
overstocked,
as they commonly express it, with their own particular species of industry;
which
is in
reality to keep it always understocked. Each class was eager to establish
regulations
proper
for this purpose, and, provided it was allowed to do so, was willing to consent
that
every
other class should do the same. In consequence of such regulations, indeed,
each class
was
obliged to buy the goods they had occasion for from every other within the
town,
somewhat
dearer than they otherwise might have done. But, in recompence, they were
enabled
to sell their own just as much dearer ; so that, so far it was as broad as
long, as they
say ;
and in the dealings of the different classes within the town with one another,
none of
them
were losers by these regulations.
But in their dealings with the country they were all
great
gainers; and in these latter dealings consist the whole trade which supports
and enriches
every
town.
Every town
draws its whole subsistence, and all the materials of its industry, from the:
country.
It pays for these chiefly in two ways. First, by sending back to the country a
part of
those
materials wrought up and manufactured ; in which case, their price is augmented
by the
wages
of the workmen, and the profits of their masters or immediate employers ;
secondly, by
sending
to it a part both of the rude and manufactured produce, either of other
countries, or of
distant
parts of the same country, imported into the town; in which case, too, the
original price
of
those goods is augmented by the wages of the carriers or sailors, and by the
profits of the
merchants
who employ them. In what is gained upon the first of those branches of
commerce,
consists
the advantage which the town makes by its manufactures; in what is gained upon
the
second,
the advantage of its inland and foreign trade. The wages of the workmen, and
the
profits
of their different employers, make up the whole of what is gained upon both.
Whatever
regulations,
therefore, tend to increase those wages and profits beyond what they otherwise:
would
be, tend to enable the town to purchase, with a smaller quantity of its labour,
the
produce
of a greater quantity of the labour of the country. They give the traders and
artificers
in the
town an advantage over the landlords, farmers, and labourers, in the country,
and break
down
that natural equality which would otherwise take place in the commerce which is
carried
on between them. The whole annual produce of the labour of the society is
annually
divided
between those two different sets of people. By means of those regulations, a
greater
share
of it is given to the inhabitants of the town than would otherwise fall to
them, and a less
to
those of' the country.
The
price which the town really pays for the provisions and materials annually
imported into
it, is
the quantity of manufactures and other goods annually exported from it. The
dearer the
latter
are sold, the cheaper the former are bought. The industry of the town becomes
more, and
that of
the country less advantageous.
That
the industry which is carried on in towns is, everywhere in Europe, more
advantageous
than
that which is carried on in the country, without entering into any very nice
computations,
we may
satisfy ourselves by one very simple and obvious observation. In every country
of
Europe,
we find at least a hundred people who have acquired great fortunes, from small
beginnings,
by trade and manufactures, the industry which properly belongs to towns, for
one
who has
done so by that which properly belongs to the country, the raising of rude
produce by
the
improvement and cultivation of land.
Industry, therefore, must be better rewarded, the
wages
of labour and the profits of stock must evidently be greater, in the one
situation than in
the
other. But stock and labour naturally seek the most advantageous employment.
They
naturally,
therefore, resort as much as they can to the town, and desert the country.
The
inhabitants of a town being collected into one place, can easily combine
together. The
most
insignificant trades carried on in towns have, accordingly, in some place or
other, been
incorporated
; and even where they have never been incorporated, yet the corporation-spirit,
the
jealousy of strangers, the aversion to take apprentices, or to communicate the
secret of
their
trade, generally prevail in them, and often teach them, by voluntary
associations and
agreements,
to prevent that free competition which they cannot prohibit by bye-laws. The
trades
which employ but a small number of hands, run most easily into such
combinations.
Half-a-dozen
wool-combers, perhaps, are necessary to keep a thousand spinners and weavers
at
work. By combining not to take apprentices, they can not only engross the
employment, but
reduce
the whole manufacture into a sort of slavery to themselves, and raise the price
of their
labour
much above what is due to the nature of their work.
The
inhabitants of the country, dispersed in distant places, cannot easily combine
together.
They
have not only never been incorporated, but the incorporation spirit never has
prevailed
among
them. No apprenticeship has ever been thought necessary to qualify for
husbandry, the
great
trade of the country. After what are called the fine arts, and the liberal
professions,
however,
there is perhaps no trade which requires so great a variety of knowledge and
experience.
The innumerable volumes which have been written upon it in all languages, may
satisfy
us, that among the wisest and most learned nations, it has never been regarded
as a
matter
very easily understood. And from all those volumes we shall in vain attempt to
collect
that
knowledge of its various and complicated operations which is commonly possessed
even
by the
common farmer ; how contemptuously soever the very contemptible authors of some
of
them
may sometimes affect to speak of him. There is scarce any common mechanic
trade, on
the
contrary, of which all the operations may not be as completely and distinctly
explained in
a
pamphlet of a very few pages, as it is possible for words illustrated by
figures to explain
them.
In the history of the arts, now publishing by the French Academy of Sciences,
several of
them
are actually explained in this manner. The direction of operations, besides,
which must
be
varied with every change of the weather, as well as with many other accidents,
requires
much
more judgment and discretion, than that of those which are always the same, or
very
nearly
the same.
Not
only the art of the farmer, the general direction of the operations of
husbandry, but many
inferior
branches of country labour require much more skill and experience than the
greater
part of
mechanic trades. The man who works upon brass and iron, works with instruments,
and
upon materials of which the temper is always the same, or very nearly the same.
But the
man who
ploughs the ground with a team of horses or oxen, works with instruments of
which
the
health, strength, and temper, are very different upon different occasions. The
condition of
the
materials which he works upon, too, is as variable as that of the instruments
which he
works
with, and both require to be managed with much judgment and discretion. The
common
ploughman,
though generally regarded as the pattern of stupidity and ignorance, is seldom
defective
in this judgment and discretion. He is less accustomed, indeed, to social
intercourse,
than
the mechanic who lives in a town. His voice and language are more uncouth, and
more
difficult
to be understood by those who are not used to them. His understanding, however,
being
accustomed to consider a greater variety of objects, is generally much superior
to that of
the
other, whose whole attention, from morning till night, is commonly occupied in
performing
one or two very simple operations. How much the lower ranks of people in the
country
are really superior to those of the town, is well known to every man whom
either
business
or curiosity has led to converse much with both. In China and Indostan,
accordingly,
both
the rank and the wages of country labourers are said to be superior to those of
the greater
part of
artificers and manufacturers. They would probably be so everywhere, if
corporation
laws
and the corporation spirit did not prevent it.
The
superiority which the industry of the towns has everywhere in Europe over that
of the
country,
is not altogether owing to corporations and corporation laws. It is supported
by many
other
regulations. The high duties upon foreign manufactures, and upon all goods
imported by
alien
merchants, all tend to the same purpose. Corporation laws enable the
inhabitants of
towns
to raise their prices, without fearing to be undersold by the free competition
of their
own countrymen.
Those other regulations secure them equally against that of foreigners. The
enhancement
of price occasioned by both is everywhere finally paid by the landlords,
farmers,
and
labourers, of the country, who have seldom opposed the establishment of such
monopolies.
They have commonly neither inclination nor fitness to enter into combinations;
and the
clamour and sophistry of merchants and manufacturers easily persuade them, that
the
private
interest of a part, and of a subordinate part, of the society, is the general
interest of the
whole.
In
Great Britain, the superiority of the industry of the towns over that of the
country seems to
have
been greater formerly than in the present times. The wages of country labour
approach
nearer
to those of manufacturing labour, and the profits of stock employed in
agriculture to
those
of trading and manufacturing stock, than they are said to have none in the last
century,
or in
the beginning of the present. This change may be regarded as the necessary,
though very
late
consequence of the extraordinary encouragement given to the industry of the
towns. The
stocks
accumulated in them come in time to be so great, that it can no longer be
employed
with
the ancient profit in that species of industry which is peculiar to them. That
industry has
its
limits like every other ; and the increase of stock, by increasing the
competition,
necessarily
reduces the profit. The lowering of profit in the town forces out stock to the
country,
where, by creating a new demand for country labour, it necessarily raises its
wages. It
then
spreads itself, if I my say so, over the face of the land, and, by being
employed in
agriculture,
is in part restored to the country, at the expense of which, in a great
measure, it
had originally
been accumulated in the town. That everywhere in Europe the greatest
improvements
of the country have been owing to such over flowings of the stock originally
accumulated
in the towns, I shall endeavour to shew hereafter, and at the same time to
demonstrate,
that though some countries have, by this course, attained to a considerable
degree
of opulence, it is in itself necessarily slow, uncertain, liable to be
disturbed and
interrupted
by innumerable accidents, and, in every respect, contrary to the order of
nature and
of
reason The interests, prejudices, laws, and customs, which have given occasion
to it, I shall
endeavour
to explain as fully and distinctly as I can in the third and fourth books of
this
Inquiry.
People
of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but
the
conversation
ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise
prices. It
is
impossible, indeed, to prevent such meetings, by any law which either could be
executed, or
would
be consistent with liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder people
of the
same
trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to do nothing to facilitate
such
assemblies,
much less to render them necessary.
A
regulation which obliges all those of the same trade in a particular town to
enter their names
and
places of abode in a public register, facilitates such assemblies. It connects
individuals
who
might never otherwise be known to one another, and gives every man of the trade
a
direction
where to find every other man of it.
A
regulation which enables those of the same trade to tax themselves, in order to
provide for
their
poor, their sick, their widows and orphans, by giving them a common interest to
manage,
renders
such assemblies necessary.
An
incorporation not only renders them necessary, but makes the act of the
majority binding
upon
the whole. In a free trade, an effectual combination cannot be established but
by the
unanimous
consent of every single trader, and it cannot last longer than every single
trader
continues
of the same mind. The majority of a corporation can enact a bye-law, with
proper
penalties,
which will limit the competition more effectually and more durably than any
voluntary
combination what. ever.
The
pretence that corporations are necessary for the better government of the
trade, is without
any
foundation. The real and effectual discipline which is exercised over a
workman, is not
that of
his corporation, but that of his customers. It is the fear of losing their
employment
which
restrains his frauds and corrects his negligence. An exclusive corporation
necessarily
weakens
the force of this discipline. A particular set of workmen must then be
employed, let
them
behave well or ill. It is upon this account that, in many large incorporated
towns, no
tolerable
workmen are to be found, even in some of the most necessary trades. If you
would
have
your work tolerably executed, it must be done in the suburbs, where the
workmen,
having
no exclusive privilege, have nothing but their character to depend upon, and
you must
then
smuggle it into the town as well as you can.
It is
in this manner that the policy of Europe, by restraining the competition in
some
employments
to a smaller number than would otherwise be disposed to enter into them,
occasions
a very important inequality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of
the
different
employments of labour and stock.
Secondly,
The policy of Europe, by increasing the competition in some employments beyond
what it
naturally would be, occasions another inequality, of an opposite kind, in the
whole of
the
advantages and disadvantages of the different employments of labour and stock.
It has
been considered as of so much importance that a proper number of young people
should
be
educated for certain professions, that sometimes the public, and sometimes the
piety of
private
founders, have established many pensions, scholarships, exhibitions, bursaries,
etc. for
this
purpose, which draw many more people into those trades than could otherwise
pretend to
follow
them. In all Christian countries, I believe, the education of the greater part
of
churchmen
is paid for in this manner. Very few of them are educated altogether at their own
expense.
The long, tedious, and expensive education, therefore, of those who are, will
not
always
procure them a suitable reward, the church being crowded with people, who, in
order
to get
employment, are willing to accept of a much smaller recompence than what such
an
education
would otherwise have entitled them to ; and in this manner the competition of
the
poor
takes away the reward of the rich. It would be indecent, no doubt, to compare
either a
curate
or a chaplain with a journeyman in any common trade. The pay of a curate or
chaplain,
however,
may very properly be considered as of the same nature with the wages of a
journeyman.
They are all three paid for their work according to the contract which they may
happen
to make with their respective superiors. Till after the middle of the
fourteenth century,
five
merks, containing about as much silver as ten pounds of our present money, was
in
England
the usual pay of a curate or a stipendiary parish priest, as we find it
regulated by the
decrees
of several different national councils. At the same period, fourpence a-day,
containing
the
same quantity of silver as a shilling of our present money, was declared to be
the pay of a
master
mason; and threepence a-day, equal to ninepence of our present money, that of a
journeyman
mason. {See the Statute of Labourers, 25, Ed. III.} The wages of both these
labourer's,
therefore, supposing them to have been constantly employed, were much superior
to
those of the curate. The wages of the master mason, supposing him to have been
without
employment
one-third of the year, would have fully equalled them. By the 12th of Queen
Anne,
c. 12. it is declared, "That whereas, for want of sufficient maintenance
and
encouragement
to curates, the cures have, in several places, been meanly supplied, the bishop
is,
therefore, empowered to appoint, by writing under his hand and seal, a
sufficient certain
stipend
or allowance, not exceeding fifty, and not less than twenty pounds
a-year". Forty
pounds
a-year is reckoned at present very good pay for a curate; and, notwithstanding
this act
of
parliament, there are many curacies under twenty pounds a-year. There are
journeymen
shoemakers
in London who earn forty pounds a-year, and there is scarce an industrious
workman
of any kind in that metropolis who does not earn more than twenty. This last
sum,
indeed,
does not exceed what frequently earned by common labourers in many country
parishes.
Whenever the law has attempted to regulate the wages of workmen, it has always
been
rather to lower them than to raise them. But the law has, upon many occasions,
attempted
to raise the wages of curates, and, for the dignity of the church, to oblige
the rectors
of
parishes to give them more than the wretched maintenance which they themselves
might be
willing
to accept of. And, in both cases, the law seems to have been equally
ineffectual, and
has
never either been able to raise the wages of curates, or to sink those of
labourers to the
degree
that was intended; because it has never been able to hinder either the one from
being
willing
to accept of less than the legal allowance, on account of the indigence of
their situation
and the
multitude of their competitors, or the other from receiving more, on account of
the
contrary
competition of those who expected to derive either profit or pleasure from
employing
them.
The
great benefices and other ecclesiastical dignities support the honour of the
church.
notwithstanding
the mean circumstances of some of its inferior members. The respect paid to
the
profession, too, makes some compensation even to them for the meanness of their
pecuniary
recompence. In England, and in all Roman catholic countries, the lottery of the
church
is in reality much more advantageous than is necessary. The example of the
churches
of
Scotland, of Geneva, and of several other protestant churches, may satisfy us,
that in so
creditable
a profession, in which education is so easily procured, the hopes of much more
moderate
benefices will draw a sufficient number of learned, decent, and respectable men
into
holy
orders.
In
professions in which there are no benefices, such as law and physic, if an
equal proportion
of
people were educated at the public expense, the competition would soon be so
great as to
sink
very much their pecuniary reward. It might then not be worth any man's while to
educate
his son
to either of those professions at his own expense. They would be entirely
abandoned to
such as
had been educated by those public charities, whose numbers and necessities
would
oblige
them in general to content themselves with a very miserable recompence, to the
entire
degradation
of the now respectable professions of law and physic.
That
unprosperous race of men, commonly called men of letters, are pretty much in
the
situation
which lawyers and physicians probably would be in, upon the foregoing
supposition.
In
every part of Europe, the greater part of them have been educated for the
church, but have
been
hindered by different reasons from entering into holy orders. They have
generally,
therefore,
been educated at the public expense; and their numbers are everywhere so great,
as
commonly
to reduce the price of their labour to a very paltry recompence.
Before
the invention of the art of printing, the only employment by which a man of
letters
could
make any thing by his talents, was that of a public or private teacher, or by
communicating
to other people the curious and useful knowledge which he had acquired
himself
; and this is still surely a more honourable, a more useful, and, in general,
even a more
profitable
employment than that other of writing for a bookseller, to which the art of
printing
has
given occasion. The time and study, the genius, knowledge, and application
requisite to
qualify
an eminent teacher of the sciences, are at least equal to what is necessary for
the
greatest
practitioners in law and physic. But the usual reward of the eminent teacher
bears no
proportion
to that of the lawyer or physician, because the trade of the one is crowded
with
indigent
people, who have been brought up to it at the public expense ; whereas those of
the
other
two are encumbered with very few who have not been educated at their own. The
usual
recompence,
however, of public and private teachers, small as it may appear, would
undoubtedly
be less than it is, if the competition of those yet more indigent men of
letters,
who
write for bread, was not taken out of the market. Before the invention of the
art of
printing,
a scholar and a beggar seem to have been terms very nearly synonymous. The
different
governors of the universities, before that time, appear to have often granted
licences
to
their scholars to beg.
In
ancient times, before any charities of this kind had been established for the
education of
indigent
people to the learned professions, the rewards of eminent teachers appear to
have
been
much more considerable. Isocrates, in what is called his discourse against the
sophists.
reproaches
the teachers of his own times with inconsistency. 'They make the most
magnificent
promises
to their scholars," says he, " and undertake to teach them to be
wise, to be happy,
and to
be just; and, in return for so important a service, they stipulate the paltry
reward of four
or five
minae." "They who teach wisdom," continues he, "ought
certainly to be wise
themselves
; but if any man were to sell such a bargain for such a price, he would be
convicted
of the most evident folly." He certainly does not mean here to exaggerate
the
reward,
and we may be assured that it was not less than he represents it. Four minae
were
equal
to thirteen pounds six shillings and eightpence ; five minae to sixteen pounds
thirteen
shillings
and fourpence.Something not less than the largest of those two sums, therefore,
must
at that
time have been usually paid to the most eminent teachers at Athens. Isocrates
himself
demanded
ten minae, or £ 33:6:8 from each scholar. When he taught at Athens, he is said
to
have
had a hundred scholars. I understand this to be the number whom he taught at
one time,
or who
attended what we would call one course of lectures ; a number which will not
appear
extraordinary
from so great a city to so famous a teacher, who taught, too, what was at that
time
the most fashionable of all sciences, rhetoric. He must have made, therefore,
by each
course
of lectures, a thousand minae, or £ 3335:6:8. A thousand minae, accordingly, is
said by
Plutarch,
in another place, to have been his didactron, or usual price of teaching. Many
other
eminent
teachers in those times appear to have acquired great fortunes. Georgias made a
present
to the temple of Delphi of his own statue in solid gold. We must not, I
presume,
suppose
that it was as large as the life. His way of living, as well as that of Hippias
and
Protagoras,
two other eminent teachers of those times, is represented by Plato as splendid,
even to
ostentation. Plato himself is said to have lived with a good deal of
magnificence.
Aristotle,
after having been tutor to Alexander, and most munificently rewarded, as it is
universally
agreed, both by him and his father, Philip, thought it worth while,
notwithstanding,
to return to Athens, in order to resume the teaching of his school. Teachers
of the
sciences were probably in those times less common than they came to be in an
age or
two
afterwards, when the competition had probably somewhat reduced both the price
of their
labour
and the admiration for their persons. The most eminent of them, however, appear
always
to have enjoyed a degree of consideration much superior to any of the like
profession
in the
present times. The Athenians sent Carneades the academic, and Diogenes the
stoic,
upon a
solemn embassy to Rome; and though their city had then declined from its former
grandeur,
it was still an independent and considerable republic.
Carneades,
too, was a Babylonian by birth; and as there never was a people more jealous of
admitting
foreigners to public offices than the Athenians, their consideration for him
must
have
been very great.
This
inequality is, upon the whole, perhaps rather advantageous than hurtful to the
public. It
may
somewhat degrade the profession of a public teacher ; but the cheapness of
literary
education
is surely an advantage which greatly overbalances this trifling inconveniency.
The
public,
too, might derive still greater benefit from it, if the constitution of those
schools and
colleges,
in which education is carried on, was more reasonable than it is at present
through
the
greater part of Europe.
Thirdly,
the policy of Europe, by obstructing the free circulation of labour and stock,
both
from
employment to employment, and from place to place, occasions, in some cases, a
very
inconvenient
inequality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of their different
employments.
The
statute of apprenticeship obstructs the free circulation of labour from one
employment to
another,
even in the same place. The exclusive privileges of corporations obstruct it
from one
place
to another, even in the same employment.
It
frequently happens, that while high wages are given to the workmen in one
manufacture,
those
in another are obliged to content themselves with bare subsistence. The one is
in an
advancing
state, and has therefore a continual demand for new hands ; the other is in a
declining
state, and the superabundance of hands is continually increasing. Those two
manufactures
may sometimes be in the same town, and sometimes in the same
neighbourhood,
without being able to lend the least assistance to one another. The statute of
apprenticeship
may oppose it in the one case, and both that and an exclusive corporation in
the
other.
In many different manufactures, however, the operations are so much alike, that
the
workmen
could easily change trades with one another, if those absurd laws did not
hinder
them.
The arts of weaving plain linen and plain silk, for example, are almost
entirely the
same.
That of weaving plain woollen is somewhat different ; but the difference is so
insignificant,
that either a linen or a silk weaver might become a tolerable workman in a very
few
days. If any of those three capital manufactures, therefore, were decaying, the
workmen
might
find a resource in one of the other two which was in a more prosperous condition;
and
their
wages would neither rise too high in the thriving, nor sink too low in the
decaying
manufacture.
The linen manufacture, indeed, is in England, by a particular statute, open to
every
body ; but as it is not much cultivated through the greater part of the
country, it can
afford
no general resource to the work men of other decaying manufactures, who,
wherever
the
statute of apprenticeship takes place, have no other choice, but dither to come
upon the
parish,
or to work as common labourers ; for which, by their habits, they are much
worse
qualified
than for any sort of manufacture that bears any resemblance to their own. They
generally,
therefore, chuse to come upon the parish.
Whatever
obstructs the free circulation of labour from one employment to another,
obstructs
that of
stock likewise; the quantity of stock which can be employed in any branch of
business
depending
very much upon that of the labour which can be employed in it. Corporation
laws,
however,
give less obstruction to the free circulation of stock from one place to
another, than
to that
of labour. It is everywhere much easier for a wealthy merchant to obtain the
privilege
of
trading in a town-corporate, than for a poor artificer to obtain that of
working in it.
The obstruction
which corporation laws give to the free circulation of labour is common, I
believe,
to every part of Europe. That which is given to it by the poor laws is, so far
as I know,
peculiar
to England. It consists in the difficulty which a poor man finds in obtaining a
settlement,
or even in being allowed to exercise his industry in any parish but that to
which he
belongs.
It is the labour of artificers and manufacturers only of which the free
circulation is
obstructed
by corporation laws. The difficulty of obtaining settlements obstructs even
that of
common
labour. It may be worth while to give some account of the rise, progress, and
present
state
of this disorder, the greatest, perhaps, of any in the police of England.
When,
by the destruction of monasteries, the poor had been deprived of the charity of
those
religious
houses, after some other ineffectual attempts for their relief, it was enacted,
by the
43d of
Elizabeth, c. 2. that every parish should be bound to provide for its own poor,
and that
overseers
of the poor should be annually appointed, who, with the church-wardens, should
raise,
by a parish rate, competent sums for this purpose.
By this
statute, the necessity of providing for their own poor was indispensably
imposed upon
every
parish. Who were to be considered as the poor of each parish became, therefore,
a
question
of some importance. This question, after some variation, was at last determined
by
the
13th and 14th of Charles II. when it was enacted, that forty days undisturbed
residence
should
gain any person a settlement in any parish; but that within that time it should
be lawful
for two
justices of the peace, upon complaint made by the church-wardens or overseers
of the
poor,
to remove any new inhabitant to the parish where he was last legally settled ;
unless he
either
rented a tenement of ten pounds a-year, or could give such security for the
discharge of
the
parish where he was then living, as those justices should judge sufficient.
Some
frauds, it is said, were committed in consequence of this statute; parish
officers
sometime's
bribing their own poor to go clandestinely to another parish, and, by keeping
themselves
concealed for forty days, to gain a settlement there, to the discharge of that
to
which
they properly belonged. It was enacted, therefore, by the 1st of James II. that
the forty
days
undisturbed residence of any person necessary to gain a settlement, should be
accounted
only
from the time of his delivering notice, in writing, of the place of his abode
and the
number
of his family, to one of the church-wardens or overseers of the parish where he
came
to
dwell.
But
parish officers, it seems, were not always more honest with regard to their own
than they
had
been with regard to other parishes, and sometimes connived at such intrusions,
receiving
the
notice, and taking no proper steps in consequence of it. As every person in a
parish,
therefore,
was supposed to have an interest to prevent as much as possible their being
burdened
by such intruders, it was further enacted by the 3rd of William III. that the
forty
days
residence should be accounted only from the publication of such notice in
writing on
Sunday
in the church, immediately after divine service.
"
After all," says Doctor Burn, "this kind of settlement, by continuing
forty days after
publication
of notice in writing, is very seldom obtained ; and the design of the acts is
not so
much
for gaining of settlements, as for the avoiding of them by persons coming into
a parish
clandestinely,
for the giving of notice is only putting a force upon the parish to remove. But
if
a
person's situation is such, that it is doubtful whether he is actually
removable or not, he
shall,
by giving of notice, compel the parish either to allow him a settlement
uncontested, by
suffering
him to continue forty days, or by removing him to try the right."
This
statute, therefore, rendered it almost impracticable for a poor man to gain a
new
settlement
in the old way, by forty days inhabitancy. But that it might not appear to
preclude
altogether
the common people of one' parish from ever establishing themselves with
security
in
another, it appointed four other ways by which a settlement might be gained
without any
notice
delivered or published. The first was, by being taxed to parish rates and
paying them;
the
second, by being elected into an annual parish office, and serving in it a year
; the third, by
serving
an apprenticeship in the parish ; the fourth, by being hired into service there
for a year,
and
continuing in the same service during the whole of it. Nobody can gain a
settlement by
either
of the two first ways, but by the public deed of the whole parish, who are too
well
aware
of the consequences to adopt any new-comer, who has nothing but his labour to
support
him,
either by taxing him to parish rates, or by electing him into a parish office.
No
married man can well gain any settlement in either of the two last ways. An
apprentice is
scarce
ever married ; and it is expressly enacted, that no married servant shall gain
any
settlement
by being hired for a year. The principal effect of introducing settlement by
service,
has
been to put out in a great measure the old fashion of hiring for a year; which
before had
been so
customary in England, that even at this day, if no particular term is agreed
upon, the
law
intends that every servant is hired for a year. But masters are not always
willing to give
their
servants a settlement by hiring them in this manner ; and servants are not
always willing
to be
so hired, because, as every last settlement discharges all the foregoing, they
might
thereby
lose their original settlement in the places of their nativity, the habitation
of their
parents
and relations.
No
independent workman, it is evident, whether labourer or artificer, is likely to
gain any new
settlement,
either by apprenticeship or by service. When such a person, therefore, carried
his
industry
to a new parish, he was liable to be removed, how healthy and industrious
soever, at
the
caprice of any churchwarden or overseer, unless he either rented a tenement of
ten pounds
a-year,
a thing impossible for one who has nothing but his labour to live by, or could
give
such
security for the discharge of the parish as two justices of the peace should
judge
sufficient.
What
security they shall require, indeed, is left altogether to their discretion;
but they cannot
well
require less than thirty pounds, it having been enacted, that the purchase even
of a
freehold
estate of less than thirty pounds value, shall not gain any person a
settlement, as not
being
sufficient for the discharge of the parish. But this is a security which scarce
any man
who
lives by labour can give; and much greater security is frequently demanded.
In
order to restore, in some measure, that free circulation of labour which those
different
statutes
had almost entirely taken away, the invention of certificates was fallen upon.
By the
8th and
9th of William III. it was enacted that if any person should bring a
certificate from the
parish
where he was last legally settled, subscribed by the church-wardens and
overseers of
the
poor, and allowed by two justices of the peace, that every other parish should
be obliged to
receive
him; that he should not be removable merely upon account of his being likely to
become
chargeable, but only upon his becoming actually chargeable ; and that then the
parish
which
granted the certificate should be obliged to pay the expense both of his
maintenance
and of
his removal. And in order to give the most perfect security to the parish where
such
certificated
man should come to reside, it was further enacted by the same statute, that he
should
gain no settlement there by any means whatever, except either by renting a
tenement of
ten
pounds a-year, or by serving upon his own account in an annual parish office
for one
whole
year ; and consequently neither by notice nor by service, nor by
apprenticeship, nor by
paying
parish rates. By the 12th of Queen Anne, too, stat. 1, c.18, it was further
enacted, that
neither
the servants nor apprentices of such certificated man should gain any
settlement in the
parish
where he resided under such certificate.
How far
this invention has restored that free circulation of labour, which the
preceding
statutes
had almost entirely taken away, we may learn from the following very judicious
observation
of Doctor Burn. "It is obvious," says he, " that there are
divers good reasons for
requiring
certificates with persons coming to settle in any place; namely, that persons
residing
under
them can gain no settlement, neither by apprenticeship, nor by service, nor by
giving
notice,
nor by paying parish rates; that they can settle neither apprentices nor
servants ; that if
they
become chargeable, it is certainly known whither to remove them, and the parish
shall be
paid
for the removal, and for their maintenance in the mean time ; and that, if they
fall sick,
and
cannot be removed, the parish which gave the certificate must maintain them ;
none of all
which
can be without a certificate. Which reasons will hold proportionably for
parishes not
granting
certificates in ordinary cases; for it is far more than an equal chance, but
that they
will
have the certificated persons again, and in a worse condition." The moral
of this
observation
seems to be, that certificates ought always to be required by the parish where
any
poor
man comes to reside, and that they ought very seldom to be granted by that
which he
purposes
to leave. " There is somewhat of hardship in this matter of
certificates," says the
same
very intelligent author, in his History of the Poor Laws, "by putting it
in the power of a
parish
officer to imprison a man as it were for life, however inconvenient it may be
for him to
continue
at that place where he has had the misfortune to acquire what is called a
settlement,
or
whatever advantage he may propose himself by living elsewhere."
Though
a certificate carries along with it no testimonial of good behaviour, and
certifies
nothing
but that the person belongs to the parish to which he really does belong, it is
altogether
discretionary in the parish officers either to grant or to refuse it. A
mandamus was
once
moved for, says Doctor Burn, to compel the church-wardens and overseers to sign
a
certificate;
but the Court of King's Bench rejected the motion as a very strange attempt.
The
very unequal price of labour which we frequently find in England, in places at
no great
distance
from one another, is probably owing to the obstruction which the law of
settlements
gives
to a poor man who would carry his industry from one parish to another without a
certificate.
A single man, indeed who is healthy and industrious, may sometimes reside by
sufferance
without one ; but a man with a wife and family who should attempt to do so,
would,
in most parishes, be sure of being removed ; and, if the single man should
afterwards
marry,
he would generally be removed likewise. The scarcity of hands in one parish,
therefore,
cannot always be relieved by their superabundance in another, as it is
constantly in
Scotland,
and. I believe, in all other countries where there is no difficulty of
settlement. In
such
countries, though wages may sometimes rise a little in the neighbourhood of a
great
town,
or wherever else there is an extraordinary demand for labour, and sink
gradually as the
distance
from such places increases, till they fall back to the common rate of the
country ; yet
we
never meet with those sudden and unaccountable differences in the wages of
neighbouring
places
which we sometimes find in England, where it is often more difficult for a poor
man to
pass
the artificial boundary of a parish, than an arm of the sea, or a ridge of high
mountains,
natural
boundaries which sometimes separate very distinctly different rates of wages in
other
countries.
To
remove a man who has committed no misdemeanour, from the parish where he
chooses to
reside,
is an evident violation of natural liberty and justice. The common people of
England,
however,
so jealous of their liberty, but like the common people of most other
countries, never
rightly
understanding wherein it consists, have now, for more than a century together,
suffered
themselves
to be exposed to this oppression without a remedy. Though men of reflection,
too,
have
some. times complained of the law of settlements as a public grievance ; yet it
has never
been
the object of any general popular clamour, such as that against general
warrants, an
abusive
practice undoubtedly, but such a one as was not likely to occasion any general
oppression.
There is scarce a poor man in England, of forty years of age, 1 will venture to
say,
who has
not, in some part of his life, felt himself most cruelly oppressed by this
ill-contrived
law of
settlements.
I shall
conclude this long chapter with observing, that though anciently it was usual
to rate
wages,
first by general laws extending over the whole kingdom, and afterwards by
particular
orders
of the justices of peace in every particular county, both these practices have
now gone
entirely
into disuse " By the experience of above four hundred years," says
Doctor Burn, " it
seems
time to lay aside all endeavours to bring under strict regulations, what in its
own nature
seems
incapable of minute limitation ; for if all persons in the same kind of work
were to
receive
equal wages, there would be no emulation, and no room left for industry or
ingenuity."
Particular
acts of parliament, however, still attempt sometimes to regulate wages in particular
trades,
and in particular places. Thus the 8th of George III. prohibits, under heavy
penalties,
all
master tailors in London, and five miles round it, from giving, and their
workmen from
accepting,
more than two shillings and sevenpence halfpenny a-day, except in the case of a
general
mourning. Whenever the legislature attempts to regulate the differences between
masters
and their workmen, its counsellors are always the masters. When the regulation,
therefore,
is in favour of the workmen, it is always just and equitable; but it is
sometimes
otherwise
when in favour of the masters. Thus the law which obliges the masters in
several
different
trades to pay their workmen in money, and not in goods, is quite just and
equitable.
It
imposes no real hardship upon the masters. It only obliges them to pay that
value in money,
which
they pretended to pay, but did not always really pay, in goods. This law is in
favour of
the
workmen; but the 8th of George III. is in favour of the masters. When masters
combine
together,
in order to reduce the wages of their workmen, they commonly enter into a
private
bond or
agreement, not to give more than a certain wage, under a certain penalty. Were
the
workmen
to enter into a contrary combination of the same kind, not to accept of a
certain
wage,
under a certain penalty, the law would punish them very severely; and, if it
dealt
impartially,
it would treat the masters in the same manner. But the 8th of George III.
enforces
by law
that very regulation which masters sometimes attempt to establish by such
combinations.
The complaint of the workmen, that it puts the ablest and most industrious
upon
the same footing with an ordinary workman, seems perfectly well founded.
In
ancient times, too, it was usual to attempt to regulate the profits of
merchants and other
dealers,
by regulating the price of provisions and ether goods. The assize of bread is,
so far as
I know,
the only remnant of this ancient usage. Where there is an exclusive
corporation, it
may,
perhaps, be proper to regulate the price of the first necessary of life ; but,
where there is
none,
the competition will regulate it much better than any assize. The method of
fixing the
assize
of bread, established by the 31st of George II. could not be put in practice in
Scotland,
on
account of a defect in the law, its execution depending upon the office of
clerk of the
market,
which does not exist there. This defect was not remedied till the third of
George III.
The
want of an assize occasioned no sensible inconveniency; and the establishment
of one in
the few
places where it has yet taken place has produced no sensible advantage. In the
greater
part of
the towns in Scotland, however, there is an incorporation of bakers, who claim
exclusive
privileges, though they are not very strictly guarded. The proportion between
the
different
rates, both of wages and profit, in the different employments of labour and
stock,
seems
not to be much affected, as has already been observed, by the riches or
poverty, the
advancing,
stationary, or declining state of the society. Such revolutions in the public
welfare,
though
they affect the general rates both of wages and profit, must, in the end,
affect them
equally
in all different employments. The proportion between them, therefore, must
remain
the
same, and cannot well be altered, at least for any considerable time, by any
such
revolutions.
CHAPTER XI.
OF THE
RENT OF LAND.
Rent,
considered as the price paid for the use of land, is naturally the
highest
which the tenant can afford to pay in the actual circumstances of
the
land. In adjusting the terms of the lease, the landlord endeavours to
leave
him no greater share of the produce than what is sufficient to keep up
the
stock from which he furnishes the seed, pays the labour, and purchases
and
maintains the cattle and other instruments of husbandry, together with
the
ordinary profits of farming stock in the neighbourhood. This is
evidently
the smallest share with which the tenant can content himself,
without
being a loser, and the landlord seldom means to leave him any more.
Whatever
part of the produce, or, what is the same thing, whatever part of
its
price, is over and above this share, he naturally endeavours to reserve
to
himself as the rent of his land, which is evidently the highest the
tenant
can afford to pay in the actual circumstances of the land. Sometimes,
indeed,
the liberality, more frequently the ignorance, of the landlord,
makes
him accept of somewhat less than this portion ; and sometimes, too,
though
more rarely, the ignorance of the tenant makes him undertake to pay
somewhat
more, or to content himself with somewhat less, than the ordinary
profits
of farming stock in the neighbourhood. This portion, however, may
still
be considered as the natural rent of land, or the rent at which it is
naturally
meant that land should, for the most part, be let.
The
rent of land, it may be thought, is frequently no more than a reasonable
profit
or interest for the stock laid out by the landlord upon its
improvement.
This, no doubt, may be partly the case upon some occasions ;
for it
can scarce ever be more than partly the case. The landlord demands a
rent
even for unimproved land, and the supposed interest or profit upon the
expense
of improvement is generally an addition to this original rent. Those
improvements,
besides, are not always made by the stock of the landlord, but
sometimes
by that of the tenant. When the lease comes to be renewed,
however,
the landlord commonly demands the same augmentation of rent as if
they
had been all made by his own.
He
sometimes demands rent for what is altogether incapable of human
improvements.
Kelp is a species of sea-weed, which, when burnt, yields an
alkaline
salt, useful for making glass, soap, and for several other
purposes.
It grows in several parts of Great Britain, particularly in
Scotland,
upon such rocks only as lie within the high-water mark, which are
twice
every day covered with the sea, and of which the produce, therefore,
was
never augmented by human industry. The landlord, however, whose estate
is
bounded by a kelp shore of this kind, demands a rent for it as much as
for his
corn-fields.
The sea
in the neighbourhood of the islands of Shetland is more than
commonly
abundant in fish, which makes a great part of the subsistence of
their
inhabitants. But, in order to profit by the produce of the water, they
must
have a habitation upon the neighbouring land. The rent of the landlord
is in
proportion, not to what the farmer can make by the land, but to what
he can
make both by the land and the water. It is partly paid in sea-fish;
and one
of the very few instances in which rent makes a part of the price of
that
commodity, is to be found in that country.
The rent
of land, therefore, considered as the price paid for the use of the
land,
is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned to what
the
landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land, or to what
he can
afford to take, but to what the farmer can afford to give.
Such
parts only of the produce of land can commonly be brought to market, of
which
the ordinary price is sufficient to replace the stock which must be
employed
in bringing them thither, together with its ordinary profits. If
the
ordinary price is more than this, the surplus part of it will naturally
go to
the rent of the land. If it is not more, though the commodity may be
brought
to market, it can afford no rent to the landlord. Whether the price
is, or
is not more, depends upon the demand.
There
are some parts of the produce of land, for which the demand must
always
be such as to afford a greater price than what is sufficient to bring
them to
market; and there are others for which it either may or may not be
such as
to afford this greater price. The former must always afford a rent
to the
landlord. The latter sometimes may and sometimes may not, according
to
different circumstances.
Rent,
it is to be observed, therefore, enters into the composition of the
price
of commodities in a different way from wages and profit. High or low
wages
and profit are the causes of high or low price ; high or low rent is
the
effect of it. It is because high or low wages and profit must be paid,
in
order to bring a particular commodity to market, that its price is high
or low.
But it is because its price is high or low, a great deal more, or
very
little more, or no more, than what is sufficient to pay those wages and
profit,
that it affords a high rent, or a low rent, or no rent at all.
The
particular consideration, first, of those parts of the produce of land
which
always afford some rent ; secondly, of those which sometimes may and
sometimes
may not afford rent ; and, thirdly, of the variations which, in
the different
periods of improvement, naturally take place in the relative
value
of those two different sorts of rude produce, when compared both with
one
another and with manufactured commodities, will divide this chapter into
three
parts.
PART I. -
Of the Produce of Land which
always affords Rent.
As men,
like all other animals, naturally multiply in proportion to the
means
of their subsistence, food is always more or less in demand. It can
always
purchase or command a greater or smaller quantity of labour, and
somebody
can always be found who is willing to do something in order to
obtain
it. The quantity of labour, indeed, which it can purchase, is not
always
equal to what it could maintain, if managed in the most economical
manner,
on account of the high wages which are sometimes given to labour ;
but it
can always purchase such a quantity of labour as it can maintain,
according
to the rate at which that sort of labour is commonly maintained in
the
neighbourhood.
But
land, in almost any situation, produces a greater quantity of food than
what is
sufficient to maintain all the labour necessary for bringing it to
market,
in the most liberal way in which that labour is ever maintained. The
surplus,
too, is always more than sufficient to replace the stock which
employed
that labour, together with its profits. Something, therefore,
always
remains for a rent to the landlord.
The
most desert moors in Norway and Scotland produce some sort of pasture
for
cattle, of which the milk and the increase are always more than
sufficient,
not only to maintain all the labour necessary for tending them,
and to
pay the ordinary profit to the farmer or the owner of the herd or
flock,
but to afford some small rent to the landlord. The rent increases in
proportion
to the goodness of the pasture. The same extent of ground not
only
maintains a greater number of cattle, but as they we brought within a
smaller
compass, less labour becomes requisite to tend them, and to collect
their
produce. The landlord gains both ways; by the increase of the produce,
and by
the diminution of the labour which must be maintained out of it.
The
rent of land not only varies with its fertility, whatever be its
produce,
but with its situation, whatever be its fertility. Land in the
neighbourhood
of a town gives a greater rent than land equally fertile in a
distant
part of the country. Though it may cost no more labour to cultivate
the one
than the other, it must always cost more to bring the produce of the
distant
land to market. A greater quantity of labour, therefore, must be
maintained
out of it; and the surplus, from which are drawn both the profit
of the
farmer and the rent of the landlord, must be diminished. But in
remote
parts of the country, the rate of profit, as has already been shewn,
is
generally higher than in the neighbourhood of a large town. A smaller
proportion
of this diminished surplus, therefore, must belong to the
landlord.
Good
roads, canals, and navigable rivers, by diminishing the expense of
carriage,
put the remote parts of the country more nearly upon a level with
those
in the neighbourhood of the town. They are upon that account the
greatest
of all improvements. They encourage the cultivation of the remote,
which
must always be the most extensive circle of the country. They are
advantageous
to the town by breaking down the monopoly of the country in its
neighbourhood.
They are advantageous even to that part of the country.
Though
they introduce some rival commodities into the old market, they open
many
new markets to its produce. Monopoly, besides, is a great enemy to good
management,
which can never be universally established, but in consequence
of that
free and universal competition which forces every body to have
recourse
to it for the sake of self defence. It is not more than fifty years
ago,
that some of the counties in the neighbourhood of London petitioned the
parliament
against the extension of the turnpike roads into the remoter
counties.
Those remoter counties, they pretended, from the cheapness of
labour,
would be able to sell their grass and corn cheaper in the London
market
than themselves, and would thereby reduce their rents, and ruin their
cultivation.
Their rents, however, have risen, and their cultivation has
been
improved since that time.
A corn
field of moderate fertility produces a much greater quantity of food
for
man, than the best pasture of equal extent. Though its cultivation
requires
much more labour, yet the surplus which remains after replacing the
seed
and maintaining all that labour, is likewise much greater. If a pound
of
butcher's meat, therefore, was never supposed to be worth more than a
pound
of bread, this greater surplus would everywhere be of greater value
and
constitute a greater fund, both for the profit of the farmer and the
rent of
the landlord. It seems to have done so universally in the rude
beginnings
of agriculture.
But the
relative values of those two different species of food, bread and
butcher's
meat, are very different in the different periods of agriculture.
In its
rude beginnings, the unimproved wilds, which then occupy the far
greater
part of the country, are all abandoned to cattle. There is more
butcher's
meat than bread; and bread, therefore, is the food for which there
is the
greatest competition, and which consequently brings the greatest
price.
At Buenos Ayres, we are told by Ulloa, four reals, one-and-twenty
pence
halfpenny sterling, was, forty or fifty years ago, the ordinary price
of an
ox, chosen from a herd of two or three hundred. He says nothing of the
price
of bread, probably because he found nothing remarkable about it. An ox
there,
he says, costs little more than the labour of catching him. But corn
can
nowhere be raised without a great deal of labour ; and in a country
which
lies upon the river Plate, at that time the direct road from Europe to
the
silver mines of Potosi, the money-price of labour could be very cheap.
It is
otherwise when cultivation is extended over the greater part of the
country.
There is then more bread than butcher's meat. The competition
changes
its direction, and the price of butcher's meat becomes greater
than
the price of bread.
By the
extension, besides, of cultivation, the unimproved wilds become
insufficient
to supply the demand for butcher's meat. A great part of the
cultivated
lands must be employed in rearing and fattening cattle ; of which
the
price, therefore, must be sufficient to pay, not only the labour
necessary
for tending them, but the rent which the landlord, and the profit
which
the farmer, could have drawn from such land employed in tillage. The
cattle
bred upon the most uncultivated moors, when brought to the same
market,
are, in proportion to their weight or goodness, sold at the same
price
as those which are reared upon the most improved land. The proprietors
of
those moors profit by it, and raise the rent of their land in proportion
to the
price of their cattle. It is not more than a century ago, that in
many
parts of the Highlands of Scotland, butcher's meat was as cheap or
cheaper
than even bread made of oatmeal The Union opened the market of
England
to the Highland cattle. Their ordinary price, at present, is about
three
times greater than at the beginning of the century, and the rents of
many
Highland estates have been tripled and quadrupled in the same time. In
almost
every part of Great Britain, a pound of the best butcher's meat is,
in the
present times, generally worth more than two pounds of the best white
bread ;
and in plentiful years it is sometimes worth three or four pounds.
It is
thus that, in the progress of improvement, the rent and profit of
unimproved
pasture come to be regulated in some measure by the rent and
profit
of what is improved, and these again by the rent and profit of corn.
Corn is
an annual crop ; butcher's meat, a crop which requires four or five
years
to grow. As an acre of land, therefore, will produce a much smaller
quantity
of the one species of food than of the other, the inferiority of
the
quantity must be compensated by the superiority of the price. If it was
more
than compensated, more corn-land would be turned into pasture ; and if
it was
not compensated, part of what was in pasture would be brought back
into
corn.
This
equality, however, between the rent and profit of grass and those of
corn ;
of the land of which the immediate produce is food for cattle, and of
that of
which the immediate produce is food for men, must be understood to
take
place only through the greater part of the improved lands of a great
country.
In some particular local situations it is quite otherwise, and the
rent
and profit of grass are much superior to what can be made by corn.
Thus,
in the neighbourhood of a great town, the demand for milk, and for
forage
to horses, frequently contribute, together with the high price of
butcher's
meat, to raise the value of grass above what may be called its
natural
proportion to that of corn. This local advantage, it is evident,
cannot
be communicated to the lands at a distance.
Particular
circumstances have sometimes rendered some countries so populous,
that
the whole territory, like the lands in the neighbourhood of a great
town,
has not been sufficient to produce both the grass and the corn
necessary
for the subsistence of their inhabitants. Their lands, therefore,
have
been principally employed in the production of grass, the more bulky
commodity,
and which cannot be so easily brought from a great distance; and
corn,
the food of the great body of the people, has been chiefly imported
from
foreign countries. Holland is at present in this situation; and a
considerable
part of ancient Italy seems to have been so during the
prosperity
of the Romans. To feed well, old Cato said, as we are told by
Cicero,
was the first and most profitable thing in the management of a
private
estate ; to feed tolerably well, the second ; and to feed ill, the
third.
To plough, he ranked only in the fourth place of profit and
advantage.
Tillage, indeed, in that part of ancient Italy which lay in the
neighbour
hood of Rome, must have been very much discouraged by the
distributions
of corn which were frequently made to the people, either
gratuitously,
or at a very low price. This corn was brought from the
conquered
provinces, of which several, instead of taxes, were obliged to
furnish
a tenth part of their produce at a stated price, about sixpence
a-peck,
to the republic. The low price at which this corn was distributed to
the
people, must necessarily have sunk the price of what could be brought to
the
Roman market from Latium, or the ancient territory of Rome, and must
have
discouraged its cultivation in that country.
In an
open country, too, of which the principal produce is corn, a
well-inclosed
piece of grass will frequently rent higher than any corn field
in its
neighbourhood. It is convenient for the maintenance of the cattle
employed
in the cultivation of the corn; and its high rent is, in this case,
not so
properly paid from the value of its own produce, as from that of the
corn
lands which are cultivated by means of it. It is likely to fall, if
ever
the neighbouring lands are completely inclosed. The present high rent
of
inclosed land in Scotland seems owing to the scarcity of inclosure, and
will
probably last no longer than that scarcity. The advantage of inclosure
is
greater for pasture than for corn. It saves the labour of guarding the
cattle,
which feed better, too, when they are not liable to be disturbed by
their
keeper or his dog.
But
where there is no local advantage of this kind, the rent and profit of
corn,
or whatever else is the common vegetable food of the people, must
naturally
regulate upon the land which is fit for producing it, the rent and
profit
of pasture.
The use
of the artificial grasses, of turnips, carrots, cabbages, and the
other
expedients which have been fallen upon to make an equal quantity of
land
feed a greater number of cattle than when in natural grass, should
somewhat
reduce, it might be expected, the superiority which, in an
improved
country, the price of butcher's meat naturally has over that of
bread.
It seems accordingly to have done so ; and there is some reason for
believing
that, at least in the London market, the price of butcher's meat,
in
proportion to the price of bread, is a good deal lower in the present
times
than it was in the beginning of the last century.
In the
Appendix to the life of Prince Henry, Doctor Birch has given us an
account
of the prices of butcher's meat as commonly paid by that prince. It
is
there said, that the four quarters of an ox, weighing six hundred pounds,
usually
cost him nine pounds ten shillings, or thereabouts; that is
thirty-one
shillings and eight-pence per hundred pounds weight. Prince Henry
died on
the 6th of November 1612, in the nineteenth year of his age.
In
March 1764, there was a parliamentary inquiry into the causes of the high
price
of provisions at that time. It was then, among other proof to the same
purpose,
given in evidence by a Virginia merchant, that in March 1763, he
had
victualled his ships for twentyfour or twenty-five shillings the hundred
weight
of beef, which he considered as the ordinary price; whereas, in that
dear
year, he had paid twenty-seven shillings for the same weight and sort.
This
high price in 1764 is, however, four shillings and eight-pence cheaper
than
the ordinary price paid by Prince Henry ; and it is the best beef only,
it must
be observed, which is fit to be salted for those distant voyages.
The
price paid by Prince Henry amounts to 3d. 4/5ths per pound weight of the
whole
carcase, coarse and choice pieces taken together ; and at that rate
the
choice pieces could not have been sold by retail for less than 4½d. or
5d. the
pound.
In the
parliamentary inquiry in 1764, the witnesses stated the price of the
choice
pieces of the best beef to be to the consumer 4d. and 4½d. the
pound;
and the coarse pieces in general to be from seven farthings to 2½d.
and
2¾d.; and this, they said, was in general one halfpenny dearer than the
same
sort of pieces had usually been sold in the month of March. But even
this
high price is still a good deal cheaper than what we can well suppose
the
ordinary retail price to have been in the time of Prince Henry.
During
the first twelve years of the last century, the average price of the
best
wheat at the Windsor market was £ 1:18:3½d. the quarter of nine
Winchester
bushels.
But in
the twelve years preceding 1764 including that year, the average
price
of the same measure of the best wheat at the same market was £
2:1:9½d.
In the
first twelve years of the last century, therefore, wheat appears to
have
been a good deal cheaper, and butcher's meat a good deal dearer, than
in the
twelve years preceding 1764, including that year.
In all
great countries, the greater part of the cultivated lands are
employed
in producing either food for men or food for cattle. The rent and
profit
of these regulate the rent and profit of all other cultivated land.
If any
particular produce afforded less, the land would soon be turned into
corn or
pasture; and if any afforded more, some part of the lands in corn or
pasture
would soon be turned to that produce.
Those
productions, indeed, which require either a greater original expense
of
improvement, or a greater annual expense of cultivation in order to fit
the
land for them, appear commonly to afford, the one a greater rent, the
other a
greater profit, than corn or pasture.
This superiority, however,
will
seldom be found to amount to more than a reasonable interest or
compensation
for this superior expense.
In a
hop garden, a fruit garden, a kitchen garden, both the rent of the
landlord,
and the profit of the farmer, are generally greater than in acorn
or
grass field. But to bring the ground into this condition requires more
expense.
Hence a greater rent becomes due to the landlord. It requires, too,
a more
attentive and skilful management. Hence a greater profit becomes due
to the
farmer. The crop, too, at least in the hop and fruit garden, is more
precarious.
Its price, therefore, besides compensating all occasional
losses,
must afford something like the profit of insurance. The
circumstances
of gardeners, generally mean, and always moderate, may satisfy
us that
their great ingenuity is not commonly over-recompensed. Their
delightful
art is practised by so many rich people for amusement, that
little
advantage is to be made by those who practise it for profit; because
the
persons who should naturally be their best customers, supply themselves
with
all their most precious productions.
The
advantage which the landlord derives from such improvements, seems at no
time to
have been greater than what was sufficient to compensate the
original
expense of making them. In the ancient husbandry, after the
vineyard,
a well-watered kitchen garden seems to have been the part of the
farm
which was supposed to yield the most valuable produce. But Democritus,
who
wrote upon husbandry about two thousand years ago, and who was regarded
by the
ancients as one of the fathers of the art, thought they did not act
wisely
who inclosed a kitchen garden. The profit, he said, would not
compensate
the expense of a stone-wall: and bricks (he meant, I suppose,
bricks
baked in the sun) mouldered with the rain and the winter-storm, and
required
continual repairs. Columella, who reports this judgment of
Democritus,
does not controvert it, but proposes a very frugal method of
inclosing
with a hedge of brambles and briars, which he says he had found by
experience
to be both a lasting and an impenetrable fence ; but which, it
seems,
was not commonly known in the time of Democritus. Palladius adopts
the
opinion of Columella, which had before been recommended by Varro. In the
judgment
of those ancient improvers. the produce of a kitchen garden had, it
seems,
been little more than sufficient to pay the extraordinary culture and
the
expense of watering ; for in countries so near the sun, it was thought
proper,
in those times as in the present, to have the command of a stream of
water,
which could be conducted to every bed in the garden. Through the
greater
part of Europe, a kitchen garden is not at present supposed to
deserve
a better inclosure than mat recommended by Columella. In Great
Britain,
and some other northern countries, the finer fruits cannot Be
brought
to perfection but by the assistance of a wall. Their price,
therefore,
in such countries, must be sufficient to pay the expense of
building
and maintaining what they cannot be had without. The fruit-wall
frequently
surrounds the kitchen garden, which thus enjoys the benefit of an
inclosure
which its own produce could seldom pay for.
That
the vineyard, when properly planted and brought to perfection, was the
most
valuable part of the farm, seems to have been an undoubted maxim in the
ancient
agriculture, as it is in the modern, through all the wine countries.
But
whether it was advantageous to plant a new vineyard, was a matter of
dispute
among the ancient Italian husbandmen, as we learn from Columella. He
decides,
like a true lover of all curious cultivation, in favour of the
vineyard;
and endeavours to shew, by a comparison of the profit and expense,
that it
was a most advantageous improvement. Such comparisons, however,
between
the profit and expense of new projects are commonly very fallacious
; and
in nothing more so than in agriculture. Had the gain actually made by
such
plantations been commonly as great as he imagined it might have been,
there
could have been no dispute about it. The same point is frequently at
this
day a matter of controversy in the wine countries. Their writers on
agriculture,
indeed, the lovers and promoters of high cultivation, seem
generally
disposed to decide with Columella in favour of the vineyard. In
France,
the anxiety of the proprietors of the old vineyards to prevent the
planting
of any new ones, seems to favour their opinion, and to indicate a
consciousness
in those who must have the experience, that this species of
cultivation
is at present in that country more profitable than any other. It
seems,
at the same time, however, to indicate another opinion, that this
superior
profit can last no longer than the laws which at present restrain
the
free cultivation of the vine. In 1731, they obtained an order of
council,
prohibiting both the planting of new vineyards, and the renewal of
these
old ones, of which the cultivation had been interrupted for two years,
without
a particular permission from the king, to be granted only in
consequence
of an information from the intendant of the province, certifying
that he
had examined the land, and that it was incapable of any other
culture.
The pretence of this order was the scarcity of corn and pasture,
and the
superabundance of wine. But had this superabundance been real, it
would,
without any order of council, have effectually prevented the
plantation
of new vineyards, by reducing the profits of this species of
cultivation
below their natural proportion to those of corn and pasture.
With
regard to the supposed scarcity of corn occasioned by the
multiplication
of vineyards, corn is nowhere in France more carefully
cultivated
than in the wine provinces, where the land is fit for producing
it: as
in Burgundy, Guienne, and the Upper Languedoc. The numerous hands
employed
in the one species of cultivation necessarily encourage the other,
by
affording a ready market for its produce. To diminish the number of those
who are
capable of paying it, is surely a most unpromising expedient for
encouraging
the cultivation of corn. It is like the policy which would
promote
agriculture, by discouraging manufactures.
The
rent and profit of those productions, therefore, which require either a
greater
original expense of improvement in order to fit the land for them,
or a
greater annual expense of cultivation, though often much superior to
those
of corn and pasture, yet when they do no more than compensate such
extraordinary
expense, are in reality regulated by the rent and profit of
those
common crops.
It
sometimes happens, indeed, that the quantity of land which can be fitted
for
some particular produce, is too small to supply the effectual demand.
The
whole produce can be disposed of to those who are willing to give
somewhat
more than what is sufficient to pay the whole rent, wages, and
profit,
necessary for raising and bringing it to market, according to their
natural
rates, or according to the rates at which they are paid in the
greater
part of other cultivated land. The surplus part of the price which
remains
after defraying the whole expense of improvement and cultivation,
may
commonly, in this case, and in this case only, bear no regular
proportion
to the like surplus in corn or pasture, but may exceed it in
almost
any degree; and the greater part of this excess naturally goes to the
rent of
the landlord.
The
usual and natural proportion, for example, between the rent and profit
of
wine, and those of corn and pasture, must be understood to take place
only
with regard to those vineyards which produce nothing but good common
wine,
such as can be raised almost anywhere, upon any light, gravelly, or
sandy
soil, and which has nothing to recommend it but its strength and
wholesomeness.
It is with such vineyards only, that the common land of the
country
can be brought into competition ; for with those of a peculiar
quality
it is evident that it cannot.
The
vine is more affected by the difference of soils than any other
fruit-tree.
From some it derives a flavour which no culture or management
can
equal, it is supposed, upon any other. This flavour, real or imaginary,
is
sometimes peculiar to the produce of a few vineyards; sometimes it
extends
through the greater part of a small district, and sometimes through
a
considerable part of a large province. The whole quantity of such wines
that is
brought to market falls short of the effectual demand, or the demand
of
those who would be willing to pay the whole rent, profit, and wages,
necessary
for preparing and bringing them thither, according to the ordinary
rate,
or according to the rate at which they are paid in common vineyards.
The
whole quantity, therefore, can be disposed of to those who are willing
to pay
more, which necessarily raises their price above that of common wine.
The
difference is greater or less, according as the fashionableness and
scarcity
of the wine render the competition of the buyers more or less
eager.
Whatever it be, the greater part of it goes to the rent of the
landlord.
For though such vineyards are in general more carefully cultivated
than
most others, the high price of the wine seems to be, not so much the
effect,
as the cause of this careful cultivation. In so valuable a produce,
the loss
occasioned by negligence is so great, as to force even the most
careless
to attention. A small part of this high price, therefore, is
sufficient
to pay the wages of the extraordinary labour bestowed upon their
cultivation,
and the profits of the extraordinary stock which puts that
labour
into motion.
The
sugar colonies possessed by the European nations in the West Indies may
be
compared to those precious vineyards. Their whole produce falls short of
the
effectual demand of Europe, and can be disposed of to those who are
willing
to give more than what is sufficient to pay the whole rent, profit,
and
wages, necessary for preparing and bringing it to market, according to
the
rate at which they are commonly paid by any other produce. In Cochin
China,
the finest white sugar generally sells for three piastres the
quintal,
about thirteen shillings and sixpence of our money, as we are told
by Mr
Poivre {Voyages d'un Philosophe.}, a very careful observer of the
agriculture
of that country. What is there called the quintal, weighs from a
hundred
and fifty to two hundred Paris pounds, or a hundred and seventy-five
Paris
pounds at a medium, which reduces the price of the hundred weight
English
to about eight shillings sterling; not a fourth part of what is
commonly
paid for the brown or muscovada sugars imported from our colonies,
and not
a sixth part of what is paid for the finest white sugar. The greater
part of
the cultivated lands in Cochin China are employed in producing corn
and
rice, the food of the great body of the people. The respective prices of
corn,
rice, and sugar, are there probably in the natural proportion, or in
that
which naturally takes place in the different crops of the greater part
of
cultivated land, and which recompenses the landlord and farmer, as nearly
as can
be computed, according to what is usually the original expense of
improvement,
and the annual expense of cultivation. But in our sugar
colonies,
the price of sugar bears no such proportion to that of the produce
of a
rice or corn field either in Europe or America. It is commonly said
that a
sugar planter expects that the rum and the molasses should defray the
whole
expense of his cultivation, and that his sugar should be all clear
profit.
If this be true, for I pretend not to affirm it, it is as if a corn
farmer
expected to defray the expense of his cultivation with the chaff and
the
straw, and that the grain should be all clear profit. We see frequently
societies
of merchants in London, and other trading towns, purchase waste
lands
in our sugar colonies, which they expect to improve and cultivate with
profit,
by means of factors and agents, notwithstanding the great
distance
and the uncertain returns, from the defective administration of
justice
in those countries. Nobody will attempt to improve and cultivate in
the
same manner the most fertile lands of Scotland, Ireland, or the corn
provinces
of North America, though, from the more exact administration of
justice
in these countries, more regular returns might be expected.
In
Virginia and Maryland, the cultivation of tobacco is preferred, as most
profitable,
to that of corn. Tobacco might be cultivated with advantage
through
the greater part of Europe ; but, in almost every part of Europe, it
has
become a principal subject of taxation ; and to collect a tax from every
different
farm in the country where this plant might happen to be
cultivated,
would be more difficult, it has been supposed, than to levy one
upon
its importation at the custom-house. The cultivation of tobacco has,
upon
this account, been most absurdly prohibited through the greater part of
Europe,
which necessarily gives a sort of monopoly to the countries where it
is
allowed ; and as Virginia and Maryland produce the greatest quantity of
it,
they share largely, though with some competitors, in the advantage of
this
monopoly. The cultivation of tobacco, however, seems not to be so
advantageous
as that of sugar. I have never even heard of any tobacco
plantation
that was improved and cultivated by the capital of merchants who
resided
in Great Britain; and our tobacco colonies send us home no such
wealthy
planters as we see frequently arrive from our sugar islands. Though,
from
the preference given in those colonies to the cultivation of tobacco
above
that of corn, it would appear that the effectual demand of Europe for
tobacco
is not completely supplied, it probably is more nearly so than that
for
sugar; and though the present price of tobacco is probably more than
sufficient
to pay the whole rent, wages, and profit, necessary for preparing
and
bringing it to market, according to the rate at which they are commonly
paid in
corn land, it must not be so much more as the present price of
sugar.
Our tobacco planters, accordingly, have shewn the same fear of the
superabundance
of tobacco, which the proprietors of the old vineyards in
France
have of the superabundance of wine. By act of assembly, they have
restrained
its cultivation to six thousand plants, supposed to yield a
thousand
weight of tobacco, for every negro between sixteen and sixty years
of age.
Such a negro, over and above this quantity of tobacco, can manage,
they
reckon, four acres of Indian corn. To prevent the market from being
overstocked,
too, they have sometimes, in plentiful years, we are told by Dr
Douglas
{Douglas's Summary,vol. ii. p. 379, 373.} (I suspect he has been ill
informed),
burnt a certain quantity of tobacco for every negro, in the same
manner
as the Dutch are said to do of spices. If such violent methods are
necessary
to keep up the present price of tobacco, the superior advantage of
its
culture over that of corn, if it still has any, will not probably be of
long
continuance.
It is
in this manner that the rent of the cultivated land, of which the
produce
is human food, regulates the rent of the greater part of other
cultivated
land. No particular produce can long afford less, because the
land
would immediately be turned to another use; and if any particular
produce
commonly affords more, it is because the quantity of land which can
be
fitted for it is too small to supply the effectual demand.
In
Europe, corn is the principal produce of land, which serves immediately
for
human food. Except in particular situations, therefore, the rent of corn
land
regulates in Europe that of all other cultivated land. Britain need
envy
neither the vineyards of France, nor the olive plantations of Italy.
Except
in particular situations, the value of these is regulated by that of
corn, in
which the fertility of Britain is not much inferior to that of
either
of those two countries.
If, in
any country, the common and favourite vegetable food of the people
should
be drawn from a plant of which the most common land, with the same,
or nearly
the same culture, produced a much greater quantity than the most
fertile
does of corn ; the rent of the landlord, or the surplus quantity of
food
which would remain to him, after paying the labour, and replacing the
stock
of the farmer, together with its ordinary profits, would necessarily
be much
greater. Whatever was the rate at which labour was commonly
maintained
in that country, this greater surplus could always maintain a
greater
quantity of it, and, consequently, enable the landlord to purchase
or
command a greater quantity of it. The real value of his rent, his real
power
and authority, his command of the necessaries and conveniencies of
life
with which the labour of other people could supply him, would
necessarily
be much greater.
A rice
field produces a much greater quantity of food than the most fertile
corn
field. Two crops in the year, from thirty to sixty bushels each, are
said to
be the ordinary produce of an acre. Though its cultivation,
therefore,
requires more labour, a much greater surplus remains after
maintaining
all that labour. In those rice
countries, therefore, where
rice is
the common and favourite vegetable food of the people, and where the
cultivators
are chiefly maintained with it, a greater share of this greater
surplus
should belong to the landlord than in corn countries. In Carolina,
where
the planters, as in other British colonies, are generally both farmers
and
landlords, and where rent, consequently, is confounded with profit,
the
cultivation of rice is found to be more profitable than that of corn,
though
their fields produce only one crop in the year, and though, from the
prevalence
of the customs of Europe, rice is not there the common and
favourite
vegetable food of the people.
A good rice
field is a bog at all seasons, and at one season a bog covered
with
water. It is unfit either for corn, or pasture, or vineyard, or,
indeed,
for any other vegetable produce that is very useful to men ; and the
lands
which are fit for those purposes are not fit for rice. Even in the
rice
countries, therefore, the rent of rice lands cannot regulate the rent
of the
other cuitivated land which can never be turned to that produce.
The
food produced by a field of potatoes is not inferior in quantity to that
produced
by a field of rice, and much superior to what is produced by a
field
of wheat. Twelve thousand weight of potatoes from an acre of land is
not a
greater produce than two thousand weight of wheat. The food or solid
nourishment,
indeed, which can be drawn from each of those two plants, is
not
altogether in proportion to their weight, on account of the watery
nature
of potatoes. Allowing, however, half the weight of this root to go to
water,
a very large allowance, such an acre of potatoes will still produce
six
thousand weight of solid nourishment, three times the quantity produced
by the
acre of wheat. An acre of potatoes is cultivated with less expense
than an
acre of wheat; the fallow, which generally precedes the sowing of
wheat,
more than compensating the hoeing and other extraordinary culture
which
is always given to potatoes. Should this root ever become in any part
of
Europe, like rice in some rice countries, the common and favourite
vegetable
food of the people, so as to occupy the same proportion of the
lands
in tillage, which wheat and other sorts of grain for human food do at
present,
the same quantity of cultivated land would maintain a much greater
number
of people ; and the labourers being generally fed with potatoes, a
greater
surplus would remain after replacing all the stock, and maintaining
all the
labour employed in cultivation. A greater share of this surplus,
too,
would belong to the landlord. Population would increase, and rents
would
rise much beyond what they are at present.
The
land which is fit for potatoes, is fit for almost every other useful
vegetable.
If they occupied the same proportion of cultivated land which
corn
does at present, they would regulate, in the same manner, the rent of
the greater
part of other cultivated land.
In some
parts of Lancashire, it is pretended, I have been told, that bread
of
oatmeal is a heartier food for labouring people than wheaten bread, and 1
have
frequently heard the same doctrine held in Scotland. I am, however,
somewhat
doubtful of the truth of if. The common people in Scotland, who are
fed
with oatmeal, are in general neither so strong nor so handsome as the
same
rank of people in England, who are fed with wheaten bread. They neither
work so
well, nor look so well; and as there is not the same difference
between
the people of fashion in the two countries, experience would seem to
shew,
that the food of the common people in Scotland is not so suitable to
the
human constitution as that of their neighbours of the same rank in
England.
But it seems to be otherwise with potatoes. The chairmen, porters,
and
coal-heavers in London, and those unfortunate women who live by
prostitution,
the strongest men and the most beautiful women perhaps in the
British
dominions, are said to be, the greater part of them, from the lowest
rank of
people in Ireland. who are generally fed with this root. No food can
afford
a more decisive proof of its nourishing quality, or of its being
peculiarly
suitable to the health of the human constitution.
It is
difficult to preserve potatoes through the year, and impossible to
store
them like corn, for two or three years together. The fear of not being
able to
sell them before they rot, discourages their cultivation, and is,
perhaps,
the chief obstacle to their ever becoming in any great country,
like
bread, the principal vegetable food of all the different ranks of the
people.
PART II.
- Of the Produce of Land, which
sometimes does, and sometimes
does
not, afford Rent.
Human
food seems to be the only produce of land, which always and
necessarily
affords some rent to the landlord. Other sorts of produce
sometimes
may, and sometimes may not, according to different circumstances.
After
food, clothing and lodging are the two great wants of mankind.
Land,
in its original rude state, can afford the materials of clothing and
lodging
to a much greater number of people than it can feed. In its improved
state,
it can sometimes feed a greater number of people than it can supply
with
those materials; at least in the way in which they require them, and
are
willing to pay for them. In the one state, therefore, there is always a
superabundance
of these materials, which are frequently, upon that account,
of
little or no value. In the other, there is often a scarcity, which
necessarily
augments their value. In the one state, a great part of them is
thrown
away as useless and the price of what is used is considered as equal
only to
the labour and expense of fitting it for use, and can, therefore,
afford
no rent to the landlord. In the other, they are all made use of, and
there
is frequently a demand for more than can be had. Somebody is always
willing
to give more for every part of them, than what is sufficient to pay
the
expense of bringing them to market.
Their price, therefore, can
always
afford some rent to the landlord.
The
skins of the larger animals were the original materials of clothing.
Among
nations of hunters and shepherds, therefore, whose food consists
chiefly
in the flesh of those animals, everyman, by providing himself with
food,
provides himself with the materials of more clothing than he can wear.
If
there was no foreign commerce, the greater part of them would be thrown
away as
things of no value. This was probably the case among the hunting
nations
of North America, before their country was discovered by the
Europeans,
with whom they now exchange their surplus peltry, for blankets,
fire-arms,
and brandy, which gives it some value. In the present commercial
state
of the known world, the most barbarous nations, I believe, among whom
land
property is established, have some foreign commerce of this kind, and
find
among their wealthier neighbours such a demand for all the materials of
clothing,
which their land produces, and which can neither be wrought up nor
consumed
at home, as raises their price above what it costs to send them to
those
wealthier neighbours. It affords, therefore, some rent to the
landlord.
When the greater part of the Highland cattle were consumed on
their
own hills, the exportation of their hides made the most considerable
article
of the commerce of that country, and what they were exchanged for
afforded
some addition to the rent of the Highland estates. The wool of
England,
which in old times, could neither be consumed nor wrought up at
home,
found a market in the then wealthier and more industrious country of
Flanders,
and its price afforded something to the rent of the land which
produced
it. In countries not better cultivated than England was then, or
than
the Highlands of Scotland are now, and which had no foreign commerce,
the
materials of clothing would evidently be so superabundant, that a great
part of
them would be thrown away as useless, and no part could afford any
rent to
the landlord.
The
materials of lodging cannot always be transported to so great a distance
as
those of clothing, and do not so readily become an object of foreign
commerce.
When they are superabundant in the country which produces them, it
frequently
happens, even in the present commercial state of the world, that
they
are of no value to the landlord. A good stone quarry in the
neighbourhood
of London would afford a considerable rent. In many parts of
Scotland
and Wales it affords none. Barren timber for building is of great
value
in a populous and well-cultivated country, and the land which produces
it
affords a considerable rent. But in many parts of North America, the
landlord
would be much obliged to any body who would carry away the greater
part of
his large trees. In some parts of the Highlands of Scotland, the
bark is
the only part of the wood which, for want of roads and
water-carriage,
can be sent to market ; the timber is left to rot upon the
ground.
When the materials of lodging are so superabundant, the part made
use of
is worth only the labour and expense of fitting it for that use. It
affords
no rent to the landlord, who generally grants the use of it to
whoever
takes the trouble of asking it. The demand of wealthier nations,
however,
sometimes enables him to get a rent for it. The paving of the
streets
of London has enabled the owners of some barren rocks on the coast
of
Scotland to draw a rent from what never afforded any before. The woods of
Norway,
and of the coasts of the Baltic, find a market in many parts of
Great
Britain, which they could not find at home, and thereby afford some
rent to
their proprietors.
Countries
are populous, not in proportion to the number of people whom their
produce
can clothe and lodge, but in proportion to that of those whom it can
feed.
When food is provided, it is easy to find the necessary clothing and
lodging.
But though these are at hand, it may often be difficult to find
food.
In some parts of the British dominions, what is called a house may be
built
by one day's labour of one man. The simplest species of clothing, the
skins
of animals, require somewhat more labour to dress and prepare them for
use.
They do not, however, require a great deal. Among savage or barbarous
nations,
a hundredth, or little more than a hundredth part of the labour of
the
whole year, will be sufficient to provide them with such clothing and
lodging
as satisfy the greater part of the people. All the other ninety-nine
parts
are frequently no more than enough to provide them with food.
But
when, by the improvement and cultivation of land, the labour of one
family
can provide food for two, the labour of half the society becomes
sufficient
to provide food for the whole. The other half, therefore, or at
least
the greater part of them, can be employed in providing other things,
or in
satisfying the other wants and fancies of mankind. Clothing and
lodging,
household furniture, and what is called equipage, are the principal
objects
of the greater part of those wants and fancies. The rich man
consumes
no more food than his poor neighbour. In quality it may be very
different,
and to select and prepare it may require more labour and art;
but in
quantity it is very nearly the same. But compare the spacious palace
and
great wardrobe of the one, with the hovel and the few rags of the other,
and you
will be sensible that the difference between their clothing,
lodging,
and household furniture, is almost as great in quantity as it is in
quality.
The desire of food is limited in every
man by the narrow capacity
of the
human stomach; but the desire of the conveniencies and ornaments
of
building, dress, equipage, and household furniture, seems to have no limit
or certain
boundary. Those, therefore, who have the command of more food
than
they themselves can consume, are always willing to exchange the
surplus,
or, what is the same thing, the price of it, for gratifications of
this
other kind. What is over and above
satisfying the limited desire, is
given
for the amusement of those desires which cannot be satisfied, but seem
to be
altogether endless. The poor, in order to obtain food, exert
themselves
to gratify those fancies of the rich ; and to obtain it more
certainly,
they vie with one another in the cheapness and perfection of
their
work. The number of workmen increases with the increasing quantity of
food,
or with the growing improvement and cultivation of the lands ; and as
the
nature of their business admits of the utmost subdivisions of labour,
the
quantity of materials which they can work up, increases in a much
greater
proportion than their numbers. Hence
arises a demand for every sort
of
material which human invention can employ, either usefully or
ornamentally,
in building, dress, equipage, or household furniture ; for the
fossils
and minerals contained in the bowels of the earth, the precious
metals,
and the precious stones.
Food
is, in this manner, not only the original source of rent, but every
other
part of the produce of land which afterwards affords rent, derives
that
part of its value from the improvement of the powers of labour in
producing
food, by means of the improvement and cultivation of land.
Those
other parts of the produce of land, however, which afterwards afford
rent,
do not afford it always. Even in improved and cultivated countries,
the
demand for them is not always such as to afford a greater price than
what is
sufficient to pay the labour, and replace, together with its
ordinary
profits, the stock which must be employed in bringing them to
market.
Whether it is or is not such, depends upon different circumstances.
Whether
a coal mine, for example, can afford any rent, depends partly upon
its
fertility, and partly upon its situation.
A mine
of any kind may be said to be either fertile or barren, according as
the
quantity of mineral which can be brought from it by a certain quantity
of
labour, is greater or less than what can be brought by an equal quantity
from
the greater part of other mines of the same kind.
Some
coal mines, advantageously situated, cannot be wrought on account of
their
barrenness. The produce does not pay the expense. They can afford
neither
profit nor rent.
There
are some, of which the produce is barely sufficient to pay the labour,
and
replace, together with its ordinary profits, the stock employed in
working
them. They afford some profit to the undertaker of the work, but no
rent to
the landlord. They can be wrought advantageously by nobody but the
landlord,
who, being himself the undertaker of the work, gets the ordinary
profit
of the capital which he employs in it. Many coal mines in Scotland
are
wrought in this manner, and can be wrought in no other. The landlord
will
allow nobody else to work them without paying some rent, and nobody can
afford
to pay any.
Other
coal mines in the same country, sufficiently fertile, cannot be
wrought
on account of their situation. A
quantity of mineral, sufficient
to
defray the expense of working, could be brought from the mine by the
ordinary,
or even less than the ordinary quantity of labour: but in an
inland
country, thinly inhabited, and without either good roads or
water-carriage,
this quantity could not be sold.
Coals
are a less agreeable fuel than wood : they are said too to be less
wholesome.
The expense of coals, therefore, at the place where they are
consumed,
must generally be somewhat less than that of wood.
The
price of wood, again, varies with the state of agriculture, nearly in
the
same manner, and exactly for the same reason, as the price of cattle. In
its
rude beginnings, the greater part of every country is covered with wood,
which
is then a mere incumbrance, of no value to the landlord, who would
gladly
give it to any body for the cutting. As agriculture advances, the
woods
are partly cleared by the progress of tillage, and partly go to decay
in
consequence of the increased number of cattle. These, though they do not
increase
in the same proportion as corn, which is altogether the acquisition
of
human industry, yet multiply under the care and protection of men, who
store
up in the season of plenty what may maintain them in that of scarcity
; who,
through the whole year, furnish them with a greater quantity of food
than
uncultivated nature provides for them; and who, by destroying and
extirpating
their enemies, secure them in the free enjoyment of all that she
provides.Numerous
herds of cattle, when allowed to wander through the woods,
though
they do not destroy the old trees, hinder any young ones from coming
up ; so
that, in the course of a century or two, the whole forest goes to
ruin.
The scarcity of wood then raises its price. It affords a good rent ;
and the
landlord sometimes finds that he can scarce employ his best lands
more
advantageously than in growing barren timber, of which the greatness of
the
profit often compensates the lateness of the returns. This seems, in the
present
times, to be nearly the state of things in several parts of Great
Britain,
where the profit of planting is found to be equal to that of either
corn or
pasture. The advantage which the landlord derives from planting can
nowhere
exceed, at least for any considerable time, the rent which these
could
afford him ; and in an inland country, which is highly cuitivated, it
will
frequently not fall much short of this rent. Upon the sea-coast of a
well-improved
country, indeed, if coals can conveniently be had for fuel, it
may
sometimes be cheaper to bring barren timber for building from less
cultivated
foreign countries than to raise it at home. In the new town of
Edinburgh,
built within these few years, there is not, perhaps, a single
stick
of Scotch timber.
Whatever
may be the price of wood, if that of coals is such that the expense
of a
coal fire is nearly equal to that of a wood one we may be assured, that
at that
place, and in these circumstances, the price of coals is as high as
it can
be. It seems to be so in some of the inland parts of England,
particularly
in Oxfordshire, where it is usual, even in the fires of the
common
people, to mix coals and wood together, and where the difference in
the
expense of those two sorts of fuel cannot, therefore, be very great.
Coals,
in the coal countries, are everywhere much below this highest price.
If they
were not, they could not bear the expense of a distant carriage,
either
by land or by water. A small quantity only could be sold; and the
coal
masters and the coal proprietors find it more for their interest to
sell a
great quantity at a price somewhat above the lowest, than a small
quantity
at the highest. The most fertile coal mine, too, regulates the
price
of coals at all the other mines in its neighbourhood. Both the
proprietor
and the undertaker of the work find, the one that he can get a
greater
rent, the other that he can get a greater profit, by somewhat
underselling
all their neighbours. Their neighbours are soon obliged to sell
at the
same price, though they cannot so well afford it, and though it
always
diminishes, and sometimes takes away altogether, both their rent and
their
profit. Some works are abandoned altogether ; others can afford no
rent,
and can be wrought only by the proprietor.
The
lowest price at which coals can be sold for any considerable time, is.
like
that of all other commodities, the price which is barely sufficient to
replace,
together with its ordinary profits, the stock which must be
employed
in bringing them to market. At a coal mine for which the landlord
can get
no rent, but, which he must either work himself or let it alone
altogether,
the price of coals must generally be nearly about this price.
Rent,
even where coals afford one, has generally a smaller share in their
price
than in that of most other parts of the rude produce of land. The rent
of an
estate above ground, commonly amounts to what is supposed to be a
third
of the gross produce; and it is generally a rent certain and
independent
of the occasional variations in the crop. In coal mines, a fifth
of the
gross produce is a very great rent, a tenth the common rent ; and it
is
seldom a rent certain, but depends upon the occasional variations in the
produce.
These are so great, that in a country where thirty years purchase
is
considered as a moderate price for the property of a landed estate, ten
years
purchase is regarded as a good price for that of a coal mine.
The
value of a coal mine to the proprietor, frequently depends as much upon
its
situation as upon its fertility. That of a metallic mine depends more
upon
its fertility, and less upon its situation. The coarse, and still more
the
precious metals, when separated from the ore, are so valuable, that they
can
generally bear the expense of a very long land, and of the most distant
sea
carriage. Their market is not confined to the countries in the
neighbourhood
of the mine, but extends to the whole world. The copper of
Japan
makes an article of commerce in Europe; the iron of Spain in that of
Chili
and Peru. The silver of Peru finds its way, not only to Europe, but
from
Europe to China.
The
price of coals in Westmoreland or Shropshire can have little effect on
their
price at Newcastle ; and their price in the Lionnois can have none at
all.
The productions of such distant coal mines can never be brought into
competition
with one another. But the productions of the most distant
metallic
mines frequently may, and in fact commonly are.
The
price, therefore, of the coarse, and still more that of the precious
metals,
at the most fertile mines in the world, must necessarily more or
less
affect their price at every other in it. The price of copper in Japan
must
have some influence upon its price at the copper mines in Europe. The
price
of silver in Peru, or the quantity either of labour or of other goods
which
it will purchase there, must have some influence on its price, not
only at
the silver mines of Europe, but at those of China. After the
discovery
of the mines of Peru, the silver mines of Europe were, the greater
part of
them, abandoned. The value of silver was so much reduced, that their
produce
could no longer pay the expense of working them, or replace, with a
profit,
the food, clothes, lodging, and other necessaries which were
consumed
in that operation. This was the case, too, with the mines of Cuba
and St.
Domingo, and even with the ancient mines of Peru, after the
discovery
of those of Potosi.
The
price of every metal, at every mine, therefore, being regulated in some
measure
by its price at the most fertile mine in the world that is actually
wrought,
it can, at the greater part of mines, do very little more than pay
the
expense of working, and can seldom afford a very high rent to the
landlord.
Rent accordingly, seems at the greater part of mines to have but a
small
share in the price of the coarse, and a still smaller in that of the
precious
metals. Labour and profit make up the greater part of both.
A sixth
part of the gross produce may be reckoned the average rent of the
tin
mines of Cornwall, the most fertile that are known in the world, as we
are
told by the Rev. Mr. Borlace, vice-warden of the stannaries. Some, he
says,
afford more, and some do not afford so much. A sixth part of the gross
produce
is the rent, too, of several very fertile lead mines in Scotland.
In the
silver mines of Peru, we are told by Frezier and Ulloa, the
proprietor
frequently exacts no other acknowledgment from the undertaker of
the
mine, but that he will grind the ore at his mill, paying him the
ordinary
multure or price of grinding. Till 1736, indeed, the tax of the
king of
Spain amounted to one fifth of the standard silver, which till then
might
be considered as the real rent of the greater part of the silver mines
of
Peru, the richest which have been known in the world. If there had been
no tax,
this fifth would naturally have belonged to the landlord, and many
mines
might have been wrought which could not then be wrought, because they
could
not afford this tax. The tax of the duke of Cornwall upon tin is
supposed
to amount to more than five per cent. or one twentieth part of the
value ;
and whatever may be his proportion, it would naturally, too, belong
to the
proprietor of the mine, if tin was duty free. But if you add one
twentieth
to one sixth, you will find that the whole average rent of the tin
mines
of Cornwall, was to the whole average rent of the silver mines of
Peru,
as thirteen to twelve. But the silver mines of Peru are not now able
to pay
even this low rent; and the tax upon silver was, in 1736, reduced
from
one fifth to one tenth. Even this tax upon silver, too, gives more
temptation
to smuggling than the tax of one twentieth upon tin; and
smuggling
must be much easier in the precious than in the bulky commodity.
The tax
of the king of Spain, accordingly, is said to be very ill paid, and
that of
the duke of Cornwall very well. Rent, therefore, it is probable,
makes a
greater part of the price of tin at the most fertile tin mines than
it does
of silver at the most fertile silver mines in the world. After
replacing
the stock employed in working those different mines, together with
its
ordinary profits, the residue which remains to the proprietor is
greater,
it seems, in the coarse, than in the precious metal.
Neither
are the profits of the undertakers of silver mines commonly very
great
in Peru.The same most respectable and well-informed authors acquaint
us,
that when any person undertakes to work a new mine in Peru, he is
universally
looked upon as a man destined to bankruptcy and ruin, and is
upon
that account shunned and avoided by every body.Mining, it seems, is
considered
there in the same light as here, as a lottery, in which the
prizes
do not compensate the blanks, though the greatness of some tempts
many
adventurers to throw away their fortunes in such unprosperous projects.
As the
sovereign, however, derives a considerable part of his revenue from the produce
of
silver mines, the law in Peru gives every possible encouragement to the
discovery
and working of new ones. Whoever discovers a new mine, is entitled
to
measure off two hundred and forty-six feet in length, according to what
he
supposes to be the direction of the vein, and half as much in breadth. He
becomes
proprietor of this portion of the mine, and can work it without
paving
any acknowledgment to the landlord. The interest of the duke of
Cornwall
has given occasion to a regulation nearly of the same kind in that
ancient
dutchy. In waste and uninclosed lands, any person who discovers a
tin
mine may mark out its limits to a certain extent, which is called
bounding
a mine. The bounder becomes the real proprietor of the mine, and
may
either work it himself, or give it in lease to another, without the
consent
of the owner of the land, to whom, however, a very small
acknowdedgment
must be paid upon working it. In both regulations, the sacred
rights
of private property are sacrificed to the supposed interests of
public
revenue.
The
same encouragement is given in Peru to the discovery and working of new
gold
mines; and in gold the king's tax amounts only to a twentieth part of
the
standard rental. It was once a fifth, and afterwards a tenth, as in
silver;
but it was found that the work could not bear even the lowest of
these
two taxes. If it is rare, however, say the same authors, Frezier and
Ulloa,
to find a person who has made his fortune by a silver, it is still
much
rarer to find one who has done so by a gold mine. This twentieth part
seems
to be the whole rent which is paid by the greater part of the gold
mines
of Chili and Peru. Gold, too, is much more liable to be smuggled than
even
silver; not only on account of the superior value of the metal in
proportion
to its bulk, but on account of the peculiar way in which nature
produces
it. Silver is very seldom found virgin, but, like most other
metals,
is generally mineralized with some other body, from which it is
impossible
to separate it in such quantities as will pay for the expense,
but by
a very laborious and tedious operation, which cannot well be carried
on but
in work-houses erected for the purpose, and, therefore, exposed to
the
inspection of the king's officers. Gold, on the contrary, is almost
always
found virgin. It is sometimes found in pieces of some bulk ; and,
even
when mixed, in small and almost insensible particles, with sand, earth,
and
other extraneous bodies, it can be separated from them by a very short
and
simple operation, which can be carried on in any private house by any
body
who is possessed of a small quantity of mercury. If the king's tax,
therefore,
is but ill paid upon silver, it is likely to be much worse paid
upon
gold; and rent must make a much smaller part of the price of gold than
that of
silver.
The
lowest price at which the precious metals can be sold, or the smallest
quantity
of other goods for which they can be exchanged, during any
considerable
time, is regulated by the same principles which fix the lowest
ordinary
price of all other goods. The stock which must commonly be
employed,
the food, clothes, and lodging, which must commonly be consumed in
bringing
them from the mine to the market, determine it. It must at least be
sufficient
to replace that stock, with the ordinary profits.
Their
highest price, however, seems not to be necessarily determined by any
thing
but the actual scarcity or plenty of these metals themselves. It is
not
determined by that of any other commodity, in the same manner as the
price
of coals is by that of wood, beyond which no scarcity can ever raise
it.
Increase the scarcity of gold to a certain degree, and the smallest bit
of it
may become more precious than a diamond, and exchange for a greater
quantity
of other goods.
The
demand for those metals arises partly from their utility, and partly
from
their beauty. If you except iron, they are more useful than, perhaps,
any
other metal. As they are less liable to rust and impurity, they can more
easily
be kept clean; and the utensils, either of the table or the kitchen,
are
often, upon that account, more agreeable when made of them. A silver
boiler
is more cleanly than a lead, copper, or tin one; and the same quality
would
render a gold boiler still better than a silver one. Their principal
merit,
however, arises from their beauty, which renders them peculiarly fit
for the
ornaments of dress and furniture. No paint or dye can give so
splendid
a colour as gilding. The merit of their beauty is greatly enhanced
by
their scarcity. With the greater part of rich people, the chief enjoyment
of
riches consists in the parade of riches ; which, in their eye, is never
so
complete as when they appear to possess those decisive marks of opulence
which
nobody can possess but themselves.
In their eyes, the merit of an
object,
which is in any degree either useful or beautiful, is greatly
enhanced
by its scarcity, or by the great labour which it requires to
collect
any considerable quantity of it; a labour which nobody can afford to
pay but
themselves. Such objects they are willing to purchase at a higher
price
than things much more beautiful and useful, but more common. These
qualities
of utility, beauty, and scarcity, are the original foundation of
the
high price of those metals, or of the great quantity of other goods for
which
they can everywhere be exchanged.
This value was antecedent to,
and
independent of their being employed as coin, and was the quality which
fitted
them for that employment. That employment, however, by occasioning a
new
demand, and by diminishing the quantity which could be employed in any
other
way, may have afterwards contributed to keep up or increase their
value.
The
demand for the precious stones arises altogether from their beauty. They
are of
no use but as ornaments ; and the merit of their beauty is greatly
enhanced
by their scarcity, or by the difficulty and expense of getting them
from
the mine. Wages and profit accordingly make up, upon most occasions,
almost
the whole of the high price. Rent comes in but for a very small
share,
frequently for no share ; and the most fertile mines only afford any
considerable
rent. When Tavernier, a jeweller, visited the diamond mines of
Golconda
and Visiapour, he was informed that the sovereign of the country,
for
whose benefit they were wrought, had ordered all of them to be shut up
except
those which yielded the largest and finest stones. The other, it
seems,
were to the proprietor not worth the working.
As the
prices, both of the precious metals and of the precious stones, is
regulated
all over the world by their price at the most fertile mine in it,
the
rent which a mine of either can afford to its proprietor is in
proportion,
not to its absolute, but to what may be called its relative
fertility,
or to its superiority over other mines of the same kind. If new
mines
were discovered, as much superior to those of Potosi, as they were
superior
to those of Europe, the value of silver might be so much degraded
as to
render even the mines of Potosi not worth the working. Before the
discovery
of the Spanish West Indies, the most fertile mines in Europe may
have
afforded as great a rent to their proprietors as the richest mines in
Peru do
at present. Though the quantity of silver was much less, it might
have
exchanged for an equal quantity of other goods, and the proprietor's
share
might have enabled him to purchase or command an equal quantity either
of
labour or of commodities.
The
value, both of the produce and of the rent, the real revenue which they
afforded,
both to the public and to the proprietor, might have been the
same.
The
most abundant mines, either of the precious metals, or of the precious
stones,
could add little to the wealth of the world. A produce, of which the
value
is principally derived from its scarcity, is necessarily degraded by
its
abundance. A service of plate, and the other frivolous ornaments of
dress
and furniture, could be purchased for a smaller quantity of
commodities
; and in this would consist the sole advantage which the world
could
derive from that abundance.
It is
otherwise in estates above ground. The value, both of their produce
and of
their rent, is in proportion to their absolute, and not to their
relative
fertility. The land which produces a certain quantity of food,
clothes,
and lodging, can always feed, clothe, and lodge, a certain number
of
people ; and whatever may be the proportion of the landlord, it will
always
give him a proportionable command of the labour of those people, and
of the
commodities with which that labour can supply him. The value of the
most
barren land is not diminished by the neighbourhood of the most fertile.
On the
contrary, it is generally increased by it. The great number of people
maintained
by the fertile lands afford a market to many parts of the produce
of the
barren, which they could never have found among those whom their own
produce
could maintain.
Whatever
increases the fertility of land in producing food, increases not
only
the value of the lands upon which the improvement is bestowed, but
contributes
likewise to increase that of many other lands, by creating a new
demand
for their produce. That abundance of food, of which, in consequence
of the
improvement of land, many people have the disposal beyond what they
themselves
can consume, is the great cause of the demand, both for the
precious
metals and the precious stones, as well as for every other
conveniency
and ornament of dress, lodging, household furniture, and
equipage.
Food not only constitutes the principal part of the riches of the
world,
but it is the abundance of food which gives the principal part of
their
value to many other sorts of riches. The poor inhabitants of Cuba and
St.
Domingo, when they were first discovered by the Spaniards, used to wear
little
bits of gold as ornaments in their hair and other parts of their
dress.
They seemed to value them as we would do any little pebbles of
somewhat
more than ordinary beauty, and to consider them as just worth the
picking
up, but not worth the refusing to any body who asked them, They gave
them to
their new guests at the first request, without seeming to think that
they
had made them any very valuable present. They were astonished to
observe
the rage of the Spaniards to obtain them; and had no notion that
there
could anywhere be a country in which many people had the disposal of
so
great a superfluity of food; so scanty always among themselves, that, for
a very
small quantity of those glittering baubles, they would willingly give
as much
as might maintain a whole family for many years. Could they have
been
made to understand this, the passion of the Spaniards would not have
surprised
them.
PART
III. ˜ Of the variations in the
Proportion between the respective
Values
of that sort of Produce which always affords Rent, and of that which
sometimes
does, and sometimes does not, afford Rent.
The
increasing abundance of food, in consequence of the increasing
improvement
and cultivation, must necessarily increase the demand for every
part of
the produce of land which is not food, and which can be applied
either
to use or to ornament. In the whole progress of improvement, it
might,
therefore, be expected there should be only one variation in the
comparative
values of those two different sorts of produce. The value of
that
sort which sometimes does, and sometimes does not afford rent, should
constantly
rise in proportion to that which always affords some rent. As art
and
industry advance, the materials of clothing and lodging, the useful
fossils
and materials of the earth, the precious metals and the precious
stones,
should gradually come to be more and more in demand, should
gradually
exchange for a greater and a greater quantity of food ; or, in
other
words, should gradually become dearer and dearer. This, accordingly,
has
been the case with most of these things upon most occasions, and would
have
been the case with all of them upon all occasions, if particular
accidents
had not, upon some occasions, increased the supply of some of them
in a
still greater proportion than the demand.
The
value of a free-stone quarry, for example, will necessarily increase
with
the increasing improvement and population of the country round about
it,
especially if it should be the only one in the neighbourhood. But the
value
of a silver mine, even though there should not be another within a
thousand
miles of it, will not necessarily increase with the improvement of
the
country in which it is situated. The market for the produce of a
free-stone
quarry can seldom extend more than a few miles round about it,
and the
demand must generally be in proportion to the improvement and
population
of that small district ; but the market for the produce of a silver
mine
may extend over the whole known world. Unless the world in general.
therefore,
be advancing in improvement and population, the demand for silver
might
not be at all increased by the improvement even of a large country in
the
neighbourhood of the mine. Even though the world in general were
improving,
yet if, in the course of its improvements, new mines should be
discovered,
much more fertile than any which had been known before, though
the
demand for silver would necessarily increase, yet the supply might
increase
in so much a greater proportion, that the real price of that metal
might
gradually fall; that is, any given quantity, a pound weight of it, for
example,
might gradually purchase or command a smaller and a smaller
quantity
of labour, or exchange for a smaller and a smaller quantity of
corn,
the principal part of the subsistence of the labourer.
The
great market for silver is the commercial and civilized part of the
world.
If, by
the general progress of improvement, the demand of this market should
increase,
while, at the same time, the supply did not increase in the same
proportion,
the value of silver would gradually rise in proportion to that
of
corn. Any given quantity of silver would exchange for a greater and a
greater
quantity of corn ; or, in other words, the average money price of
corn
would gradually become cheaper and cheaper.
If, on
the contrary, the supply, by some accident, should increase, for many
years
together, in a greater proportion than the demand, that metal would
gradually
become cheaper and cheaper; or, in other words, the average money
price
of corn would, in spite of all improvements, gradually become dearer
and
dearer.
But if,
on the other hand, the supply of that metal should increase nearly
in the
same proportion as the demand, it would continue to purchase or
exchange
for nearly the same quantity of corn ; and the average money price
of corn
would, in spite of all improvements. continue very nearly the same.
These
three seem to exhaust all the possible combinations of events which
can
happen in the progress of improvement; and during the course of the four
centuries
preceding the present, if we may judge by what has happened both
in
France and Great Britain, each of those three different combinations
seems
to have taken place in the European market, and nearly in the same
order,
too, in which I have here set them down.
Digression
concerning the Variations in the value of Silver during the
Course
of the Four last Centuries.
First
Period. ˜ In 1350, and for some time before,
the average price of the
quarter
of wheat in England seems not to have been estimated lower than four
ounces
of silver, Tower weight, equal to about twenty shillings of our
present
money. From this price it seems to have fallen gradually to two
ounces
of silver, equal to about ten shillings of our present money, the
price
at which we find it estimated in the beginning of the sixteenth
century,
and at which it seems to have continued to be estimated till about
1570.
In
1350, being the 25th of Edward III. was enacted what is called the
Statute
of Labourers. In the preamble, it complains much of the insolence of
servants,
who endeavoured to raise their wages upon their masters. It
therefore
ordains, that all servants and labourers should, for the future,
be
contented with the same wages and liveries (liveries in those times
signified
not only clothes, but provisions) which they had been accustomed
to
receive in the 20th year of the king, and the four preceding years; that,
upon
this account, their livery-wheat should nowhere be estimated higher
than
tenpence a-bushel, and that it should always be in the option of the
master
to deliver them either the wheat or the money. Tenpence: a-bushel,
therefore,
had, in the 25th of Edward III. been reckoned a very moderate
price
of wheat, since it required a particular statute to oblige servants to
accept
of it in exchange for their usual livery of provisions ; and it had
been
reckoned a reasonable price ten years before that, or in the 16th year
of the
king, the term to which the statute refers. But in the 16th year of
Edward
III. tenpence contained about half an ounce of silver, Tower weight,
and was
nearly equal to half-a-crown of our present money. Four ounces of
silver,
Tower weight, therefore, equal to six shillings and eightpence of
the
money of those times, and to near twenty shillings of that of the
present,
must have been reckoned a moderate price for the quarter of eight
bushels.
This
statute is surely a better evidence of what was reckoned, in those
times,
a moderate price of grain, than the prices of some particular years,
which
have generally been recorded by historians and other writers, on
account
of their extraordinary dearness or cheapness, and from which,
therefore,
it is difficult to form any judgment concerning what may have
been
the ordinary price. There are, besides, other reasons for believing
that,
in the beginning of the fourteenth century, and for some time before,
the
common price of wheat was not less than four ounces of silver the
quarter,
and that of other grain in proportion.
In
1309, Ralph de Born, prior of St Augustine's, Canterbury, gave a feast
upon
his installation-day, of which William Thorn has preserved, not only
the
bill of fare, but the prices of many particulars. In that feast were
consumed,
1st, fifty-three quarters of wheat,
which cost nineteen pounds,
or
seven shillings, and twopence a-quarter, equal to about one-and-twenty
shillings
and sixpence of our present money ; 2dly, fifty-eight quarters of
malt,
which cost seventeen pounds ten shillings, or six shillings a-quarter,
equal
to about eighteen shillings of our present money; 3dly, twenty
quarters
of oats, which cost four pounds, or four shillings a-quarter, equal
to
about twelve shillings of our present money. The prices of malt and oats
seem
here to lie higher than their ordinary proportion to the price of
wheat.
These
prices are not recorded, on account of their extraordinary dearness or
cheapness,
but are mentioned accidentally, as the prices actually paid for
large
quantities of grain consumed at a feast, which was famous for its
magnificence.
In
1262, being the 51st of Henry III. was revived an ancient statute, called
the
assize of bread and ale, which, the king says in the preamble, had been
made in
the times of his progenitors, some time kings of England. It is
probably,
therefore, as old at least as the time of his grandfather, Henry
II. and
may have been as old as the Conquest. It regulates the price of
bread
according as the prices of wheat may happen to be, from one shilling
to
twenty shillings the quarter of the money of those times. But statutes of
this
kind are generally presumed to provide with equal care for all
deviations
from the middle price, for those below it, as well as for those
above
it. Ten shillings, therefore, containing six ounces of silver, Tower
weight,
and equal to about thirty shillings of our present money, must, upon
this
supposition, have been reckoned the middle price of the quarter of
wheat
when this statute was first enacted, and must have continued to be so
in the
51st of Henry III. We cannot, therefore, be very wrong in supposing
that
the middle price was not less than one-third of the highest price at
which
this statute regulates the price of bread, or than six shillings and
eightpence
of the money of those times, containing four ounces of silver,
Tower
weight.
From
these different facts, therefore, we seem to have some reason to
conclude
that, about the middle of the fourteenth century, and for a
considerable
time before, the average or ordinary price of the quarter of
wheat
was not supposed to be less than four ounces of silver, Tower weight.
From
about the middle of the fourteenth to the beginning of the sixteenth
century,
what was reckoned the reasonable and moderate, that is, the
ordinary
or average price of wheat, seems to have sunk gradually to about
one
half of this price; so as at last to have fallen to about two ounces of
silver,
Tower weight, equal to about ten shillings of our present money. It
continued
to be estimated at this price till about 1570.
In the
household book of Henry, the fifth earl of Northumberland, drawn up
in 1512
there are two different estimations of wheat.
In one of them it is
computed
at six shilling and eightpence the quarter, in the other at five
shillings
and eightpence only. In 1512, six shillings and eightpence
contained
only two ounces of silver, Tower weight, and were equal to about
ten
shillings of our present money.
From
the 25th of Edward III. to the beginning of the reign of Elizabeth,
during
the space of more than two hundred years, six shillings and
eightpence,
it appears from several different statutes, had continued to be
considered
as what is called the moderate and reasonable, that is, the
ordinary
or average price of wheat. The quantity of silver, however,
contained
in that nominal sum was, during the course of this period,
continually
diminishing in consequence of some alterations which were made
in the
coin. But the increase of the value of silver had, it seems, so far
compensated
the diminution of the quantity of it contained in the same
nominal
sum, that the legislature did not think it worth while to attend to
this
circumstance.
Thus,
in 1436, it was enacted, that wheat might be exported without a
licence
when the price was so low as six shillings and eightpence: and in
1463,
it was enacted, that no wheat should be imported if the price was not
above
six shillings and eightpence the quarter: The legislature had
imagined,
that when the price was so low, there could be no inconveniency in
exportation,
but that when it rose higher, it became prudent to allow of
importation.
Six shillings and eightpence, therefore, containing about the
same
quantity of silver as thirteen shillings and fourpence of our present
money
(one-third part less than the same nominal sum contained in the time
of
Edward III), had, in those times, been considered as what is called the
moderate
and reasonable price of wheat.
In
1554, by the 1st and 2nd of Philip and Mary, and in 1558, by the 1st of
Elizabeth,
the exportation of wheat was in the same manner prohibited,
whenever
the price of the quarter should exceed six shillings and
eightpence,
which did not then contain two penny worth more silver than the
same
nominal sum does at present. But it had soon been found, that to
restrain
the exportation of wheat till the price was so very low, was, in
reality,
to prohibit it altogether. In 1562, therefore, by the 5th of
Elizabeth,
the exportation of wheat was allowed from certain ports, whenever
the
price of the quarter should not exceed ten shillings, containing nearly
the
same quantity of silver as the like nominal sum does at present. This
price
had at this time, therefore, been considered as what is called the
moderate
and reasonable price of wheat. It agrees nearly with the estimation
of the
Northumberland book in 1512.
That in
France the average price of grain was, in the same manner, much
lower
in the end of the fifteenth and beginning of the sixteenth century,
than in
the two centuries preceding, has been observed both by Mr Dupré de
St
Maur, and by the elegant author of the Essay on the Policy of Grain. Its
price,
during the same period, had probably sunk in the same manner through
the
greater part of Europe.
This
rise in the value of silver, in proportion to that of corn, may either
have
been owing altogether to the increase of the demand for that metal, in
consequence
of increasing improvement and cultivation, the supply, in
the
mean time, continuing the same as before; or, the demand continuing the
same as
before, it may have been owing altogether to the gradual diminution
of the
supply: the greater part of the mines which were then known in the
world
being much exhausted, and, consequently, the expense of working them
much
increased; or it may have been owing partly to the one, and partly to
the
other of those two circumstances. In the end of the fifteenth and
beginning
of the sixteenth centuries, the greater part of Europe was
approaching
towards a more settled from of government than it had enjoyed
for
several ages before. The increase of security would naturally increase
industry
and improvement; and the demand for the precious metals, as well as
for
every other luxury and ornament, would naturally increase with the
increase
of riches. A greater annual produce would require a greater
quantity
of coin to circulate it ; and a greater number of rich people would
require
a greater quantity of plate and other ornaments of silver. It is
natural
to suppose, too, that the greater part of the mines which then
supplied
the European market with silver might be a good deal exhausted, and
have
become more expensive in the working. They had been wrought, many of
them,
from the time of the Romans.
It has
been the opinion, however, of the greater part of those who have
written
upon the prices of commodities in ancient times, that, from the
Conquest,
perhaps from the invasion of Julius Caesar, till the discovery of
the
mines of America, the value of silver was continually diminishing. This
opinion
they seem to have been led into, partly by the observations which
they
had occasion to make upon the prices both of corn and of some other
parts
of the rude produce of land, and partly by the popular notion, that as
the
quantity of silver naturally increases in every country with the
increase
of wealth, so its value diminishes as it quantity increases.
In
their observations upon the prices of corn, three different circumstances
seem
frequently to have misled them.
First.
in ancient times, almost all rents were paid in kind; in a certain
quantity
of corn, cattle, poultry, etc. It sometimes happened, however, that
the
landlord would stipulate, that he should be at liberty to demand of the
tenant,
either the annual payment in kind or a certain sum of money instead
of it.
The price at which the payment in kind was in this manner exchanged
for a
certain sum of money, is in Scotland called the conversion price. As
the
option is always in the landlord to take either the substance or the
price,
it is necessary, for the safety of the tenant, that the conversion
price
should rather be below than above the average market price. In many
places,
accordingly, it is not much above one half of this price. Through
the
greater part of Scotland this custom still continues with regard to
poultry,
and in some places with regard to cattle. It might probably have
continued
to take place, too, with regard to corn, had not the institution
of the
public fiars put an end to it. These are annual valuations, according
to the
judgment of an assize, of the average price of all the different
sorts
of grain, and of all the different qualities of each, according to the
actual
market price in every different county. This institution rendered it
sufficiently
safe for the tenant, and much more convenient for the landlord,
to
convert, as they call it, the corn rent, rather at what should happen to
be the
price of the fiars of each year, than at any certain fixed price. But
the
writers who have collected the prices of corn in ancient times seem
frequently
to have mistaken what is called in Scotland the conversion price
for the
actual market price. Fleetwood acknowledges, upon one occasion, that
he had
made this mistake. As he wrote his book, however, for a particular
purpose,
he does not think proper to make this acknowledgment till after
transcribing
this conversion price fifteen times. The price is eight
shillings
the quarter of wheat. This sum in 1423, the year at which he
begins
with it, contained the same quantity of silver as sixteen shillings
of our
present money. But in 1562, the year at which he ends with it, it
contained
no more than the same nominal sum does at present.
Secondly,
they have been misled by the slovenly manner in which some ancient
statutes
of assize had been sometimes transcribed by lazy copiers, and
sometimes,
perhaps, actually composed by the legislature.
The
ancient statutes of assize seem to have begun always with determining
what
ought to be the price of bread and ale when the price of wheat and
barley
were at the lowest ; and to have proceeded gradually to determine
what it
ought to be, according as the prices of those two sorts of grain
should
gradually rise above this lowest price. But the transcribers of those
statutes
seem frequently to have thought it sufficient to copy the
regulation
as far as the three or four first and lowest prices ; saving in
this
manner their own labour, and judging, I suppose, that this was enough
to show
what proportion ought to be observed in all higher prices.
Thus,
in the assize of bread and ale, of the 51st of Henry III. the price of
bread
was regulated according to the different prices of wheat, from one
shilling
to twenty shillings the quarter of the money of those times. But in
the
manuscripts from which all the different editions of the statutes,
preceding
that of Mr Ruffhead, were printed, the copiers had never
transcribed
this regulation beyond the price of twelve shillings. Several
writers,
therefore, being misled by this faulty transcription, very
naturally
conclude that the middle price, or six shillings the quarter,
equal
to about eighteen shillings of our present money, was the ordinary or
average
price of wheat at that time.
In the
statute of Tumbrel and Pillory, enacted nearly about the same time,
the
price of ale is regulated according to every sixpence rise in the price
of barley,
from two shillings, to four shillings the quarter. That four
shillings,
however, was not considered as the highest price to which barley
might
frequently rise in those times, and that these prices were only given
as an
example of the proportion which ought to be observed in all other
prices,
whether higher or lower, we may infer from the last words of the
statute:
" Et sic deinceps crescetur vel diminuetur per sex denarios." The
expression
is very slovenly, but the meaning is plain enough, " that the
price
of ale is in this manner to be increased or diminished according to
every
sixpence rise or fall in the price of barley." In the composition of
this
statute, the legislature itself seems to have been as negligent as the
copiers
were in the transcription of the other.
In an
ancient manuscript of the Regiam Majestatem, an old Scotch law book,
there
is a statute of assize, in which the price of bread is regulated
according
to all the different prices of wheat, from tenpence to three
shillings
the Scotch boll, equal to about half an English quarter. Three
shillings
Scotch, at the time when this assize is supposed to have been
enacted,
were equal to about nine shillings sterling of our present money Mr
Ruddiman
seems {See his Preface to Anderson's Diplomata Scotiae.} to
conclude
from this, that three shillings was the highest price to which
wheat
ever rose in those times, and that tenpence, a shilling, or at most
two
shillings, were the ordinary prices. Upon consulting the manuscript,
however,
it appears evidently, that all these prices are only set down as
examples
of the proportion which ought to be observed between the respective
prices
of wheat and bread. The last words of the statute are " reliqua
judicabis
secundum praescripta, habendo respectum ad pretium bladi." ˜ " You
shall
judge of the remaining cases, according to what is above written,
having
respect to the price of corn."
Thirdly,
they seem to have been misled too, by the very low price at which
wheat
was sometimes sold in very ancient times ; and to have imagined, that
as its
lowest price was then much lower than in later times its ordinary
price
must likewise have been much lower. They might have found, however,
that in
those ancient times its highest price was fully as much above, as
its
lowest price was below any thing that had ever been known in later
times.
Thus, in 1270, Fleetwood gives us two prices of the quarter of wheat.
The one
is four pounds sixteen shillings of the money of those times, equal
to fourteen
pounds eight shillings of that of the present; the other is six
pounds
eight shillings, equal to nineteen pounds four shillings of our
present
money. No price can be found in the end of the fifteenth, or
beginning
of the sixteenth century, which approaches to the extravagance of
these.
The price of corn, though at all times liable to variation varies
most in
those turbulent and disorderly societies, in which the interruption
of all
commerce and communication hinders the plenty of one part of the
country
from relieving the scarcity of another. In the disorderly state of
England
under the Plantagenets, who governed it from about the middle of the
twelfth
till towards the end of the fifteenth century, one district might be
in
plenty, while another, at no great distance, by having its crop
destroyed,
either by some accident of the seasons, or by the incursion of
some
neighbouring baron, might be suffering all the horrors of a famine; and
yet if
the lands of some hostile lord were interposed between them, the one
might
not be able to give the least assistance to the other. Under the
vigorous
administration of the Tudors, who governed England during the
latter
part of the fifteenth, and through the whole of the sixteenth
century,
no baron was powerful enough to dare to disturb the public
security.
The
reader will find at the end of this chapter all the prices of wheat
which
have been collected by Fleetwood, from l202 to 1597, both inclusive,
reduced
to the money of the present times, and digested, according to the
order
of time, into seven divisions of twelve years each. At the end of each
division,
too, he will find the average price of the twelve years of which
it
consists. In that long period of time, Fleetwood has been able to collect
the
prices of no more than eighty years ; so that four years are wanting to
make
out the last twelve years. I have added, therefore, from the accounts
of Eton
college, the prices of 1598, 1599, 1600, and 1601. It is the only
addition
which I have made. The reader will see, that from the beginning of
the
thirteenth till after the middle of the sixteenth century, the average
price
of each twelve years grows gradually lower and lower; and that towards
the end
of the sixteenth century it begins to rise again. The prices,
indeed,
which Fleetwood has been able to collect, seem to have been those
chiefly
which were remarkable for extraordinary dearness or cheapness ; and
I do
not pretend that any very certain conclusion can be drawn from them. So
far,
however, as they prove any thing at all, they confirm the account which
I have
been endeavouring to give. Fleetwood himself, however, seems, with
most
other writers, to have believed, that, during all this period, the
value
of silver, in consequence of its increasing abundance, was continually
diminishing.
The prices of corn, which he himself has collected, certainly
do not
agree with this opinion. They agree perfectly with that of Mr Dupré
de St
Maur, and with that which I have been endeavouring to explain. Bishop
Fleetwood
and Mr Dupré de St Maur are the two authors who seem to have
collected,
with the greatest diligence and fidelity, the prices of things in
ancient
times. It is some what curious that, though their opinions are so
very
different, their facts, so far as they relate to the price of corn at
least,
should coincide so very exactly.
It is
not, however, so much from the low price of corn, as from that of some
other
parts of the rude produce of land, that the most judicious writers
have
inferred the great value of silver in those very ancient times. Corn,
it has
been said, being a sort of manufacture, was, in those rude ages, much
dearer
in proportion than the greater part of other commodities; it is
meant,
I suppose, than the greater part of unmanufactured commodities, such
as
cattle, poultry, game of all kinds, etc. That in those times of poverty
and
barbarism these were proportionably much cheaper than corn, is
undoubtedly
true. But this cheapness was not the effect of the high value of
silver,
but of the low value of those commodities. It was not because silver
would
in such times purchase or represent a greater quantity of labour, but
because
such commodities would purchase or represent a much smaller quantity
than in
times of more opulence and improvement. Silver must certainly be
cheaper
in Spanish America than in Europe ; in the country where it is
produced,
than in the country to which it is brought, at the expense of a
long
carriage both by land and by sea, of a freight, and an insurance.
One-and-twenty
pence halfpenny sterling, however, we are told by Ulloa, was,
not
many years ago, at Buenos Ayres, the price of an ox chosen from a herd
of
three or four hundred. Sixteen shillings sterling, we are told by Mr
Byron,
was the price of a good horse in the capital of Chili. In a country
naturally
fertile, but of which the far greater part is altogether
uncultivated,
cattle, poultry, game of all kinds, etc. as they can be
acquired
with a very small quantity of labour, so they will purchase or
command
but a very small quantity. The low money price for which they may be
sold,
is no proof that the real value of silver is there very high, but that
the
real value of those commodities is very low.
Labour,
it must always be remembered, and not any particular commodity, or
set of
commodities, is the real measure of the value both of silver and of
all
other commodities.
But in
countries almost waste, or but thinly inhabited, cattle, poultry,
game of
all kinds, etc. as they are the spontaneous productions of Nature,
so she
frequently produces them in much greater quantities than the
consumption
of the inhabitants requires. In such a state of things, the
supply
commonly exceeds the demand. In different states of society, in
different
states of improvement, therefore, such commodities will represent,
or be
equivalent, to very different quantities of labour.
In
every state of society, in every stage of improvement, corn is the
production
of human industry. But the average produce of every sort of
industry
is always suited, more or less exactly, to the average consumption;
the
average supply to the average demand. In every different stage of
improvement,
besides, the raising of equal quantities of corn in the same
soil
and climate, will, at an average, require nearly equal quantities of
labour;
or, what comes to the same thing, the price of nearly equal
quantities;
the continual increase of the productive powers of labour, in an
improved
state of cultivation, being more or less counterbalanced by the
continual
increasing price of cattle, the principal instruments of
agriculture.
Upon all these accounts, therefore, we may rest assured, that
equal
quantities of corn will, in every state of society, in every stage of
improvement,
more nearly represent, or be equivalent to, equal quantities of
labour,
than equal quantities of any other part of the rude produce of land.
Corn,
accordingly, it has already been observed, is, in all the different
stages
of wealth and improvement, a more accurate measure of value than any
other
commodity or set of commodities. In all those different stages,
therefore,
we can judge better of the real value of silver, by comparing it
with
corn, than by comparing it with any other commodity or set of
commodities.
Corn,
besides, or whatever else is the common and favourite vegetable food
of the
people, constitutes, in every civilized country, the principal part
of the
subsistence of the labourer. In consequence of the extension of
agriculture,
the land of every country produces a much greater quantity of
vegetable
than of animal food, and the labourer everywhere lives chiefly
upon
the wholesome food that is cheapest and most abundant. Butcher's meat,
except
in the most thriving countries, or where labour is most highly
rewarded,
makes but an insignificant part of his subsistence; poultry makes
a still
smaller part of it, and game no part of it. In France, and even in
Scotland,
where labour is somewhat better rewarded than in France, the
labouring
poor seldom eat butcher's meat, except upon holidays, and other
extraordinary
occasions. The money price of labour, therefore, depends much
more
upon the average money price of corn, the subsistence of the labourer,
than upon
that of butcher's meat, or of any other part of the rude produce
of
land. The real value of gold and silver, therefore, the real quantity of
labour
which they can purchase or command, depends much more upon the
quantity
of corn which they can purchase or command, than upon that of
butcher's
meat, or any other part of the rude produce of land.
Such
slight observations, however, upon the prices either of corn or of
other
commodities, would not probably have misled so many intelligent
authors,
had they not been influenced at the same time by the popular
notion,
that as the quantity of silver naturally increases in every country
with
the increase of wealth, so its value diminishes as its quantity
increases.
This notion, however, seems to be altogether groundless.
The
quantity of the precious metals may increase in any country from two
different
causes ; either, first, from the increased abundance of the mines
which
supply it; or, secondly, from the increased wealth of the people, from
the increased
produce of their annual labour. The first of these causes is
no
doubt necessarily connected with the diminution of the value of the
precious
metals; but the second is not.
When
more abundant mines are discovered, a greater quantity of the precious
metals
is brought to market; and the quantity of the necessaries and
conveniencies
of life for which they must he exchanged being the same as
before,
equal quantities of the metals must be exchanged for smaller
quantities
of commodities. So far, therefore, as the increase of the
quantity
of the precious metals in any country arises from the increased
abundance
of the mines, it is necessarily connected with some diminution of
their
value.
When,
on the contrary, the wealth of any country increases, when the annual
produce
of its labour becomes gradually greater and greater, a greater
quantity
of coin becomes necessary in order to circulate a greater quantity
of
commodities: and the people, as they can afford it, as they have more
commodities
to give for it, will naturally purchase a greater and a greater
quantity
of plate. The quantity of their coin will increase from necessity;
the
quantity of their plate from vanity and ostentation, or from the same
reason
that the quantity of fine statues, pictures, and of every other
luxury
and curiosity, is likely to increase among them. But as statuaries
and
painters are not likely to be worse rewarded in times of wealth and
prosperity,
than in times of poverty and depression, so gold and silver are
not
likely to be worse paid for.
The
price of gold and silver, when the accidental discovery of more abundant
mines
does not keep it down, as it naturally rises with the wealth of every
country;
so, whatever be the state of the mines, it is at all times
naturally
higher in a rich than in a poor country. Gold and silver, like all
other
commodities, naturally seek the market where the best price is given
for
them, and the best price is commonly given for every thing in the
country
which can best afford it. Labour, it must be remembered, is the
ultimate
price which is paid for every thing; and in countries where labour
is
equally well rewarded, the money price of labour will be in proportion to
that of
the subsistence of the labourer. But gold and silver will naturally
exchange
for a greater quantity of subsistence in a rich than in a poor
country
; in a country which abounds with subsistence, than in one which is
but
indifferently supplied with it. If the two countries are at a great
distance,
the difference may be very great; because, though the metals
naturally
fly from the worse to the better market, yet it may be difficult
to
transport them in such quantities as to bring their price nearly to a
level
in both. If the countries are near, the difference will be smaller,
and may
sometimes be scarce perceptible ; because in this case the
transportation
will be easy. China is a much richer country than any part of
Europe,
and the difference between the price of subsistence in China and in
Europe
is very great. Rice in China is much cheaper than wheat is any where
in
Europe. England is a much richer country than Scotland, but the
difference
between the money price of corn in those two countries is much
smaller,
and is but just perceptible. In proportion to the quantity or
measure,
Scotch corn generally appears to be a good deal cheaper than
English;
but, in proportion to its quality, it is certainly somewhat dearer.
Scotland
receives almost every year very large supplies from England, and
every
commodity must commonly be somewhat dearer in the country to which it
is
brought than in that from which it comes. English corn, therefore, must
be
dearer in Scotland than in England ; and yet in proportion to its
quality,
or to the quantity and goodness of the flour or meal which can be
made
from it, it cannot commonly be sold higher there than the Scotch corn
which
comes to market in competition with it.
The
difference between the money price of labour in China and in Europe, is
still greater
than that between the money price of subsistence; because the
real
recompence of labour is higher in Europe than in China, the greater
part of
Europe being in an improving state, while China seems to be standing
still.
The money price of labour is lower in Scotland than in England,
because
the real recompence of labour is much lower: Scotland, though
advancing
to greater wealth, advances much more slowly than England. The
frequency
of emigration from Scotland, and the rarity of it from England,
sufficiently
prove that the demand for labour is very different in the two
countries.
The proportion between the real recompence of labour in different
countries,
it must be remembered, is naturally regulated, not by their
actual
wealth or poverty, but by their advancing, stationary, or declining
condition.
Gold
and silver, as they are naturally of the greatest value among the
richest,
so they are naturally of the least value among the poorest nations.
Among
savages, the poorest of all nations, they are scarce of any value.
In
great towns, corn is always dearer than in remote parts of the country.
This,
however, is the effect, not of the real cheapness of silver, but of
the
real dearness of corn. It does not cost less labour to bring silver to
the
great town than to the remote parts of the country; but it costs a great
deal
more to bring corn.
In some
very rich and commercial countries, such as Holland and the
territory
of Genoa, corn is dear for the same reason that it is dear in
great
towns. They do not produce enough to maintain their inhabitants. They
are
rich in the industry and skill of their artificers and manufacturers, in
every
sort of machinery which can facilitate and abridge labour; in
shipping,
and in all the other instruments and means of carriage and
commerce:
but they are poor in corn, which, as it must be brought to them
from
distant countries, must, by an addition to its price, pay for the
carriage
from those countries. It does not cost less labour to bring silver
to
Amsterdam than to Dantzic ; but it costs a great deal more to bring corn.
The
real cost of silver must be nearly the same in both places ; but that of
corn
must be very different. Diminish the real opulence either of Holland or
of the
territory of Genoa, while the number of their inhabitants remains the
same ;
diminish their power of supplying themselves from distant countries;
and the
price of corn, instead of sinking with that diminution in the
quantity
of their silver, which must necessarily accompany this declension,
either
as its cause or as its effect, will rise to the price of a famine.
When we
are in want of necessaries, we must part with all superfluities, of
which
the value, as it rises in times of opulence and prosperity, so it
sinks
in times of poverty and distress. It is otherwise with necessaries.
Their
real price, the quantity of labour which they can purchase or command,
rises
in times of poverty and distress, and sinks in times of opulence and
prosperity,
which are always times of great abundance ; for they could not
otherwise
be times of opulence and prosperity.Corn is a necessary, silver is
only a
superfluity.
Whatever,
therefore, may have been the increase in the quantity of the
precious
metals, which, during the period between the middle of the
fourteenth
and that of the sixteenth century, arose from the increase of
wealth
and improvement, it could have no tendency to diminish their value,
either
in Great Britain, or in my other part of Europe. If those who have
collected
the prices of things in ancient times, therefore, had, during this
period,
no reason to infer the diminution of the value of silver from any
observations
which they had made upon the prices either of corn, or of
other
commodities, they had still less reason to infer it from any supposed
increase
of wealth and improvement.
Second
Period. ˜ But how various soever may have been the opinions of the
learned
concerning the progress of the value of silver during the first
period,
they are unanimous concerning it during the second.
From
about 1570 to about 1640, during a period of about seventy years, the
variation
in the proportion between the value of silver and that of corn
held a
quite opposite course. Silver sunk in its real value, or would
exchange
for a smaller quantity of labour than before; and corn rose in its
nominal
price, and, instead of being commonly sold for about two ounces of
silver
the quarter, or about ten shillings of our present money, came to be
sold
for six and eight ounces of silver the quarter, or about thirty and
forty
shillings of our present money.
The
discovery of the abundant mines of America seems to have been the sole
cause
of this diminution in the value of silver, in proportion to that of
corn.
It is accounted for, accordingly, in the same manner by every body ;
and
there never has been any dispute, either about the fact, or about the
cause
of it. The greater part of Europe was, during this period, advancing
in
industry and improvement, and the demand for silver must consequently
have
been increasing; but the increase of the supply had, it seems, so far
exceeded
that of the demand, that the value of that metal sunk considerably.
The
discovery of the mines of America, it is to be observed, does not seem
to have
had any very sensible effect upon the prices of things in England
till
after 1570; though even the mines of Potosi had been discovered more
than
twenty years before.
From
1595 to 1620, both inclusive, the average price of the quarter of nine
bushels
of the best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, from the accounts of
Eton
college, to have been £ 2:1:6 9/13. From which sum, neglecting the
fraction,
and deducting a ninth, or 4s. 7 1/3d., the price of the quarter of
eight
bushels comes out to have been £ 1:16:10 2/3. And from this sum,
neglecting
likewise the fraction, and deducting a ninth, or 4s. 1 1/9d., for
the
difference between the price of the best wheat and that of the middle
wheat,
the price of the middle wheat comes out to have been about £ 1:12:8
8/9, or
about six ounces and one-third of an ounce of silver.
From
1621 to 1636, both inclusive, the average price of the same measure of
the
best wheat, at the same market, appears, from the same accounts, to have
been £
2:10s.; from which, making the like deductions as in the foregoing
case,
the average price of the quarter of eight bushels of middle wheat comes
out to
have been £ 1:19:6, or about seven ounces and two-thirds of an ounce
of
silver.
Third
Period. - Between 1630 and 1640, or about 1636, the effect of the
discovery
of the mines of America, in reducing the value of silver, appears
to have
been completed, and the value of that metal seems never to have sunk
lower
in proportion to that of corn than it was about that time. It seems to
have
risen somewhat in the course of the present century, and it had
probably
begun to do so, even some time before the end of the last.
From
1637 to 1700, both inclusive, being the sixty-four last years of the
last
century the average price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best
wheat,
at Windsor market, appears, from the same accounts, to have been £
2:11:0
1/3, which is only 1s. 0 1/3d. dearer than it had been during the
sixteen
years before. But, in the course of these sixty-four years, there
happened
two events, which must have produced a much greater scarcity of
corn
than what the course of the season is would otherwise have occasioned,
and
which, therefore, without supposing any further reduction in the value
of
silver, will much more than account for this very small enhancement of
price.
The
first of these events was the civil war, which, by discouraging tillage
and
interrupting commerce, must have raised the price of corn much above
what
the course of the seasons would otherwise have occasioned. It must have
had
this effect, more or less, at all the different markets in the kingdom,
but
particularly at those in the neighbourhood of London, which require to
be
supplied from the greatest distance. In 1648, accordingly, the price of
the
best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, from the same accounts, to have
been £
4:5s., and, in 1649, to have been £ 4, the quarter of nine bushels.
The
excess of those two years above £ 2:10s. (the average price of the
sixteen
years preceding 1637 is £ 3:5s., which, divided among the sixty four
last
years of the last century, will alone very nearly account for that
small
enhancement of price which seems to have taken place in them. These,
however,
though the highest, are by no means the only high prices which seem
to have
been occasioned by the civil wars.
The
second event was the bounty upon the exportation of corn, granted in
1688.
The bounty, it has been thought by many people, by encouraging
tillage,
may, in a long course of years, have occasioned a greater
abundance,
and, consequently, a greater cheapness of corn in the home
market,
than what would otherwise have taken place there. How far the bounty
could
produce this effect at any time I shall examine hereafter: I shall
only
observe at present, that between 1688 and 1700, it had not time to
produce
any such effect. During this short period, its only effect must have
been,
by encouraging the exportation of the surplus produce of every year,
and
thereby hindering the abundance of one year from compensating the
scarcity
of another, to raise the price in the home market. The scarcity
which
prevailed in England, from 1693 to 1699, both inclusive, though no
doubt
principally owing to the badness of the seasons, and, therefore,
extending
through a considerable part of Europe, must have been somewhat
enhanced
by the bounty. In 1699, accordingly, the further exportation of
corn
was prohibited for nine months.
There
was a third event which occurred in the course of the same period, and
which,
though it could not occasion any scarcity of corn, nor, perhaps, any
augmentation
in the real quantity of silver which was usually paid for it,
must
necessarily have occasioned some augmetation in the nominal sum. This
event
was the great debasement of the silver coin, by clipping and wearing.
This
evil had begun in the reign of Charles II. and had gone on continually
increasing
till 1695; at which time, as we may learn from Mr Lowndes, the
current
silver coin was, at an average, near five-and-twenty per cent. below
its
standard value. But the nominal sum which constitutes the market price
of
every commodity is necessarily regulated, not so much by the quantity of
silver,
which, according to the standard, ought to be contained in it, as by
that
which, it is found by experience, actually is contained in it. This
nominal
sum, therefore, is necessarily higher when the coin is much debased
by
clipping and wearing, than when near to its standard value.
In the
course of the present century, the silver coin has not at any time
been
more below its standard weight than it is at present. But though very
much
defaced, its value has been kept up by that of the gold coin, for which
it is
exchanged. For though, before the late recoinage, the gold coin was a
good
deal defaced too, it was less so than the silver. In 1695, on the
contrary,
the value of the silver coin was not kept up by the gold coin; a
guinea
then commonly exchanging for thirty shillings of the worn and clipt
silver.
Before the late recoinage of the gold, the price of silver bullion
was
seldom higher than five shillings and sevenpence an ounce, which is but
fivepence
above the mint price. But in 1695, the common price of silver
bullion
was six shillings and fivepence an ounce, {Lowndes's Essay on the
Silver
Coin, 68.} which is fifteen pence above the mint price. Even before
the
late recoinage of the gold, therefore, the coin, gold and silver
together,
when compared with silver bullion, was not supposed to be more
than
eight per cent. below its standard value, In 1695, on the contrary, it
had
been supposed to be near five-and-twenty per cent. below that value. But
in the
beginning of the present century, that is, immediately after the
great
recoinage in King William's time, the greater part of the current
silver
coin must have been still nearer to its standard weight than it is at
present.
In the course of the present century, too, there has been no great
public
calamity, such as a civil war, which could either discourage tillage,
or
interrupt the interior commerce of the country. And though the bounty
which
has taken place through the greater part of this century, must always
raise
the price of corn somewhat higher than it otherwise would be in the
actual
state of tillage ; yet, as in the course of this century, the bounty
has had
full time to produce all the good effects commonly imputed to it to
encourage
tillage, and thereby to increase the quantity of corn in the home
market,
it may, upon the principles of a system which I shall explain and
examine
hereafter, be supposed to have done something to lower the price of
that
commodity the one way, as well as to raise it the other. It is by many
people
supposed to have done more. In the sixty-four years of the present
century,
accordingly, the average price of the quarter of nine bushels of
the
best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, by the accounts of Eton college,
to have
been £ 2:0:6 10/32, which is about ten shillings and sixpence, or
more
than five-and-twenty percent. cheaper than it had been during the
sixty-four
last years of the last century; and about nine shillings and
sixpence
cheaper than it had been during the sixteen years preceding 1636,
when
the discovery of the abundant mines of America may be supposed to have
produced
its full effect ; and about one shilling cheaper than it had been
in the
twenty-six years preceding 1620, before that discovery can well be
supposed
to have produced its full effect. According to this account, the
average
price of middle wheat, during these sixty-four first years of the
present
century, comes out to have been about thirty-two shillings the
quarter
of eight bushels.
The
value of silver, therefore, seems to have risen somewhat in proportion
to that
of corn during the course of the present century, and it had
probably
begun to do so even some time before the end of the last.
In
1687, the price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best wheat, at
Windsor
market, was £ 1:5:2, the lowest price at which it had ever been from
1595.
In
1688, Mr Gregory King, a man famous for his knowledge in matters of this
kind,
estimated the average price of wheat, in years of moderate plenty, to
be to
the grower 3s. 6d. the bushel, or eight-and-twenty shillings the
quarter.
The grower's price I understand to be the same with what is
sometimes
called the contract price, or the price at which a farmer
contracts
for a certain number of years to deliver a certain quantity of
corn to
a dealer. As a contract of this kind saves the farmer the expense
and
trouble of marketing, the contract price is generally lower than what is
supposed
to be the average market price. Mr King had judged eight-and-twenty
shillings
the quarter to be at that time the ordinary contract price in
years
of moderate plenty. Before the scarcity occasioned by the late
extraordinary
course of bad seasons, it was, I have been assured, the
ordinary
contract price in all common years.
In 1688
was granted the parliamentary bounty upon the exportation of corn.
The
country gentlemen, who then composed a still greater proportion of the
legislature
than they do at present, had felt that the money price of corn
was
falling. The bounty was an expedient to raise it artificially to the
high
price at which it had frequently been sold in the times of Charles I.
and II.
It was to take place, therefore, till wheat was so high as
fortyeight
shillings the quarter; that is, twenty shillings, or 5-7ths
dearer
than Mr King had, in that very year, estimated the grower's price to
be in
times of moderate plenty. If his calculations deserve any part of the
reputation
which they have obtained very universally, eight-and-forty
shillings
the quarter was a price which, without some such expedient as the
bounty,
could not at that time be expected, except in years of extraordinary
scarcity.
But the government of King William was not then fully settled. It
was in
no condition to refuse anything to the country gentlemen, from whom
it was,
at that very time, soliciting the first establishment of the annual
land-tax,
The
value of silver, therefore, in proportion to that of corn, had probably
risen
somewhat before the end of the last century; and it seems to have
continued
to do so during the course of the greater part of the present,
though
the necessary operation of the bounty must have hindered that rise
from
being so sensible as it otherwise would have been in the actual state
of
tillage.
In
plentiful years, the bounty, by occasioning an extraordinary exportation,
necessarily
raises the price of corn above what it otherwise would be in
those
years. To encourage tillage, by keeping up the price of corn, even in
the
most plentiful years, was the avowed end of the institution.
In
years of great scarcity, indeed, the bounty has generally been suspended.
It
must, however, have had some effect upon the prices of many of those
years.
By the extraordinary exportation which it occasions in years of
plenty,
it must frequently hinder the plenty of one year from compensating
the
scarcity of another.
Both in
years of plenty and in years of scarcity, therefore, the bounty
raises
the price of corn above what it naturally would be in the actual
state
of tillage. If during the sixty-four
first years of the present
century,
therefore, the average price has been lower than during the
sixty-four
last years of the last century, it must, in the same state of
tillage,
have been much more so, had it not been for this operation of the
bounty.
But,
without the bounty, it may be said the state of tillage would not have
been
the same. What may have been the effects of this institution upon the
agriculture
of the country, I shall endeavour to explain hereafter, when I
come to
treat particularly of bounties. I shall only observe at present,
that
this rise in the value of silver, in proportion to that of corn, has
not
been peculiar to England. It has been observed to have taken place in
France
during the same period, and nearly in the same proportion, too, by
three
very faithful, diligent, and laborious collectors of the prices of
corn,
Mr Dupré de St Maur, Mr Messance, and the author of the Essay on the
Police
of Grain. But in France, till 1764,
the exportation of grain was by
law
prohibited ; and it is somewhat difficult to suppose, that nearly the
same
diminution of price which took place in one country, notwithstanding
this
prohibition. should, in another, be owing to the extraordinary
encouragement
given to exportation.
It
would be more proper, perhaps, to consider this variation in the average
money
price of corn as the effect rather of some gradual rise in the real
value
of silver in the European market, than of any fall in the real average
value
of corn. Corn, it has already been observed, is, at distant periods of
time, a
more accurate measure of value than either silver or, perhaps, any
other
commodity. When, after the discovery of the abundant mines of America,
corn
rose to three and four times its former money price, this change was
universally
ascribed, not to any rise in the real value of corn, but to a
fall in
the real value of silver. If, during the sixty-four first years of
the
present century, therefore, the average money price of corn has fallen
somewhat
below what it had been during the greater part of the last century,
we
should, in the same manner, impute this change, not to any fall in the
real
value of corn, but to some rise in the real value of silver in the
European
market.
The high
price of corn during these ten or twelve years past, indeed, has
occasioned
a suspicion that the real value of silver still continues to fall
in the
European market. This high price of corn, however. seems evidently to
have
been the effect of the extraordinary unfavourableness of the seasons,
and
ought, therefore, to be regarded, not as a permanent, but as a
transitory
and occasional event. The seasons, for these ten or twelve years
past,
have been unfavourable through the greater part of Europe; and the
disorders
of Poland have very much increased the scarcity in all those
countries,
which, in dear years, used to be supplied from that market. So
long a
course of bad seasons, though not a very common event, is by no means
a
singular one; and whoever has inquired much into the history of the prices
of corn
in former times, will be at no loss to recollect several other
examples
of the same kind. Ten years of extraordinary scarcity, besides, are
not
more wonderful than ten years of extraordinary plenty. The low price of
corn,
from 1741 to 1750, both inclusive, may very well be set in opposition
to its
high price during these last eight or ten years. From 1741 to 1750,
the
average price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best wheat, at
Windsor
market, it appears from the accounts of Eton college, was only £
1:13:9
4/5, which is nearly 6s.3d. below the average price of the sixty-four
first
years of the present century. The average price of the quarter of
eight
bushels of middle wheat comes out, according to this account, to have
been,
during these ten years, only £ 1:6:8.
Between
1741 and 1750, however, the bounty must have hindered the price of
corn
from falling so low in the home market as it naturally would have done.
During
these ten years, the quantity of all sorts of grain exported, it
appears
from the custom-house books, amounted to no less than 8,029,156
quarters,
one bushel. The bounty paid for this amounted to £ 1,514,962:17:4
1/2. In
1749, accordingly, Mr Pelham, at that time prime minister, observed
to the
house of commons, that, for the three years preceding, a very
extraordinary
sum had been paid as bounty for the exportation of corn. He
had
good reason to make this observation, and in the following year he might
have
had still better. In that single year, the bounty paid amounted to no
less
than £ 324,176:10:6. {See Tracts on the Corn Trade, Tract 3,} It is
unnecessary
to observe how much this forced exportation must have raised the
price
of corn above what it otherwise would have been in the home market.
At the
end of the accounts annexed to this chapter the reader will find the
particular
account of those ten years separated from the rest. He will find
there,
too, the particular account of the preceding ten years, of which the
average
is likewise below, though not so much below, the general average of
the
sixty-four first years of the century. The year 1740, however, was a
year of
extraordinary scarcity. These twenty years preceding 1750 may very
well be
set in opposition to the twenty preceding 1770. As the former were a
good
deal below the general average of the century, notwithstanding the
intervention
of one or two dear years; so the latter have been a good deal
above
it, notwithstanding the intervention of one or two cheap ones, of
1759,
for example. If the former have not been as much below the general
average
as the latter have been above it, we ought probably to impute it to
the
bounty. The change has evidently been too sudden to he ascribed to any
change
in the value of silver, which is always slow and gradual. The
suddenness
of the effect can be accounted for only by a cause which can
operate
suddenly, the accidental variations of the seasons.
The
money price of labour in Great Britain has, indeed, risen during the
course
of the present century. This, however, seems to be the effect, not so
much of
any diminution in the value of silver in the European market, as of
an
increase in the demand for labour in Great Britain, arising from the
great,
and almost universal prosperity of the country. In France, a country
not
altogether so prosperous, the money price of labour has, since the
middle
of the last century, been observed to sink gradually with the average
money
price of corn. Both in the last century and in the present, the day
wages
of common labour are there said to have been pretty uniformly about
the
twentieth part of the average price of the septier of wheat ; a measure
which
contains a little more than four Winchester bushels. In Great Britain,
the
real recompence of labour, it has already been shewn, the real
quantities
of the necessaries and conveniencies of life which are given to
the
labourer, has increased considerably during the course of the present
century.
The rise in its money price seems to have been the effect, not of
any
diminution of the value of silver in the general market of Europe, but
of a
rise in the real price of labour, in the particular market of Great
Britain,
owing to the peculiarly happy circumstances of the country.
For
some time after the first discovery of America, silver would continue to
sell at
its former, or not much below its former price. The profits of
mining
would for some time be very great, and much above their natural rate.
Those
who imported that metal into Europe, however, would soon find that the
whole
annual importation could not be disposed of at this high price. Silver
would
gradually exchange for a smaller and a smaller quantity of goods. Its
price
would sink gradually lower and lower, till it fell to its natural
price ;
or to what was just sufficient to pay, according to their natural
rates,
the wages of the labour, the profits of the stock, and the rent of
the
land, which must be paid in order to bring it from the mine to the
market.
In the greater part of the silver mines of Peru, the tax of the king
of
Spain, amounting to a tenth of the gross produce, eats up, it has already
been
observed, the whole rent of the land. This tax was originally a half;
it soon
afterwards fell to a third, then to a fifth, and at last to a tenth,
at
which late it still continues. In the greater part of the silver mines of
Peru,
this, it seems, is all that remains, after replacing the stock of the
undertaker
of the work, together with its ordinary profits ; and it seems to
be
universally acknowledged that these profits, which were once very high,
are now
as low as they can well be, consistently with carrying on the works.
The tax
of the king of Spain was reduced to a fifth of the registered silver
in
1504 {Solorzano, vol, ii.},
one-and-forty years before 1545, the date of
the
discovery of the mines of Potosi. In the course of ninety years, or
before
1636, these mines, the most fertile in all America, had time
sufficient
to produce their full effect, or to reduce the value of silver in
the
European market as low as it could well fall, while it continued to pay
this
tax to the king of Spain. Ninety years is time sufficient to reduce any
commodity,
of which there is no monopoly, to its natural price, or to the
lowest
price at which, while it pays a particular tax, it can continue to be
sold
for any considerable time together.
The
price of silver in the European market might, perhaps, have fallen still
lower,
and it might have become necessary either to reduce the tax upon it,
not
only to one-tenth, as in 1736, but to one twentieth, in the same manner
as that
upon gold, or to give up working the greater part of the American
mines
which are now wrought. The gradual increase of the demand for silver,
or the
gradual enlargement of the market for the produce of the silver mines
of
America, is probably the cause which has prevented this from happening,
and
which has not only kept up the value of silver in the European market,
but has
perhaps even raised it somewhat higher than it was about the middle
of the
last century.
Since
the first discovery of America, the market for the produce of its
silver
mines has been growing gradually more and more extensive.
First,
the market of Europe has become gradually more and more extensive.
Since
the discovery of America, the greater part of Europe has been much
improved.
England, Holland, France, and Germany; even Sweden, Denmark, and
Russia,
have all advanced considerably, both in agriculture and in
manufactures.
Italy seems not to have gone backwards. The fall of Italy
preceded
the conquest of Peru. Since that time it seems rather to have
recovered
a little. Spain and Portugal, indeed, are supposed to have gone
backwards.
Portugal, however, is but a very small part of Europe, and the
declension
of Spain is not, perhaps, so great as is commonly imagined. In the
beginning
of the sixteenth century, Spain was a very poor country, even in
comparison
with France, which has been so much improved since that time. It
was the
well known remark of the emperor Charles V. who had travelled so
frequently
through both countries, that every thing abounded in France, but
that
every thing was wanting in Spain. The increasing produce of the
agriculture
and manufactures of Europe must necessarily have required a
gradual
increase in the quantity of silver coin to circulate it ; and the
increasing
number of wealthy individuals must have required the like
increase
in the quantity of their plate and other ornaments of silver.
Secondly,
America is itself a new market, for the produce of its own silver
mines;
and as its advances in agriculture, industry, and population, are
much
more rapid than those of the most thriving countries in Europe, its
demand
must increase much more rapidly. The English colonies are altogether
a new
market, which, partly for coin, and partly for plate, requires a
continual
augmenting supply of silver through a great continent where there
never
was any demand before. The greater part, too, of the Spanish and
Portuguese
colonies, are altogether new markets. New Granada, the Yucatan,
Paraguay,
and the Brazils, were, before discovered by the Europeans,
inhabited
by savage nations, who had neither arts nor agriculture. A
considerable
degree of both has now been introduced into all of them. Even
Mexico
and Peru, though they cannot be considered as altogether new markets,
are
certainly much more extensive ones than they ever were before. After all
the wonderful
tales which have been published concerning the splendid state
of
those countries in ancient times, whoever reads, with any degree of sober
judgment,
the history of their first discovery and conquest, will evidently
discern
that, in arts, agriculture, and commerce, their inhabitants were
much
more ignorant than the Tartars of the Ukraine are at present. Even the
Peruvians,
the more civilized nation of the two, though they made use of
gold
and silver as ornaments, had no coined money of any kind. Their whole
commerce
was carried on by barter, and there was accordingly scarce any
division
of labour among them. Those who cultivated the ground, were obliged
to
build their own houses, to make their own household furniture, their own
clothes,
shoes, and instruments of agriculture. The few artificers among
them
are said to have been all maintained by the sovereign, the nobles, and
the
priests, and were probably their servants or slaves. All the ancient
arts of
Mexico and Peru have never furnished one single manufacture to
Europe.
The Spanish armies, though they scarce ever exceeded five hundred
men,
and frequently did not amount to half that number, found almost
everywhere
great difficulty in procuring subsistence. The famines which they
are
said to have occasioned almost wherever they went, in countries, too,
which
at the same time are represented as very populous and well cultivated,
sufficiently
demonstrate that the story of this populousness and high
cultivation
is in a great measure fabulous. The Spanish colonies are under a
government
in many respects less favourable to agriculture, improvement, and
population,
than that of the English colonies. They seem, however, to be
advancing
in all those much more rapidly than any country in Europe. In a
fertile
soil and happy climate, the great abundance and cheapness of land, a
circumstance
common to all new colonies, is, it seems, so great an
advantage,
as to compensate many defects in civil government. Frezier, who
visited
Peru in 1713, represents Lima as containing between twenty-five and
twenty-eight
thousand inhabitants. Ulloa, who resided in the same country
between
1740 and 1746, represents it as containing more than fifty thousand.
The
difference in their accounts of the populousness of several other
principal
towns of Chili and Peru is nearly the same ; and as there seems to
be no
reason to doubt of the good information of either, it marks an
increase
which is scarce inferior to that of the English colonies. America,
therefore,
is a new market for the produce of its own silver mines, of which
the
demand must increase much more rapidly than that of the most thriving
country
in Europe.
Thirdly,
the East Indies is another market for the produce of the silver
mines
of America, and a market which, from the time of the first discovery
of
those mines, has been continually taking off a greater and a greater
quantity
of silver. Since that time, the direct trade between America and
the
East Indies, which is carried on by means of the Acapulco ships, has
been
continually augmenting, and the indirect intercourse by the way of
Europe
has been augmenting in a still greater proportion. During the
sixteenth
century, the Portuguese were the only European nation who carried
on any regular
trade to the East Indies. In the last years of that century,
the
Dutch began to encroach upon this monopoly, and in a few years expelled
them
from their principal settlements in India.
During the greater part of
the
last century, those two nations divided the most considerable part of
the
East India trade between them; the trade of the Dutch continually
augmenting
in a still greater proportion than that of the Portuguese
declined.
The English and French carried on some trade with India in the
last
century, but it has been greatly augmented in the course of the
present.
The East India trade of the Swedes and Danes began in the course of
the
present century. Even the Muscovites now trade regularly with China, by
a sort
of caravans which go over land through Siberia and Tartary to Pekin.
The
East India trade of all these nations, if we except that of the French,
which
the last war had well nigh annihilated, has been almost continually
augmenting.
The increasing consumptions of East India goods in Europe is, it
seems,
so great, as to afford a gradual increase of employment to them all.
Tea,
for example, was a drug very little used in Europe, before the middle
of the
last century. At present, the value of the tea annually imported by
the English
East India company, for the use of their own countrymen, amounts
to more
than a million and a half a year; and even this is not enough; a
great
deal more being constantly smuggled into the country from the ports of
Holland,
from Gottenburgh in Sweden, and from the coast of France, too, as
long as
the French East India company was in prosperity. The consumption of
the
porcelain of China, of the spiceries of the Moluccas, of the piece goods
of
Bengal, and of innumerable other articles, has increased very nearly in a
like
proportion. The tonnage, accordingly, of all the European shipping
employed
in the East India trade, at any one time during the last century,
was
not, perhaps, much greater than that of the English East India company
before
the late reduction of their shipping.
But in
the East Indies, particularly in China and Indostan, the value of the
precious
metals, when the Europeans first began to trade to those countries,
was
much higher than in Europe; and it still continues to be so. In rice
countries,
which generally yield two, sometimes three crops in the year,
each of
them more plentiful than any common crop of corn, the abundance of
food
must be much greater than in any corn country of equal extent. Such
countries
are accordingly much more populous. In them, too, the rich, having
a
greater superabundance of food to dispose of beyond what they themselves
can
consume, have the means of purchasing a much greater quantity of the
labour
of other people. The retinue of a grandee in China or Indostan
accordingly
is, by all accounts, much more numerous and splendid than that
of the
richest subjects in Europe. The same superabundance of food, of which
they
have the disposal, enables them to give a greater quantity of it for
all
those singular and rare productions which nature furnishes but in very
small
quantities; such as the precious metals and the precious stones, the
great
objects of the competition of the rich. Though the mines, therefore,
which
supplied the Indian market, had been as abundant as those which
supplied
the European, such commodities would naturally exchange for a
greater
quantity of food in India than in Europe. But the mines which
supplied
the Indian market with the precious metals seem to have been a good
deal
less abundant, and those which supplied it with the precious stones a
good
deal more so, than the mines which supplied the European. The precious
metals,
therefore, would naturally exchange in India for a somewhat greater
quantity
of the precious stones, and for a much greater quantity of food
than in
Europe. The money price of diamonds, the greatest of all
superfluities,
would be somewhat lower, and that of food, the first of all
necessaries,
a great deal lower in the one country than in the other. But
the
real price of labour, the real quantity of the necessaries of life which
is
given to the labourer, it has already been observed, is lower both in
China
and Indostan, the two great markets of India, than it is through the
greater
part of Europe. The wages of the labourer will there purchase a
smaller
quantity of food: and as the money price of food is much lower in
India
than in Europe, the money price of labour is there lower upon a double
account;
upon account both of the small quantity of food which it will
purchase,
and of the low price of that food. But in countries of equal art
and
industry, the money price of the greater part of manufactures will be in
proportion
to the money price of labour; and in manufacturing art and
industry,
China and Indostan, though inferior, seem not to be much inferior
to any
part of Europe. The money price of the greater part of manufactures,
therefore,
will naturally be much lower in those great empires than it is
anywhere
in Europe. Through the greater part of Europe, too, the expense of
land-carriage
increases very much both the real and nominal price of most
manufactures.
It costs more labour, and therefore more money, to bring first
the
materials, and afterwards the complete manufacture to market. In China
and
Indostan, the extent and variety of inland navigations save the greater
part of
this labour, and consequently of this money, and thereby reduce
still
lower both the real and the nominal price of the greater part of their
manufactures.
Upon all these accounts, the precious metals are a commodity
which
it always has been, and still continues to be, extremely advantageous
to
carry from Europe to India. There is
scarce any commodity which
brings
a better price there; or which, in proportion to the quantity of
labour
and commodities which it costs in Europe. will purchase or command a
greater
quantity of labour and commodities in India. It is more
advantageous,
too, to carry silver thither than gold; because in China, and
the
greater part of the other markets of India, the proportion between fine
silver
and fine gold is but as ten, or at most as twelve to one; whereas in
Europe
it is as fourteen or fifteen to one. In China, and the greater part
of the
other markets of India, ten, or at most twelve ounces of silver, will
purchase
an ounce of gold ; in Europe, it requires from fourteen to fifteen
ounces. In the cargoes, therefore, of the greater
part of European ships
which
sail to India, silver has generally been one of the most valuable
articles.
It is the most valuable article in the Acapulco ships which sail
to
Manilla. The silver of the new continent seems, in this manner, to be one
of the
principal commodities by which the commerce between the two
extremities
of the old one is carried on ; and it is by means of it, in a
great
measure, that those distant parts of the world are connected with one
another.
In
order to supply so very widely extended a market, the quantity of silver
annually
brought from the mines must not only be sufficient to support that
continued
increase, both of coin and of plate, which is required in all
thriving
countries; but to repair that continual waste and consumption of
silver
which takes place in all countries where that metal is used.
The
continual consumption of the precious metals in coin by wearing, and in
plate
both by wearing and cleaning, is very sensible ; and in commodities of
which
the use is so very widely extended, would alone require a very great
annual
supply. The consumption of those metals in some particular
manufactures,
though it may not perhaps be greater upon the whole than this
gradual
consumption, is, however, much more sensible, as it is much more
rapid.
In the manufactures of Birmingham alone, the quantity of gold and
silver
annually employed in gilding and plating, and thereby disqualified
from
ever afterwards appearing in the shape of those metals, is said to
amount
to more than fifty thousand pounds sterling. We may from thence form
some
notion how great must be the annual consumption in all the different
parts
of the world, either in manufactures of the same kind with those of
Birmingham,
or in laces, embroideries, gold and silver stuffs, the gilding
of
books, furniture, etc. A considerable quantity, too, must be annually
lost in
transporting those metals from one place to another both by sea and
by
land. In the greater part of the governments of Asia, besides, the almost
universal
custom of concealing treasures in the bowels of the earth, of
which
the knowledge frequently dies with the person who makes the
concealment,
must occasion the loss of a still greater quantity.
The
quantity of gold and silver imported at both Cadiz and Lisbon (including
not
only what comes under register, but what may be supposed to be smuggled)
amounts,
according to the best accounts, to about six millions sterling
a-year.
According
to Mr Meggens {Postscript to the Universal Merchant p. 15 and 16.
This
postscript was not printed till 1756, three years after the publication
of the
book, which has never had a second edition. The postscript is,
therefore,
to be found in few copies ; it corrects several errors in the
book.},
the annual importation of the precious metals into Spain, at an
average
of six years, viz. from 1748 to 1753, both inclusive, and into
Portugal,
at an average of seven years, viz. from 1747 to 1753, both
inclusive,
amounted in silver to 1,101,107 pounds weight, and in gold to
49,940
pounds weight. The silver, at sixty two shillings the pound troy,
amounts
to £ 3,4l3,43l:10s. sterling. The gold, at forty-four guineas and a
half
the pound troy, amounts to £ 2,333,446:14s. sterling. Both together
amount
to £ 5,746,878:4s. sterling. The account of what was imported under
register,
he assures us, is exact. He gives us the detail of the particular
places
from which the gold and silver were brought, and of the particular
quantity
of each metal, which, according to the register, each of them
afforded.
He makes an allowance, too, for the quantity of each metal which,
he
supposes, may have been smuggled. The great experience of this judicious
merchant
renders his opinion of considerable weight.
According
to the eloquent, and sometimes well-informed, author of the
Philosophical
and Political History of the Establishment of the Europeans in
the two
Indies, the annual importation of registered gold and silver into
Spain,
at an average of eleven years, viz. from 1754 to 1764, both
inclusive,
amounted to 13,984,185 3/5 piastres of ten reals. On account of
what
may have been smuggled, however, the whole annual importation, he
supposes,
may have amounted to seventeen millions of piastres, which, at 4s.
6d. the
piastre, is equal to £ 3,825,000 sterling. He gives the detail, too,
of the
particular places from which the gold and silver were brought, and of
the
particular quantities of each metal, which according to the register,
each of
them afforded. He informs us, too, that if we were to judge of the
quantity
of gold annually imported from the Brazils to Lisbon, by the amount
of the
tax paid to the king of Portugal, which it seems, is one-fifth of the
standard
metal, we might value it at eighteen millions of cruzadoes, or
forty-five
millions of French livres, equal to about twenty millions
sterling.
On account of what may have been smuggled, however, we may safely,
he
says, add to this sum an eighth more, or £ 250,000 sterling, so that the
whole
will amount to £ 2,250,000 sterling. According to this account,
therefore,
the whole annual importation of the precious metals into both
Spain
and Portugal, mounts to about £ 6,075,000 sterling.
Several
other very well authenticated, though manuscript accounts, I have
been
assured, agree in making this whole annual importation amount, at an
average,
to about six millions sterling; sometimes a little more, sometimes
a
little less.
The
annual importation of the precious metals into Cadiz and Lisbon, indeed,
is not
equal to the whole annual produce of the mines of America. Some part
is sent
annually by the Acapulco ships to Manilla; some part is employed in
a
contraband trade, which the Spanish colonies carry on with those of other
European
nations; and some part, no doubt, remains in the country. The mines
of
America, besides, are by no means the only gold and silver mines in the
world.
They, are, however, by far the most abundant. The produce of all the
other
mines which are known is insignificant, it is acknowledged, in
comparison
with their's ; and the far greater part of their produce, it is
likewise
acknowledged, is annually imported into Cadiz and Lisbon. But the
consumption
of Birmingham alone, at the rate of fifty thousand pounds
a-year,
is equal to the hundred-and-twentieth part of this annual
importation,
at the rate of six millions a-year. The whole annual
consumption
of gold and silver, therefore, in all the different countries of
the
world where those metals are used, may, perhaps, be nearly equal to the
whole
annual produce. The remainder may be no more than sufficient to supply
the
increasing demand of all thriving countries. It may even have fallen so
far
short of this demand, as somewhat to raise the price of those metals in
the
European market.
The
quantity of brass and iron annually brought from the mine to the market,
is out
of all proportion greater than that of gold and silver. We do not,
however,
upon this account, imagine that those coarse metals are likely to
multiply
beyond the demand, or to become gradually cheaper and cheaper. Why
should
we imagine that the precious metals are likely to do so? The coarse
metals,
indeed, though harder, are put to much harder uses, and, as they are
of less
value, less care is employed in their preservation. The precious
metals,
however, are not necessarily immortal any more than they, but are
liable,
too, to be lost, wasted, and consumed, in a great variety of ways.
The
price of all metals, though liable to slow and gradual variations,
varies
less from year to year than that of almost any other part of the rude
produce
of land: and the price of the precious metals is even less liable to
sudden
variations than that of the coarse ones. The durableness of metals is
the
foundation of this extraordinary steadiness of price. The corn which was
brought
to market last year will be all, or almost all, consumed, long
before
the end of this year. But some part of the iron which was brought
from:
the mine two or three hundred years ago, may be still in use, and,
perhaps,
some part of the gold which was brought from it two or three
thousand
years ago. The different masses of corn, which, in different years,
must
supply the consumption of the world, will always be nearly in
proportion
to the respective produce of those different years. But the
proportion
between the different masses of iron which may be in use in two
different
years, will be very little affected by any accidental difference
in the
produce of the iron mines of those two years ; and the proportion
between
the masses of gold will be still less affected by any such
difference
in the produce of the gold mines. Though the produce of the
greater
part of metallic mines, therefore, varies, perhaps, still more from
year to
year than that of the greater part of corn fields, those variations
have
not the same effect upon the price of the one species of commodities as
upon
that of the other.
Variations
in the Proportion between the respective Values of Gold and
Silver.
Before
the discovery of the mines of America, the value of fine gold to fine
silver
was regulated in the different mines of Europe, between the
proportions
of one to ten and one to twelve ; that is, an ounce of fine gold
was
supposed to be worth from ten to twelve ounces of fine silver. About the
middle
of the last century, it came to be regulated, between the proportions
of one
to fourteen and one to fifteen; that is, an ounce of fine gold came
to be
supposed worth between fourteen and fifteen ounces of fine silver.
Gold
rose in its nominal value, or in the quantity of silver which was given
for it.
Both metals sunk in their real value, or in the quantity of labour
which
they could purchase; but silver sunk more than gold. Though both the
gold
and silver mines of America exceeded in fertility all those which had
ever
been known before, the fertility of the silver mines had, it seems,
been
proportionally still greater than that of the gold ones.
The
great quantities of silver carried annually from Europe to India, have,
in some
of the English settlements, gradually reduced the value of that
metal
in proportion to gold. In the mint of Calcutta, an ounce of fine gold
is
supposed to be worth fifteen ounces of fine silver, in the same manner as
in
Europe. It is in the mint, perhaps, rated too high for the value which it
bears
in the market of Bengal. In China, the proportion of gold to silver
still
continues as one to ten, or one to twelve. In Japan, it is said to be
as one
to eight.
The
proportion between the quantities of gold and silver annually imported
into
Europe, according to Mr Meggens' account, is as one to twenty-two
nearly
; that is, for one ounce of gold there are imported a little more
than
twenty-two ounces of silver. The great quantity of silver sent annually
to the
East Indies reduces, he supposes, the quantities of those metals
which
remain in Europe to the proportion of one to fourteen or fifteen, the
proportion
of their values. The proportion between their values, he seems to
think,
must necessarily be the same as that between their quantities, and
would
therefore be as one to twenty-two, were it not for this greater
exportation
of silver.
But the
ordinary proportion between the respective values of two commodities
is not
necessarily the same as that between the quantities of them which are
commonly
in the market. The price of an ox, reckoned at ten guineas, is
about
three score times the price of a lamb, reckoned at 3s. 6d. It would be
absurd,
however, to infer from thence, that there are commonly in the market
three
score lambs for one ox ; and it would be just as absurd to infer,
because
an ounce of gold will commonly purchase from fourteen or fifteen
ounces
of silver, that there are commonly in the market only fourteen or
fifteen
ounces of silver for one ounce of gold.
The
quantity of silver commonly in the market, it is probable, is much
greater
in proportion to that of gold, than the value of a certain quantity
of gold
is to that of an equal quantity of silver. The whole quantity of a
cheap
commodity brought to market is commonly not only greater, but of
greater
value, than the whole quantity of a dear one. The whole quantity of
bread
annually brought to market, is not only greater, but of greater value,
than
the whole quantity of butcher's meat; the whole quantity of butcher's
meat,
than the whole quantity of poultry ; and the whole quantity of
poultry,
than the whole quantity of wild fowl. There are so many more
purchasers
for the cheap than for the dear commodity, that, not only a
greater
quantity of it, but a greater value can commonly be disposed of. The
whole
quantity, therefore, of the cheap commodity, must commonly be greater
in
proportion to the whole quantity of the dear one, than the value of a
certain
quantity of the dear one, is to the value of an equal quantity of
the
cheap one. When we compare the precious metals with one another, silver
is a
cheap, and gold a dear commodity. We ought naturally to expect,
therefore,
that there should always be in the market, not only a greater
quantity,
but a greater value of silver than of gold. Let any man, who has a
little
of both, compare his own silver with his gold plate, and he will
probably
find, that not only the quantity, but the value of the former,
greatly
exceeds that of the latter. Many people, besides, have a good deal
of
silver who have no gold plate, which, even with those who have it, is
generally
confined to watch-cases, snuff-boxes, and such like trinkets, of
which
the whole amount is seldom of great value. In the British coin,
indeed,
the value of the gold preponderates greatly, but it is not so in
that of
all countries. In the coin of some countries, the value of the two
metals
is nearly equal. In the Scotch coin, before the union with England,
the
gold preponderated very little, though it did somewhat {See Ruddiman's
Preface
to Anderson's Diplomata, etc. Scotiae.}, as it appears by the
accounts
of the mint. In the coin of many countries the silver
preponderates.
In France, the largest sums are commonly paid in that metal,
and it
is there difficult to get more gold than what is necessary to carry
about
in your pocket. The superior value, however, of the silver plate above
that of
the gold, which takes place in all countries, will much more than
compensate
the preponderancy of the gold coin above the silver, which takes
place
only in some countries.
Though,
in one sense of the word, silver always has been, and probably
always
will be, much cheaper than gold ; yet, in another sense, gold may
perhaps,
in the present state of the Spanish market, be said te be somewhat
cheaper
than silver. A commodity may be said to be dear or cheap not only
according
to the absolute greatness or smallness of its usual price, but
according
as that price is more or less above the lowest for which it is
possible
to bring it to market for any considerable time together. This
lowest
price is that which barely replaces, with a moderate profit, the
stock
which must be employed in bringing the commodity thither. It is the
price
which affords nothing to the landlord, of which rent makes not any
component
part, but which resolves itself altogether into wages and profit.
But, in
the present state of the Spanish market, gold is certainly somewhat
nearer
to this lowest price than silver. The tax of the king of Spain upon
gold is
only one-twentieth part of the standard metal, or five per cent.;
whereas
his tax upon silver amounts to one-tenth part of it, or to ten per
cent.
In these taxes, too, it has already been observed, consists the whole
rent of
the greater part of the gold and silver mines of Spanish America;
and
that upon gold is still worse paid than that upon silver. The profits of
the
undertakers of gold mines, too, as they more rarely make a fortune,
must,
in general, be still more moderate than those of the undertakers of
silver
mines. The price of Spanish gold, therefore, as it affords both less
rent
and less profit, must, in the Spanish market, be somewhat nearer to the
lowest
price for which it is possible to bring it thither, than the price of
Spanish
silver. When all expenses are computed, the whole quantity of the
one
metal, it would seem, cannot, in the Spanish market, be disposed of so
advantageously
as the whole quantity of the other. The tax, indeed, of the
king of
Portugal upon the gold of the Brazils, is the same with the ancient
tax of
the king of Spain upon the silver of Mexico and Peru; or one-fifth
part of
the standard metal. It may therefore be uncertain, whether, to the
general
market of Europe, the whole mass of American gold comes at a price
nearer
to the lowest for which it is possible to bring it thither, than the
whole
mass of American silver.
The
price of diamonds and other precious stones may, perhaps, be still
nearer
to the lowest price at which it is possible to bring them to market,
than
even the price of gold.
Though
it is not very probable that any part of a tax, which is not only
imposed
upon one of the most proper subjects of taxation, a mere luxury and
superfluity,
but which affords so very important a revenue as the tax upon
silver,
will ever be given up as long as it is possible to pay it; yet the
same
impossibility of paying it, which, in 1736. made it necessary to reduce
it from
one-fifth to one-tenth, may in time make it necessary to reduce it
still
further ; in the same manner as it made it necessary to reduce the tax
upon
gold to one-twentieth. That the silver mines of Spanish America, like
all
other mines, become gradually more expensive in the working, on account
of the
greater depths at which it is necessary to carry on the works, and of
the
greater expense of drawing out the water, and of supplying them with
fresh
air at those depths, is acknowledged by everybody who has inquired
into
the state of those mines.
These
causes, which are equivalent to a growing scarcity of silver (for a
commodity
may be said to grow scarcer when it becomes more difficult and
expensive
to collect a certain quantity of it), must, in time, produce one
or
other of the three following events: The increase of the expense must
either,
first, be compensated altogether by a proportionable increase in the
price
of the metal ; or, secondly, it must be compensated altogether by a
proportionable
diminution of the tax upon silver ; or, thirdly, it must be
compensated
partly by the one and partly by the other of those two
expedients.
This third event is very possible. As gold rose in its price in
proportion
to silver, notwithstanding a great diminution of the tax upon
gold,
so silver might rise in its price in proportion to labour and
commodities,
notwithstanding an equal diminution of the tax upon silver.
Such
successive reductions of the tax, however, though they may not
prevent
altogether, must certainly retard, more or less, the rise of the
value
of silver in the European market. In consequence of such reductions,
many
mines may be wrought which could not be wrought before, because they
could
not afford to pay the old tax ; and the quantity of silver annually
brought
to market, must always be somewhat greater, and, therefore, the
value
of any given quantity somewhat less, than it otherwise would have
been.
In consequence of the reduction in 1736, the value of silver in the
European
market, though it may not at this day be lower than before that
reduction,
is, probably, at least ten per cent. lower than it would have
been,
had the court of Spain continued to exact the old tax.
That,
notwithstanding this reduction, the value of silver has, during the
course
of the present century, begun to rise somewhat in the European
market,
the facts and arguments which have been alleged above, dispose me to
believe,
or more properly to suspect and conjecture; for the best opinion
which I
can form upon this subject, scarce, perhaps, deserves the name of
belief.
The rise, indeed, supposing there has been any, has hitherto been so
very
small, that after all that has been said, it may, perhaps, appear to
many
people uncertain, not only whether this event has actually taken place,
but
whether the contrary may not have taken place, or whether the value of
silver
may not still continue to fall in the European market.
It must
be observed, however, that whatever may be the supposed annual
importation
of gold and silver, there must be a certain period at which the
annual
consumption of those metals will be equal to that annual importation.
Their
consumption must increase as their mass increases, or rather in a much
greater
proportion. As their mass increases, their value diminishes. They
are
more used, and less cared for, and their consumption consequently
increases
in a greater proportion than their mass. After a certain period,
therefore,
the annual consumption of those metals must, in this manner,
become
equal to their annual importation, provided that importation is not
continually
increasing; which, in the present times, is not supposed to be
the
case.
If,
when the annual consumption has become equal to the annual importation,
the
annual importation should gradually diminish, the annual consumption
may,
for some time, exceed the annual importation. The mass of those metals
may
gradually and insensibly diminish, and their value gradually and
insensibly
rise, till the annual importation becoming again stationary, the
annual
consumption will gradually and insensibly accommodate itself to what
that
annual importation can maintain.
Grounds
of the suspicion that the Value of Silver still continues to
decrease.
The
increase of the wealth of Europe, and the popular notion, that as the
quantity
of the precious metals naturally increases with the increase of
wealth,
so their value diminishes as their quantity increases, may, perhaps,
dispose
many people to believe that their value still continues to fall in
the European
market; and the still gradually increasing price of many parts
of the
rude produce of land may confirm them still farther in this opinion.
That
that increase in the quantity of the precious metals, which arises in
any
country from the increase of wealth, has no tendency to diminish their
value,
I have endeavoured to shew already. Gold and silver naturally resort
to a
rich country, for the same reason that all sorts of luxuries and
curiosities
resort to it ; not because they are cheaper there than in poorer
countries,
but because they are dearer, or because a better price is given
for
them. It is the superiority of price which attracts them; and as soon as
that
superiority ceases, they necessarily cease to go thither.
If you
except corn, and such other vegetables as are raised altogether by
human
industry, that all other sorts of rude produce, cattle, poultry, game
of all
kinds, the useful fossils and minerals of the earth, etc. naturally
grow
dearer, as the society advances in wealth and improvement, I have
endeavoured
to shew already. Though such commodities, therefore, come to
exchange
for a greater quantity of silver than before, it will not from
thence
follow that silver has become really cheaper, or will purchase less
labour
than before ; but that such commodities have become really dearer, or
will
purchase more labour than before. It is not their nominal price only,
but
their real price, which rises in the progress of improvement. The rise
of
their nominal price is the effect, not of any degradation of the value of
silver,
but of the rise in their real price.
Different
Effects of the Progress of Improvement upon three different sorts
of rude
Produce.
These
different sorts of rude produce may be divided into three classes. The
first
comprehends those which it is scarce in the power of human industry to
multiply
at all. The second, those which it can multiply in proportion to
the
demand. The third, those in which the efficacy of industry is either
limited
or uncertain. In the progress of wealth and improvement, the real
price
of the first may rise to any degree of extravagance, and seems not to
be
limited by any certain boundary. That of the second, though it may rise
greatly,
has, however, a certain boundary, beyond which it cannot well pass
for any
considerable time together. That of the third, though its natural
tendency
is to rise in the progress of improvement, yet in the same degree
of
improvement it may sometimes happen even to fall, sometimes to continue
the
same, and sometimes to rise more or less, according as different
accidents
render the efforts of human industry, in multiplying this sort of
rude
produce, more or less successful.
First
Sort. - The first sort of rude produce,
of which the price rises in the
progress
of improvement, is that which it is scarce in the power of human
industry
to multiply at all. It consists in those things which nature
produces
only in certain quantities, and which being of a very perishable
nature,
it is impossible to accumulate together the produce of many
different
seasons. Such are the greater part of rare and singular birds and
fishes,
many different sorts of game, almost all wild-fowl, all birds of
passage
in particular, as well as many other things. When wealth, and the
luxury
which accompanies it, increase, the demand for these is likely to
increase
with them, and no effort of human industry may be able to increase
the
supply much beyond what it was before this increase of the demand. The
quantity
of such commodities, therefore, remaining the same, or nearly the
same,
while the competition to purchase them is continually increasing,
their
price may rise to any degree of extravagance, and seems not to be
limited
by any certain boundary. If woodcocks
should
become
so fashionable as to sell for twenty guineas a-piece, no
effort
of human industry could increase the number of those brought to
market,
much beyond what it is at present. The high price paid by the
Romans,
in the time of their greatest grandeur, for rare birds and fishes,
may in
this manner easily be accounted for. These prices were not the
effects
of the low value of silver in those times, but of the high value of
such
rarities and curiosities as human industry could not multiply at
pleasure.
The real value of silver was higher at Rome, for sometime before,
and
after the fall of the republic, than it is through the greater part of
Europe
at present. Three sestertii equal to about sixpence sterling, was the
price
which the republic paid for the modius or peck of the tithe wheat of
Sicily.
This price, however, was probably below the average market price,
the
obligation to deliver their wheat at this rate being considered as a tax
upon
the Sicilian farmers. When the Romans, therefore, had occasion to order
more
corn than the tithe of wheat amounted to, they were bound by
capitulation
to pay for the surplus at the rate of four sestertii, or
eightpence
sterling the peck; and this had probably been reckoned the
moderate
and reasonable, that is, the ordinary or average contract price of
those
times; it is equal to about one-and-twenty shillings the quarter.
Eight-and-twenty
shillings the quarter was, before the late years of
scarcity,
the ordinary contract price of English wheat, which in quality is
inferior
to the Sicilian, and generally sells for a lower price in the
European
market. The value of silver, therefore, in those ancient times,
must
have been to its value in the present, as three to four inversely ;
that
is, three ounces of silver would then have purchased the same quantity
of
labour and commodities which four
ounces will do at present. When we
read in
Pliny, therefore, that Seius {Lib.X,c.29.} bought a white
nightingale,
as a present for the empress Agrippina, at the price of six
thousand
sestertii, equal to about fifty pounds of our present money ; and
that
Asinius Celer {Lib. IX,c. 17.} purchased a surmullet at the price of
eight
thousand sestertii, equal to about sixty-six pounds thirteen shillings
and fourpence
of our present money ; the extravagance of those prices, how
much
soever it may surprise us, is apt, notwithstanding, to appear to us
about
one third less than it really was. Their real price, the quantity of
labour
and subsistence which was given away for them, was about one-third
more
than their nominal price is apt to express to us in the present times.
Seius
gave for the nightingale the command of a quantity of labour and
subsistence,
equal to what £ 66:13: 4d. would purchase in the present times
; and
Asinius Celer gave for a surmullet the command of a quantity equal to
what £
88:17: 9d. would purchase. What occasioned the extravagance of those
high
prices was, not so much the abundance of silver, as the abundance of
labour
and subsistence, of which those Romans had the disposal, beyond what
was
necessary for their own use. The quantity of silver, of which they had
the
disposal, was a good deal less than what the command of the same
quantity
of labour and subsistence would have procured to them in the
present
times.
Second
sort. - The second sort of rude produce, of which the price rises in
the
progress of improvement, is that which human industry can multiply in
proportion
to the demand. It consists in those useful plants and animals,
which,
in uncultivated countries, nature produces with such profuse
abundance,
that they are of little or no value, and which, as cultivation
advances,
are therefore forced to give place to some more profitable
produce.
During a long period in the progress of improvement, the quantity
of
these is continually diminishing, while, at the same time, the demand for
them is
continually increasing. Their real value, therefore, the real
quantity
of labour which they will purchase or command, gradually rises,
till at
last it gets so high as to render them as profitable a produce as
any
thing else which human industry can raise upon the most fertile and best
cultivated
land. When it has got so high, it cannot well go higher. If it
did,
more land and more industry would soon be employed to increase their
quantity.
When
the price of cattle, for example, rises so high, that it is as
profitable
to cultivate land in order to raise food for them as in order to
raise
food for man, it cannot well go higher. If it did, more corn land
would
soon be turned into pasture. The extension of tillage, by diminishing
the
quantity of wild pasture, diminishes the quantity of butcher's meat,
which
the country naturally produces without labour or cultivation; and, by
increasing
the number of those who have either corn, or, what comes to the
same
thing, the price of corn, to give in exchange for it, increases the
demand.
The price of butcher's meat, therefore, and, consequently, of
cattle,
must gradually rise, till it gets so high, that it becomes as
profitable
to employ the most fertile and best cultivated lands in raising
food
for them as in raising corn. But it must always be late in the progress
of
improvement before tillage can be so far extended as to raise the price
of
cattle to this height ; and, till it has got to this height, if the
country
is advancing at all, their price must be continually rising. There
are,
perhaps, some parts of Europe in which the price of cattle has not yet
got to
this height. It had not got to this height in any part of Scotland
before
the Union. Had the Scotch cattle been always confined to the market
of
Scotland, in a country in which the quantity of land, which can be
applied
to no other purpose but the feeding of cattle, is so great in
proportion
to what can be applied to other purposes, it is scarce possible,
perhaps,
that their price could ever have risen so high as to render it
profitable
to cultivate land for the sake of feeding them. In England, the
price
of cattle, it has already been observed, seems, in the neighbourhood
of
London, to have got to this height about the beginning of the last
century;
but it was much later, probably, before it got through the greater
part of
the remoter counties, in some of which, perhaps, it may scarce yet
have
got to it. Of all the different substances, however, which compose this
second
sort of rude produce, cattle is, perhaps, that of which the price, in
the
progress of improvement, rises first to this height.
Till
the price of cattle, indeed, has got to this height, it seems scarce
possible
that the greater part, even of those lands which are capable of the
highest
cultivation, can be completely cultivated. In all farms too distant
from
any town to carry manure from it, that is, in the far greater part of
those
of every extensive country, the quantity of well cultivated land must
be in
proportion to the quantity of manure which the farm itself produces ;
and
this, again, must be in proportion to the stock of cattle which are
maintained
upon it. The land is manured, either by pasturing the cattle upon
it, or
by feeding them in the stable, and from thence carrying out their
dung to
it. But unless the price of the cattle be sufficient to pay both the
rent
and profit of cultivated land, the farmer cannot afford to pasture them
upon it
; and he can still less afford to feed them in the stable. It is
with
the produce of improved and cultivated land only that cattle can be fed
in the
stable; because, to collect the scanty and scattered produce of waste
and
unimproved lands, would require too much labour, and be too expensive.
It the
price of the cattle, therefore, is not sufficient to pay for the
produce
of improved and cuitivated land, when they are allowed to pasture
it,
that price will be still less sufficient to pay for that produce, when
it must
be collected with a good deal of additional labour, and brought into
the
stable to them. In these circumstances, therefore, no more cattle can
with
profit be fed in the stable than what are necessary for tillage. But
these
can never afford manure enough for keeping constantly in good
condition
all the lands which they are capable of cultivating. What they
afford,
being insufficient for the whole farm, will naturally be reserved
for the
lands to which it can be most advantageously or conveniently
applied;
the most fertile, or those, perhaps, in the neighbourhood of the
farm-yard.
These, therefore, will be kept constantly in good condition, and
fit for
tillage. The rest will, the greater part of them, be allowed to lie
waste,
producing scarce any thing but some miserable pasture, just
sufficient
to keep alive a few straggling, half-starved cattle; the farm,
though
much overstocked in proportion to what would be necessary for its
complete
cultivation, being very frequently overstocked in proportion to its
actual
produce. A portion of this waste land, however, after having been
pastured
in this wretched manner for six or seven years together, may be
ploughed
up, when it will yield, perhaps, a poor crop or two of bad oats, or
of some
other coarse grain ; and then, being entirely exhausted, it must be
rested
and pastured again as before, and another portion ploughed up, to be
in the
same manner exhausted and rested again in its turn. Such,
accordingly,
was the general system of management all over the low country
of
Scotland before the Union. The lands which were kept constantly well
manured
and in good condition seldom exceeded a third or fourth part of the
whole
farm, and sometimes did not amount to a fifth or a sixth part of it.
The
rest were never manured, but a certain portion of them was in its turn,
notwithstanding,
regularly cultivated and exhausted. Under this system of
management,
it is evident, even that part of the lands of Scotland which is
capable
of good cultivation, could produce but little in comparison of what
it may
be capable of producing. But how disadvantageous soever this system
may
appear, yet, before the Union, the low price of cattle seems to have
rendered
it almost unavoidable. If, notwithstanding a great rise in the
price,
it still continues to prevail through a considerable part of the
country,
it is owing in many places, no doubt, to ignorance and attachment
to old customs,
but, in most places, to the unavoidable obstructions which
the
natural course of things opposes to the immediate or speedy
establishment
of a better system : first, to the poverty of the tenants, to
their
not having yet had time to acquire a stock of cattle sufficient to
cultivate
their lands more completely, the same rise of price, which would
render
it advantageous for them to maintain a greater stock, rendering it
more
difficult for them to acquire it; and, secondly, to their not having
yet had
time to put their lands in condition to maintain this greater stock
properly,
supposing they were capable of acquiring it. The increase of stock
and the
improvement of land are two events which must go hand in hand, and
of
which the one can nowhere much outrun the other. Without some increase of
stock,
there can be scarce any improvement of land, but there can be no
considerable
increase of stock, but in consequence of a considerable
improvement
of land ; because otherwise the land could not maintain it.
These
natural obstructions to the establishment of a better system, cannot
be
removed but by a long course of frugality and industry ; and half a
century
or a century more, perhaps, must pass away before the old system,
which
is wearing out gradually, can be completely abolished through all the
different
parts of the country. Of all the commercial advantages, however,
which
Scotland has derived from the Union with England, this rise in the
price
of cattle is, perhaps, the greatest. It has not only raised the value
of all
highland estates, but it has, perhaps, been the principal cause of
the
improvement of the low country.
In all
new colonies, the great quantity of waste land, which can for many
years
be applied to no other purpose but the feeding of cattle, soon renders
them
extremely abundant ; and in every thing great cheapness is the
necessary
consequence of great abundance. Though all the cattle of the
European
colonies in America were originally carried from Europe, they soon
multiplied
so much there, and became of so little value, that even horses
were
allowed to run wild in the woods, without any owner thinking it worth
while
to claim them. It must be a long time after the first establishment of
such
colonies, before it can become profitable to feed cattle upon the
produce
of cultivated land. The same causes, therefore, the want of manure,
and the
disproportion between the stock employed in cultivation and the land
which
it is destined to cultivate, are likely to introduce there a system of
husbandry,
not unlike that which still continues to take place in so many
parts
of Scotland. Mr Kalm, the Swedish traveller, when he gives an account
of the
husbandry of some of the English colonies in North America, as he
found
it in 1749, observes, accordingly, that he can with difficulty
discover
there the character of the English nation, so well skilled in all
the
different branches of agriculture. They make scarce any manure for their
corn
fields, he says ; but when one piece of ground has been exhausted by
continual
cropping, they clear and cultivate another piece of fresh land;
and
when that is exhausted, proceed to a third. Their cattle are allowed to
wander
through the woods and other uncultivated grounds, where they are
half-starved;
having long ago extirpated almost all the annual grasses, by
cropping
them too early in the spring, before they had time to form their
flowers,
or to shed their seeds. {Kalm's Travels, vol 1, pp. 343, 344.} The
annual
grasses were, it seems, the best natural grasses in that part of
North
America; and when the Europeans first settled there, they used to grow
very
thick, and to rise three or four feet high. A piece of ground which,
when he
wrote, could not maintain one cow, would in former times, he was
assured,
have maintained four, each of which would have given four times
the
quantity of milk which that one was capable of giving. The poorness of
the
pasture had, in his opinion, occasioned the degradation of their cattle,
which
degenerated sensibly from me generation to another. They were probably
not
unlike that stunted breed which was common all over Scotland thirty or
forty
years ago, and which is now so much mended through the greater part of
the low
country, not so much by a change of the breed, though that expedient
has
been employed in some places, as by a more plentiful method of feeding
them.
Though
it is late, therefore, in the progress of improvement, before cattle
can
bring such a price as to render it profitable to cultivate land for the
sake of
feeding them; yet of all the different parts which compose this
second
sort of rude produce, they are perhaps the first which bring this
price ;
because, till they bring it, it seems impossible that improvement
can be
brought near even to that degree of perfection to which it has
arrived
in many parts of Europe.
As
cattle are among the first, so perhaps venison is among the last parts of
this
sort of rude produce which bring this price. The price of venison in
Great
Britain, how extravagant soever it may appear, is not near sufficient
to
compensate the expense of a deer park, as is well known to all those who
have
had any experience in the feeding of deer. If it was otherwise, the
feeding
of deer would soon become an article of common farming, in the same
manner
as the feeding of those small birds, called turdi, was among the
ancient
Romans. Varro and Columella assure us, that it was a most profitable
article.
The fattening of ortolans, birds of passage which arrive lean in
the
country, is said to be so in some parts of France. If venison continues
in
fashion, and the wealth and luxury of Great Britain increase as they have
done
for some time past, its price may very probably rise still higher than
it is at
present.
Between
that period in the progress of improvement, which brings to its
height
the price of so necessary an article as cattle, and that which brings
to it
the price of such a superfluity as venison, there is a very long
interval,
in the course of which many other sorts of rude produce gradually
arrive
at their highest price, some sooner and some later, according to
different
circumstances.
Thus,
in every farm, the offals of the barn and stable will maintain a
certain
number of poultry. These, as they are fed with what would otherwise
be
lost, are a mere save-all ; and as they cost the farmer scarce any thing,
so he
can afford to sell them for very little. Almost all that he gets is
pure
gain, and their price can scarce be so low as to discourage him from
feeding
this number. But in countries ill cultivated, and therefore but
thinly
inhabited, the poultry, which are thus raised without expense, are
often
fully sufficient to supply the whole demand. In this state of things,
therefore,
they are often as cheap as butcher's meat, or any other sort of
animal
food. But the whole quantity of poultry which the farm in this manner
produces
without expense, must always be much smaller than the whole
quantity
of butcher's meat which is reared upon it; and in times of wealth
and
luxury, what is rare, with only nearly equal merit, is always preferred
to what
is common. As wealth and luxury increase, therefore, in consequence
of
improvement and cultivation, the price of poultry gradually rises above
that of
butcher's meat, till at last it gets so high, that it becomes
profitable
to cultivate land for the sake of feeding them. When it has got
to this
height, it cannot well go higher. If it did, more land would soon be
turned
to this purpose. In several provinces of France, the feeding of
poultry
is considered as a very important article in rural economy, and
sufficiently
profitable to encourage the farmer to raise a considerable
quantity
of Indian corn and buckwheat for this purpose. A middling farmer
will
there sometimes have four hundred fowls in his yard. The feeding of
poultry
seems scarce yet to be generally considered as a matter of so much
importance
in England. They are certainly, however, dearer in England than
in
France, as England receives considerable supplies from France. In the
progress
of improvements, the period at which every particular sort of
animal
food is dearest, must naturally be that which immediately precedes
the
general practice of cultivating land for the sake of raising it. For
some
time before this practice becomes general, the scarcity must
necessarily
raise the price. After it has become general, new methods of
feeding
are commonly fallen upon, which enable the farmer to raise upon the
same
quantity of ground a much greater quantity of that particular sort of
animal
food. The plenty not only obliges him to sell cheaper, but, in
consequence
of these improvements, he can afford to sell cheaper; for if he
could
not afford it, the plenty would not be of long continuance. It has
been
probably in this manner that the introduction of clover, turnips,
carrots,
cabbages, etc. has contributed to sink the common price of
butcher's
meat in the London market, somewhat below what it was about the
beginning
of the last century.
The
hog, that finds his food among ordure, and greedily devours many things
rejected
by every other useful animal, is, like poultry, originally kept as
a
save-all. As long as the number of such animals, which can thus be reared
at
little or no expense, is fully sufficient to supply the demand, this sort
of
butcher's meat comes to market at a much lower price than any other. But
when
the demand rises beyond what this quantity can supply, when it becomes
necessary
to raise food on purpose for feeding and fattening hogs, in the
same
manner as for feeding and fattening other cattle, the price necessarily
rises,
and becomes proportionably either higher or lower than that of other
butcher's
meat, according as the nature of the country, and the state of its
agriculture,
happen to render the feeding of hogs more or less expensive
than
that of other cattle. In France, according to Mr Buffon, the price of
pork is
nearly equal to that of beef. In most parts of Great Britain it is
at
present somewhat higher.
The
great rise in the price both of hogs and poultry, has, in Great Britain,
been
frequently imputed to the diminution of the number of cottagers and
other
small occupiers of land ; an event which has in every part of Europe
been
the immediate forerunner of improvement and better cultivation, but
which
at the same time may have contributed to raise the price of those
articles,
both somewhat sooner and somewhat faster than it would otherwise
have
risen. As the poorest family can often maintain a cat or a dog without
any
expense, so the poorest occupiers of land can commonly maintain a few
poultry,
or a sow and a few pigs, at very little. The little offals of their
own
table, their whey, skimmed milk, and butter milk, supply those animals
with a
part of their food, and they find the rest in the neighbouring
fields,
without doing any sensible damage to any body. By diminishing the
number
of those small occupiers, therefore, the quantity of this sort of
provisions,
which is thus produced at little or no expense, must certainly
have
been a good deal diminished, and their price must consequently have
been
raised both sooner and faster than it would otherwise have risen.
Sooner
or later, however, in the progress of improvement, it must at any
rate
have risen to the utmost height to which it is capable of rising ; or
to the
price which pays the labour and expense of cultivating the land which
furnishes
them with food, as well as these are paid upon the greater part of
other
cultivated land.
The
business of the dairy, like the feeding of hogs and poultry, is
originally
carried on as a save-all. The cattle necessarily kept upon the
farm
produce more milk than either the rearing of their own young, or the
consumption
of the farmer's family requires ; and they produce most at one
particular
season. But of all the productions of land, milk is perhaps the
most
perishable. In the warm season, when it is most abundant, it will
scarce
keep four-and-twenty hours. The farmer, by making it into fresh
butter,
stores a small part of it for a week ; by making it into salt butter,
for a
year ; and by making it into cheese, he stores a much greater part of
it for
several years. Part of all these is reserved for the use of his own
family;
the rest goes to market, in order to find the best price which is to
be had,
and which can scarce be so low is to discourage him from sending
thither
whatever is over and above the use of his own family. If it is very
low
indeed, he will be likely to manage his dairy in a very slovenly and
dirty
manner, and will scarce, perhaps, think it worth while to have a
particular
room or building on purpose for it, but will suffer the business
to be
carried on amidst the smoke, filth, and nastiness of his own kitchen,
as was
the case of almost all the farmers' dairies in Scotland thirty or
forty
years ago, and as is the case of many of them still. The same causes
which
gradually raise the price of butcher's meat, the increase of the
demand,
and, in consequence of the improvement of the country, the
diminution
of the quantity which can be fed at little or no expense, raise,
in the
same manner, that of the produce of the dairy, of which the price
naturally
connects with that of butcher's meat, or with the expense of
feeding
cattle. The increase of price pays for more labour, care, and
cleanliness.
The dairy becomes more worthy of the farmer's attention, and
the
quality of its produce gradually improves. The price at last gets so
high,
that it becomes worth while to employ some of the most fertile and
best
cultivated lands in feeding cattle merely for the purpose of the dairy
; and
when it has got to this height, it cannot well go higher. If it did,
more
land would soon be turned to this purpose. It seems to have got to this
height
through the greater part of England, where much good land is commonly
employed
in this manner. If you except the neighbourhood of a few
considerable
towns, it seems not yet to have got to this height anywhere in
Scotland,
where common farmers seldom employ much good land in raising food
for
cattle, merely for the purpose of the dairy. The price of the produce,
though
it has risen very considerably within these few years, is probably
still
too low to admit of it. The inferiority of the quality, indeed,
compared
with that of the produce of English dairies, is fully equal to that
of the
price. But this inferiority of quality is, perhaps, rather the effect
of this
lowness of price, than the cause of it. Though the quality was much
better,
the greater part of what is brought to market could not, I
apprehend,
in the present circumstances of the country, be disposed of at a
much
better price; and the present price, it is probable, would not pay the
expense
of the land and labour necessary for producing a much better
quality.
Through the greater part of England, notwithstanding the
superiority
of price, the dairy is not reckoned a more profitable employment
of land
than the raising of corn, or the fattening of cattle, the two great
objects
of agriculture. Through the greater part of Scotland, therefore, it
cannot
yet be even so profitable.
The
lands of no country, it is evident, can ever be completely cultivated
and
improved, till once the price of every produce, which human industry is
obliged
to raise upon them, has got so high as to pay for the expense of
complete
improvement and cultivation. In order to do this, the price of each
particular
produce must be sufficient, first, to pay the rent of good corn
land,
as it is that which regulates the rent of the greater part of other
cultivated
land; and, secondly, to pay the labour and expense of the farmer,
as well
as they are commonly paid upon good corn land ; or, in other words,
to
replace with the ordinary profits the stock which he employs about it.
This
rise in the price of each particular produce; must evidently be
previous
to the improvement and cultivation of the land which is destined
for
raising it. Gain is the end of all improvement; and nothing could
deserve
that name, of which loss was to be the necessary consequence. But
loss
must be the necessary consequence of improving land for the sake of a
produce
of which the price could never bring back the expense. If the
complete
improvement and cultivation of the country be, as it most certainly
is, the
greatest of all public advantages, this rise in the price of all
those
different sorts of rude produce, instead of being considered as a
public
calamity, ought to be regarded as the necessary forerunner and
attendant
of the greatest of all public advantages.
This
rise, too, in the nominal or money price of all those different sorts
of rude
produce, has been the effect, not of any degradation in the value of
silver,
but of a rise in their real price. They have become worth, not only
a
greater quantity of silver, but a greater quantity of labour and
subsistence
than before. As it costs a greater quantity of labour and
subsistence
to bring them to market, so, when they are brought thither they
represent,
or are equivalent to a greater quantity.
Third
Sort. ˜ The third and last sort of rude produce, of which the price
naturally
rises in the progress of improvement, is that in which the
efficacy
of human industry, in augmenting the quantity, is either limited or
uncertain.
Though the real price of this sort of rude produce, therefore,
naturally
tends to rise in the progress of improvement, yet, according as
different
accidents happen to render the efforts of human industry more or
less
successful in augmenting the quantity, it may happen sometimes even to
fall,
sometimes to continue the same, in very different periods of
improvement,
and sometimes to rise more or less in the same period.
There
are some sorts of rude produce which nature has rendered a kind of
appendages
to other sorts; so that the quantity of the one which any country
can
afford, is necessarily limited by that of the other. The quantity of
wool or
of raw hides, for example, which any country can afford, is
necessarily
limited by the number of great and small cattle that are kept in
it. The
state of its improvement, and the nature of its agriculture, again
necessarily
determine this number.
The
same causes which, in the progress of improvement, gradually raise the
price
of butcher's meat, should have the same effect, it may be thought,
upon
the prices of wool and raw hides, and raise them, too, nearly in the
same
proportion. It probably would be so, if, in the rude beginnings of
improvement,
the market for the latter commodities was confined within as
narrow
bounds as that for the former. But the extent of their respective
markets
is commonly extremely different.
The
market for butcher's meat is almost everywhere confined to the country
which
produces it. Ireland, and some part of British America, indeed, carry
on a
considerable trade in salt provisions; but they are, I believe, the
only
countries in the commercial world which do so, or which export to other
countries
any considerable part of their butcher's meat.
The
market for wool and raw hides, on the contrary, is, in the rude
beginnings
of improvement, very seldom confined to the country which
produces
them. They can easily be transported to distant countries ; wool
without
any preparation, and raw hides with very little ; and as they are
the
materials of many manufactures, the industry of other countries may
occasion
a demand for them, though that of the country which produces them
might
not occasion any.
In
countries ill cultivated, and therefore but thinly inhabited, the price
of the
wool and the hide bears always a much greater proportion to that of
the
whole beast, than in countries where, improvement and population being
further
advanced, there is more demand for butcher's meat. Mr Hume observes,
that in
the Saxon times, the fleece was estimated at two-fifths of the value
of the
whole sheep and that this was much above the proportion of its
present
estimation. In some provinces of Spain, I have been assured, the
sheep is
frequently killed merely for the sake of the fleece and the tallow.
The
carcase is often left to rot upon the ground, or to be devoured by
beasts
and birds of prey. If this sometimes happens even in Spain, it
happens
almost constantly in Chili, at Buenos Ayres, and in many other parts
of
Spanish America, where the horned cattle are almost constantly killed
merely
for the sake of the hide and the tallow. This, too, used to happen
almost
constantly in Hispaniola, while it was infested by the buccaneers,
and
before the settlement, improvement, and populousness of the French
plantations
( which now extend round the coast of almost the whole western
half of
the island) had given some value to the cattle of the Spaniards, who
still
continue to possess, not only the eastern part of the coast, but the
whole
inland mountainous part of the country.
Though, in the progress of improvement and
population, the price of the
whole
beast necessarily rises, yet the price of the carcase is likely to be
much more
affected by this rise than that of the wool and the hide. The
market
for the carcase being in the rude state of society confined always to
the
country which produces it, must necessarily be extended in proportion to
the
improvement and population of that country. But the market for the wool
and the
hides, even of a barbarous country, often extending to the whole
commercial
world, it can very seldom be enlarged in the same proportion. The
state
of the whole commercial world can seldom be much affected by the
improvement
of any particular country; and the market for such commodities
may
remain the same, or very nearly the same, after such improvements, as
before.
It should, however, in the natural course of things, rather, upon
the
whole, be somewhat extended in consequence of them. If the manufactures,
especially,
of which those commodities are the materials, should ever come
to
flourish in the country, the market, though it might not be much
enlarged,
would at least be brought much nearer to the place of growth than
before
; and the price of those materials might at least be increased by
what
had usually been the expense of transporting them to distant countries.
Though
it might not rise, therefore, in the same proportion as that of
butcher's
meat, it ought naturally to rise somewhat, and it ought certainly
not to
fall.
In
England, however, notwithstanding the flourishing state of its woollen
manufacture,
the price of English wool has fallen very considerably since
the
time of Edward III. There are many authentic records which demonstrate
that,
during the reign of that prince (towards the middle of the fourteenth
century,
or about 1339), what was reckoned the moderate and reasonable price
of the
tod, or twenty-eight pounds of English wool, was not less than ten
shillings
of the money of those times {See Smith 's Memoirs of Wool, vol. i
c. 5,
6, 7. also vol. ii.}, containing, at the rate of twenty-pence the
ounce,
six ounces of silver, Tower weight, equal to about thirty shillings
of our
present money. In the present times, one-and-twenty shillings the tod
may be
reckoned a good price for very good English wool. The money price of
wool,
therefore, in the time of Edward III. was to its money price in the
present
times as ten to seven. The superiority of its real price was still
greater.
At the rate of six shillings and eightpence the quarter, ten
shillings
was in those ancient times the price of twelve bushels of wheat.
At the
rate of twenty-eight shillings the quarter, one-and-twenty shillings
is in
the present times the price of six bushels only. The proportion
between
the real price of ancient and modern times, therefore, is as twelve
to six,
or as two to one. In those ancient times, a tod of wool would have
purchased
twice the quantity of subsistence which it will purchase at
present,
and consequently twice the quantity of labour, if the real
recompence
of labour had been the same in both periods.
This
degradation, both in the real and nominal value of wool, could never
have
happened in consequence of the natural course of things. It has
accordingly
been the effect of violence and artifice. First, of the absolute
prohibition
of exporting wool from England: secondly, of the permission of
importing
it from Spain, duty free: thirdly, of the prohibition of exporting
it from
Ireland to another country but England. In consequence of these
regulations,
the market for English wool, instead of being somewhat
extended,
in consequence of the improvement of England, has been confined to
the
home market, where the wool of several other countries is allowed to
come
into competition with it, and where that of Ireland is forced into
competition
with it. As the woollen manufactures, too, of Ireland, are fully
as much
discouraged as is consistent with justice and fair dealing, the
Irish
can work up but a smaller part of their own wool at home, and are
therefore
obliged to send a greater proportion of it to Great Britain, the
only
market they are allowed.
I have
not been able to find any such authentic records concerning the price
of raw
hides in ancient times. Wool was commonly paid as a subsidy to the
king,
and its valuation in that subsidy ascertains, at least in some degree,
what
was its ordinary price. But this seems not to have been the case with
raw
hides. Fleetwood, however, from an account in 1425, between the prior of
Burcester
Oxford and one of his canons, gives us their price, at least as it
was
stated upon that particular occasion, viz. five ox hides at twelve
shillings
; five cow hides at seven shillings and threepence ; thirtysix
sheep
skins of two years old at nine shillings; sixteen calf skins at two
shillings.
In 1425, twelve shillings contained about the same quantity of
silver
as four-and-twenty shillings of our present money. An ox hide,
therefore,
was in this account valued at the same quantity of silver as 4s.
4/5ths
of our present money. Its nominal price was a good deal lower than at
present.
But at the rate of six shillings and eightpence the quarter, twelve
shillings
would in those times have purchased fourteen bushels and
four-fifths
of a bushel of wheat, which, at three and sixpence the bushel,
would
in the present times cost 51s. 4d. An ox hide, therefore, would in
those
times have purchased as much corn as ten shillings and threepence
would
purchase at present. Its real value was equal to ten shillings and
threepence
of our present money. In those ancient times, when the cattle
were
half starved during the greater part of the winter, we cannot suppose
that
they were of a very large size. An ox hide which weighs four stone of
sixteen
pounds of avoirdupois, is not in the present times reckoned a bad
one;
and in those ancient times would probably have been reckoned a very
good one.
But at half-a-crown the stone, which at this moment (February
1773) I
understand to be the common price, such a hide would at present cost
only
ten shillings.Through its nominal price, therefore, is higher in the
present
than it was in those ancient times, its real price, the real
quantity
of subsistence which it will purchase or command, is rather
somewhat
lower. The price of cow hides, as stated in the above account, is
nearly
in the common proportion to that of ox hides. That of sheep skins is
a good
deal above it. They had probably been sold with the wool. That of
calves
skins, on the contrary, is greatly below it. In countries where the
price
of cattle is very low, the calves, which are not intended to be reared
in
order to keep up the stock, are generally killed very young, as was the
case in
Scotland twenty or thirty years ago. It saves the milk, which their
price
would not pay for. Their skins, therefore, are commonly good for
little.
The
price of raw hides is a good deal lower at present than it was a few
years
ago; owing probably to the taking off the duty upon seal skins, and to
the
allowing, for a limited time, the importation of raw hides from Ireland,
and
from the plantations, duty free, which was done in 1769. Take the whole
of the
present century at an average, their real price has probably been
somewhat
higher than it was in those ancient times. The nature of the
commodity
renders it not quite so proper for being transported to distant
markets
as wool. It suffers more by keeping. A salted hide is reckoned
inferior
to a fresh one, and sells for a lower price. This circumstance must
necessarily
have some tendency to sink the price of raw hides produced in a
country
which does not manufacture them, but is obliged to export them, and
comparatively
to raise that of those produced in a country which does
manufacture
them. It must have some tendency to sink their price in a
barbarous,
and to raise it in an improved and manufacturing country. It must
have
had some tendency, therefore, to sink it in ancient, and to raise it in
modern
times. Our tanners, besides, have not been quite so successful as our
clothiers,
in convincing the wisdom of the nation, that the safety of the
commonwealth
depends upon the prosperity of their particular manufacture.
They
have accordingly been much less favoured. The exportation of raw hides
has,
indeed, been prohibited, and declared a nuisance; but their importation
from
foreign countries has been subjected to a duty ; and though this duty
has
been taken off from those of Ireland and the plantations (for the
limited
time of five years only), yet Ireland has not been confined to the
market
of Great Britain for the sale of its surplus hides, or of those which
are not
manufactured at home. The hides of common cattle have, but within
these
few years, been put among the enumerated commodities which the
plantations
can send nowhere but to the mother country ; neither has the
commerce
of Ireland been in this case oppressed hitherto, in order to
support
the manufactures of Great Britain.
Whatever
regulations tend to sink the price, either of wool or of raw hides,
below
what it naturally would he, must, in an improved and cultivated
country,
have some tendency to raise the price of butcher's meat. The price
both of
the great and small cattle, which are fed on improved and cultivated
land,
must be sufficient to pay the rent which the landlord, and the profit
which
the farmer, has reason to expect from improved and cultivated land. If
it is
not, they will soon cease to feed them. Whatever part of this price,
therefore,
is not paid by the wool and the hide, must be paid by the
carcase.
The less there is paid for the one, the more must be paid for the
other.
In what manner this price is to be divided upon the different parts
of the
beast, is indifferent to the landlords and farmers, provided it is
all
paid to them. In an improved and cultivated country, therefore, their
interest
as landlords and farmers cannot be much affected by such
regulations,
though their interest as consumers may, by the rise in the
price
of provisions. It would be quite otherwise, however, in an unimproved
and
uncultivated country, where the greater part of the lands could be
applied
to no other purpose but the feeding of cattle, and where the wool
and the
hide made the principal part of the value of those cattle. Their
interest
as landlords and farmers would in this case be very deeply affected
by such
regulations, and their interest as consumers very little. The fall
in the
price of the wool and the hide would not in this case raise the price
of the
carcase; because the greater part of the lands of the country being
applicable
to no other purpose but the feeding of cattle, the same number
would
still continue to be fed. The same quantity of butcher's meat would
still
come to market. The demand for it would be no greater than before. Its
price,
therefore, would be the same as before. The whole price of cattle
would
fall, and along with it both the rent and the prot of all those
lands
of which cattle was the principal produce, that is, of the greater
part of
the lands of the country. The perpetual prohibition of the
exportation
of wool, which is commonly, but very falsely, ascribed to Edward
III.,
would, in the then circumstances of the country, have been the most
destructive
regulation which could well have been thought of. It would not
only
have reduced the actual value of the greater part of the lands in the
kingdom,
but by reducing the price of the most important species of small
cattle,
it would have retarded very much its subsequent improvement.
The
wool of Scotland fell very considerably in its price in consequence of
the
union with England, by which it was excluded from the great market of
Europe,
and confined to the narrow one of Great Britain. The value of the
greater
part of the lands in the southern counties of Scotland, which are
chiefly
a sheep country, would have been very deeply affected by this event,
had not
the rise in the price of butcher's meat fully compensated the fall
in the
price of wool.
As the
efficacy of human industry, in increasing the quantity either of wool
or of
raw hides, is limited, so far as it depends upon the produce of the
country
where it is exerted ; so it is uncertain so far as it depends upon
the
produce of other countries. It so far depends not so much upon the
quantity
which they produce, as upon that which they do not manufacture; and
upon
the restraints which they may or may not think proper to impose upon
the
exportation of this sort of rude produce. These circumstances, as they
are
altogether independent of domestic industry, so they necessarily render
the
efficacy of its efforts more or less uncertain. In multiplying this sort
of rude
produce, therefore, the efficacy of human industry is not only
limited,
but uncertain.
In
multiplying another very important sort of rude produce, the quantity of
fish
that is brought to market, it is likewise both limited and uncertain.
It is
limited by the local situation of the country, by the proximity or
distance
of its different provinces from the sea, by the number of its lakes
and
rivers, and by what may be called the fertility or barrenness of those
seas,
lakes, and rivers, as to this sort of rude produce. As population
increases,
as the annual produce of the land and labour of the country grows
greater
and greater, there come to be more buyers of fish ; and those
buyers,
too, have a greater quantity and variety of other goods, or, what is
the
same thing, the price of a greater quantity and variety of other goods,
to buy
with. But it will generally be impossible to supply the great and
extended
market, without employing a quantity of labour greater than in
proportion
to what had been requisite for supplying the narrow and confined
one. A
market which, from requiring only one thousand, comes to require
annually
ten thousand ton of fish, can seldom be supplied, without employing
more
than ten times the quantity of labour which had before been sufficient
to
supply it. The fish must generally be sought for at a greater distance,
larger
vessels must be employed, and more expensive machinery of every kind
made
use of. The real price of this commodity, therefore, naturally rises in
the
progress of improvement. It has accordingly done so, I believe, more or
less in
every country.
Though
the success of a particular day's fishing maybe a very uncertain
matter,
yet the local situation of the country being supposed, the general
efficacy
of industry in bringing a certain quantity of fish to market,
taking
the course of a year, or of several years together, it may, perhaps,
be
thought is certain enough; and it, no doubt, is so. As it depends more,
however,
upon the local situation of the country, than upon the state of its
wealth
and industry ; as upon this account it may in different countries be
the
same in very different periods of improvement, and very different in the
same
period; its connection with the state of improvement is uncertain; and
it is
of this sort of uncertainty that I am here speaking.
In
increasing the quantity of the different minerals and metals which are
drawn
from the bowels of the earth, that of the more precious ones
particularly,
the efficacy of human industry seems not to be limited, but to
be
altogether uncertain.
The
quantity of the precious metals which is to be found in any country, is
not
limited by any thing in its local situation, such as the fertility or
barrenness
of its own mines. Those metals frequently abound in countries
which
possess no mines. Their quantity, in every particular country, seems
to
depend upon two different circumstances ; first, upon its power of
purchasing,
upon the state of its industry, upon the annual produce of its
land
and labour, in consequence of which it can afford to employ a greater
or a
smaller quantity of labour and subsistence, in bringing or purchasing
such
superfluities as gold and silver, either from its own mines, or from
those
of other countries; and, secondly, upon the fertility or barrenness of
the
mines which may happen at any particular time to supply the commercial
world
with those metals. The quantity of those metals in the countries most
remote
from the mines, must be more or less affected by this fertility or
barrenness,
on account of the easy and cheap transportation of those metals,
of
their small bulk and great value. Their quantity in China and Indostan
must
have been more or less affected by the abundance of the mines of
America.
So far
as their quantity in any particular country depends upon the former
of
those two circumstances (the power of purchasing), their real price, like
that of
all other luxuries and superfluities, is likely to rise with the
wealth
and improvement of the country, and to fall with its poverty and
depression.
Countries which have a great quantity of labour and subsistence
to
spare, can afford to purchase any particular quantity of those metals at
the
expense of a greater quantity of labour and subsistence, than countries
which
have less to spare.
So far
as their quantity in any particular country depends upon the latter
of
those two circumstances (the fertility or barrenness of the mines which
happen
to supply the commercial world), their real price, the real quantity
of
labour and subsistence which they will purchase or exchange for, will, no
doubt,
sink more or less in proportion to the fertility, and rise in
proportion
to the barrenness of those mines.
The
fertility or barrenness of the mines, however, which may happen at any
particular
time to supply the commercial world, is a circumstance which, it
is
evident, may have no sort of connection with the state of industry in a
particular
country. It seems even to have no very necessary connection with
that of
the world in general. As arts and commerce, indeed, gradually spread
themselves
over a greater and a greater part of the earth, the search for
new
mines, being extended over a wider surface, may have somewhat a better
chance
for being successful than when confined within narrower bounds. The
discovery
of new mines, however, as the old ones come to be gradually
exhausted,
is a matter of the greatest uncertainty, and such as no human
skill
or industry can insure. All indications, it is acknowledged, are
doubtful;
and the actual discovery and successful working of a new mine can
alone
ascertain the reality of its value, or even of its existence. In this
search
there seem to be no certain limits, either to the possible success,
or to
the possible disappointment of human industry. In the course of a
century
or two, it is possible that new mines may be discovered, more
fertile
than any that have ever yet been known ; and it is just equally
possible,
that the most fertile mine then known may be more barren than any
that
was wrought before the discovery of the mines of America. Whether the
one or
the other of those two events may happen to take place, is of very
little
importance to the real wealth and prosperity of the world, to the
real
value of the annual produce of the land and labour of mankind. Its
nominal
value, the quantity of gold and silver by which this annual produce
could
be expressed or represented, would, no doubt, be very different ; but
its
real value, the real quantity of labour which it could purchase or
command,
would be precisely the same. A shilling might, in the one case,
represent
no more labour than a penny does at present ; and a penny, in the
other,
might represent as much as a shilling does now. But in the one case,
he who
had a shilling in his pocket would be no richer than he who has a
penny
at present; and in the other, he who had a penny would be just as rich
as he
who has a shilling now. The cheapness and abundance of gold and silver
plate
would be the sole advantage which the world could derive from the one
event;
and the dearness and scarcity of those trifling superfluities, the
only
inconveniency it could suffer from the other.
Conclusion
of the Digression concerning the Variations in the Value of
Silver.
The
greater part of the writers who have collected the money price of things
in
ancient times, seem to have considered the low money price of corn, and
of
goods in general, or, in other words, the high value of gold and silver,
as a
proof, not only of the scarcity of those metals, but of the poverty and
barbarism
of the country at the time when it took place. This notion is
connected
with the system of political economy, which represents national
wealth
as consisting in the abundance and national poverty in the scarcity,
of gold
and silver ; a system which I shall endeavour to explain and examine
at
great length in the fourth book of this Inquiry. I shall only observe at
present,
that the high value of the precious metals can be no proof of the
poverty
or barbarism of any particular country at the time when it took
place.
It is a proof only of the barrenness of the mines which happened at
that
time to supply the commercial world. A poor country, as it cannot
afford
to buy more, so it can as little afford to pay dearer for gold and
silver
than a rich one ; and the value of those metals, therefore, is not
likely
to be higher in the former than in the latter. In China, a country
much
richer than any part of Europe, the value of the precious metals is
much
higher than in any part of Europe. As the wealth of Europe, indeed, has
increased
greatly since the discovery of the mines of America, so the value
of gold
and silver has gradually diminished. This diminution of their
value,
however, has not been owing to the increase of the real wealth of
Europe,
of the annual produce of its land and labour, but to the accidental
discovery
of more abundant mines than any that were known before. The
increase
of the quantity of gold and silver in Europe, and the increase of
its
manufactures and agriculture, are two events which, though they have
happened
nearly about the same time, yet have arisen from very different
causes,
and have scarce any natural connection with one another. The one has
arisen
from a mere accident, in which neither prudence nor policy either had
or
could have any share; the other, from the fall of the feudal system, and
from
the establishment of a government which afforded to industry the only
encouragement
which it requires, some tolerable security that it shall enjoy
the
fruits of its own labour. Poland, where the feudal system still
continues
to take place, is at this day as beggarly a country as it was
before
the discovery of America. The money price of corn, however, has risen
; the
real value of the precious metals has fallen in Poland, in the same
manner
as in other parts of Europe. Their quantity, therefore, must have
increased
there as in other places, and nearly in the same proportion to the
annual
produce of its land and labour. This increase of the quantity of
those
metals, however, has not, it seems, increased that annual produce, has
neither
improved the manufactures and agriculture of the country, nor mended
the
circumstances of its inhabitants. Spain and Portugal, the countries
which
possess the mines, are, after Poland, perhaps the two most beggarly
countries
in Europe. The value of the precious metals, however, must be
lower
in Spain and Portugal than in any other part of Europe, as they come
from
those countries to all other parts of Europe, loaded, not only with a
freight
and an insurance, but with the expense of smuggling, their
exportation
being either prohibited or subjected to a duty. In proportion to
the
annual produce of the land and labour, therefore, their quantity must be
greater
in those countries than in any other part of Europe; those
countries,
however, are poorer than the greater part of Europe. Though the
feudal
system has been abolished in Spain and Portugal, it has not been
succeeded
by a much better.
As the
low value of gold and silver, therefore, is no proof of the wealth
and
flourishing state of the country where it takes place ; so neither is
their
high value, or the low money price either of goods in general, or of
corn in
particular, any proof of its poverty and barbarism.
But
though the low money price, either of goods in general, or of corn in
particular,
be no proof of the poverty or barbarism of the times, the low
money price
of some particular sorts of goods, such as cattle, poultry, game
of all
kinds, etc. in proportion to that of corn, is a most decisive one. It
clearly
demonstrates, first, their great abundance in proportion to that of
corn,
and, consequently, the great extent of the land which they occupied in
proportion
to what was occupied by corn ; and, secondly, the low value of
this
land in proportion to that of corn land, and, consequently, the
uncultivated
and unimproved state of the far greater part of the lands of
the
country. It clearly demonstrates, that the stock and population of the
country
did not bear the same proportion to the extent of its territory,
which
they commonly do in civilized countries ; and that society was at that
time,
and in that country, but in its infancy. From the high or low money
price,
either of goods in general, or of corn in particular, we can infer
only,
that the mines, which at that time happened to supply the commercial
world
with gold and silver, were fertile or barren, not that the country was
rich or
poor. But from the high or low money price of some sorts of goods in
proportion
to that of others, we can infer, with a degree of probability
that
approaches almost to certainty, that it was rich or poor, that the
greater
part of its lands were improved or unimproved, and that it was
either
in a more or less barbarous state, or in a more or less civilized
one.
Any
rise in the money price of goods which proceeded altogether from the
degradation
of the value of silver, would affect all sorts of goods equally,
and
raise their price universally, a third, or a fourth, or a fifth part
higher,
according as silver happened to lose a third, or a fourth, or a
fifth
part of its former value. But the rise in the price of provisions,
which
has been the subject of so much reasoning and conversation, does not
affect
all sorts of provisions equally. Taking the course of the present
century
at an average, the price of corn, it is acknowledged, even by those
who
account for this rise by the degradation of the value of silver, has
risen
much less than that of some other sorts of provisions. The rise in the
price
of those other sorts of provisions, therefore, cannot be owing
altogether
to the degradation of the value of silver. Some other causes must
be
taken into the account ; and those which have been above assigned, will,
perhaps,
without having recourse to the supposed degradation of the value of
silver,
sufficiently explain this rise in those particular sorts of
provisions,
of which the price has actually risen in proportion to that of
corn.
As to
the price of corn itself, it has, during the sixty-four first years of
the
present century, and before the late extraordinary course of bad
seasons,
been somewhat lower than it was during the sixty-four last years of
the
preceding century. This fact is attested, not only by the accounts of
Windsor
market, but by the public fiars of all the different counties of
Scotland,
and by the accounts of several different markets in France, which
have
been collected with great diligence and fidelity by Mr Messance, and by
Mr
Dupré de St Maur. The evidence is more complete than could well have been
expected
in a matter which is naturally so very difficult to be ascertained.
As to
the high price of corn during these last ten or twelve years, it can
be
sufficiently accounted for from the badness of the seasons, without
supposing
any degradation in the value of silver.
The
opinion, therefore, that silver is continually sinking in its value,
seems
not to be founded upon any good observations, either upon the prices
of
corn, or upon those of other provisions.
The
same quantity of silver, it may perhaps be said, will, in the present
times,
even according to the account which has been here given, purchase a
much
smaller quantity of several sorts of provisions than it would have done
during
some part of the last century ; and to ascertain whether this change
be
owing to a rise in the value of those goods, or to a fall in the value of
silver,
is only to establish a vain and useless distinction, which can be of
no sort
of service to the man who has only a certain quantity of silver to
go to
market with, or a certain fixed revenue in money. I certainly do not
pretend
that the knowledge of this distinction will enable him to buy
cheaper.
It may not, however, upon that account be altogether useless.
It may
be of some use to the public, by affording an easy proof of the
prosperous
condition of the country. If the rise in the price of some sorts
of
provisions be owing altogether to a fall in the value of silver, it is
owing
to a circumstance, from which nothing can be inferred but the
fertility
of the American mines. The real wealth of the country, the annual
produce
of its land and labour, may, notwithstanding this circumstance, be
either
gradually declining, as in Portugal and Poland ; or gradually
advancing,
as in most other parts of Europe. But if this rise in the price
of some
sorts of provisions be owing to a rise in the real value of the land
which
produces them, to its increased fertility, or, in consequence of more
extended
improvement and good cultivation, to its having been rendered fit
for
producing corn; it is owing to a circumstance which indicates, in the
clearest
manner, the prosperous and advancing state of the country. The land
constitutes
by far the greatest, the most important, and the most durable
part of
the wealth of every extensive country. It may surely be of some use,
or, at
least, it may give some satisfaction to the public, to have so
decisive
a proof of the increasing value of by far the greatest, the most
important,
and the most durable part of its wealth.
It may, too, be of some use to the public, in
regulating the pecuniary
reward
of some of its inferior servants. If this rise in the price of some
sorts
of provisions be owing to a fall in the value of silver, their
pecuniary
reward, provided it was not too large before, ought certainly to
be
augmented in proportion to the extent of this fall. If it is not
augmented,
their real recompence will evidently be so much diminished. But
if this
rise of price is owing to the increased value, in consequence of the
improved
fertility of the land which produces such provisions, it becomes a
much
nicer matter to judge, either in what proportion any pecuniary reward
ought
to be augmented, or whether it ought to be augmented at all. The
extension
of improvement and cultivation, as it necessarily raises more or
less,
in proportion to the price of corn, that of every sort of animal food,
so it
as necessarily lowers that of, I believe, every sort of vegetable
food.
It raises the price of animal food ; because a great part of the land
which
produces it, being rendered fit for producing corn, must afford to the
landlord
anti farmer the rent and profit of corn land. It lowers the price
of
vegetable food; because, by increasing the fertility of the land, it
increases
its abundance. The improvements of agriculture, too, introduce
many
sorts of vegetable food, which requiring less land, and not more labour
than
corn, come much cheaper to market. Such are potatoes and maize, or what
is
called Indian corn, the two most important improvements which the
agriculture
of Europe, perhaps, which Europe itself, has received from the
great
extension of its commerce and navigation. Many sorts of vegetable
food,
besides, which in the rude state of agriculture are confined to the
kitchen-garden,
and raised only by the spade, come, in its improved state,
to be
introduced into common fields, and to be raised by the plough ; such
as
turnips, carrots, cabbages, etc. If, in the progress of improvement,
therefore,
the real price of one species of food necessarily rises, that of
another
as necessarily falls ; and it becomes a matter of more nicety to
judge
how far the rise in the one may be compensated by the fall in the
other.
When the real price of butcher's meat has once got to its height
(which,
with regard to every sort, except perhaps that of hogs flesh, it
seems
to have done through a great part of England more than a century ago),
any
rise which can afterwards happen in that of any other sort of animal
food,
cannot much affect the circumstances of the inferior ranks of people.
The circumstances
of the poor, through a great part of England, cannot
surely
be so much distressed by any rise in the price of poultry, fish,
wild-fowl,
or venison, as they must be relieved by the fall in that of
potatoes.
In the
present season of scarcity, the high price of corn no doubt
distresses
the poor. But in times of moderate plenty, when corn is at its
ordinary
or average price, the natural rise in the price of any other sort
of rude
produce cannot much affect them. They suffer more, perhaps, by the
artificial
rise which has been occasioned by taxes in the price of some
manufactured
commodities, as of salt, soap, leather, candles, malt, beer,
ale,
etc.
Effects
of the Progress of Improvement upon the real Price of Manufactures.
It is
the natural effect of improvement, however, to diminish gradually the
real
price of almost all manufactures. That of the manufacturing workmanship
diminishes,
perhaps, in all of them without exception. In consequence of
better
machinery, of greater dexterity, and of a more proper division and
distribution
of work, all of which are the natural effects of improvement, a
much
smaller quantity of labour becomes requisite for executing any
particular
piece of work ; and though, in consequence of the flourishing
circumstances
of the society, the real price of labour should rise very
considerably,
yet the great diminution of the quantity will generally much
more
than compensate the greatest rise which can happen in the price.
There
are, indeed, a few manufactures, in which the necessary rise in the
real
price of the rude materials will more than compensate all the
advantages
which improvement can introduce into the execution of the work In
carpenters'
and joiners' work, and in the coarser sort of cabinet work, the
necessary
rise in the real price of barren timber, in consequence of the
improvement
of land, will more than compensate all the advantages which can
be
derived from the best machinery, the greatest dexterity, and the most
proper
division and distribution of work.
But in
all cases in which the real price of the rude material either does
not
rise at all, or does not rise very much, that of the manufactured
commodity
sinks very considerably.
This
diminution of price has, in the course of the present and preceding
century,
been most remarkable in those manufactures of which the materials
are the
coarser metals. A better movement of a watch, than about the middle
of the
last century could have been bought for twenty pounds, may now
perhaps
be had for twenty shillings. In the work of cutlers and locksmiths,
in all
the toys which are made of the coarser metals, and in all those goods
which
are commonly known by the name of Birmingham and Sheffield ware, there
has
been, during the same period, a very great reduction of price, though
not
altogether so great as in watch-work. It has, however, been sufficient
to
astonish the workmen of every other part of Europe, who in many cases
acknowledge
that they can produce no work of equal goodness for double
or even
for triple the price. There are perhaps no manufactures, in which
the
division of labour can be carried further, or in which the machinery
employed
admits of' a greater variety of improvements, than those of which
the
materials are the coarser metals.
In the
clothing manufacture there has, during the same period, been no such
sensible
reduction of price. The price of superfine cloth, I have been
assured,
on the contrary, has, within these five-and-twenty or thirty years,
risen
somewhat in proportion to its quality, owing, it was said, to a
considerable
rise in the price of the material, which consists altogether of
Spanish
wool. That of the Yorkshire cloth, which is made altogether of
English
wool, is said, indeed, during the course of the present century, to
have
fallen a good deal in proportion to its quality. Quality, however, is
so very
disputable a matter, that I look upon all information of this kind
as
somewhat uncertain. In the clothing manufacture, the division of labour
is
nearly the same now as it was a century ago, and the machinery employed
is not
very different. There may, however, have been some small improvements
in
both, which may have occasioned some reduction of price.
But the
reduction will appear much more sensible and undeniable, if we
compare
the price of this manufacture in the present times with what it was
in a
much remoter period, towards the end of the fifteenth century, when the
labour
was probably much less subdivided, and the machinery employed much
more
imperfect, than it is at present.
In
1487, being the 4th of Henry VII., it was enacted, that " whosoever shall
sell by
retail a broad yard of the finest scarlet grained, or of other
grained
cloth of the finest making, above sixteen shillings, shall forfeit
forty
shillings for every yard so sold." Sixteen shillings, therefore,
containing
about the same quantity of silver as four-and-twenty shillings of
our
present money, was, at that time, reckoned not an unreasonable price for
a yard
of the finest cloth; and as this is a sumptuary law, such cloth, it
is
probable, had usually been sold somewhat dearer. A guinea may be reckoned
the
highest price in the present times. Even though the quality of the
cloths,
therefore, should be supposed equal, and that of the present times
is most
probably much superior, yet, even upon this supposition, the money
price
of the finest cloth appears to have been considerably reduced since
the end
of the fifteenth century. But its real price has been much more
reduced.
Six shillings and eightpence was then, and long afterwards,
reckoned
the average price of a quarter of wheat. Sixteen shillings,
therefore,
was the price of two quarters and more than three bushels of
wheat.
Valuing a quarter of wheat in the present times at eight-and-twenty
shillings,
the real price of a yard of fine cloth must, in those times, have
been
equal to at least three pounds six shillings and sixpence of our
present
money. The man who bought it must have parted with the command of a
quantity
of labour and subsistence equal to what that sum would purchase in
the
present times.
The
reduction in the real price of the coarse manufacture, though
considerable,
has not been so great as in that of the fine.
In
1463, being the 3rd of Edward IV. it was enacted, that "no servant in
husbandry
nor common labourer, nor servant to any artificer inhabiting out
of a
city or burgh, shall use or wear in their clothing any cloth above two
shillings
the broad yard." In the 3rd of Edward IV., two shillings contained
very
nearly the same quantity of silver as four of our present money. But
the
Yorkshire cloth which is now sold at four shillings the yard, is
probably
much superior to any that was then made for the wearing of the very
poorest
order of common servants. Even the money price of their clothing,
therefore,
may, in proportion to the quality, be somewhat cheaper in the
present
than it was in those ancient times. The real price is certainly a
good
deal cheaper. Tenpence was then reckoned what is called the moderate
and
reasonable price of a bushel of wheat. Two shillings, therefore, was the
price
of two bushels and near two pecks of wheat, which in the present
times,
at three shillings and sixpence the bushel, would be worth eight
shillings
and ninepence. For a yard of this cloth the poor servant must have
parted
with the power of purchasing a quantity of subsistence equal to what
eight
shillings and ninepence would purchase in the present times. This is a
sumptuary
law, too, restraining the luxury and extravagance of the poor.
Their
clothing, therefore, had commonly been much more expensive.
The
same order of people are, by the same law, prohibited from wearing hose,
of
which the price should exceed fourteen-pence the pair, equal to about
eight-and-twenty
pence of our present money. But fourteen-pence was in those
times
the price of a bushel and near two pecks of wheat; which in the
present
times, at three and sixpence the bushel, would cost five shillings
and
threepence. We should in the present times consider this as a very high
price
for a pair of stockings to a servant of the poorest and lowest order.
He must
however, in those times, have paid what was really equivalent to
this
price for them.
In the
time of Edward IV. the art of knitting stockings was probably not
known
in any part of Europe. Their hose were made of common cloth, which may
have
been one of the causes of their dearness. The first person that wore
stockings
in England is said to have been Queen Elizabeth. She received them
as a
present from the Spanish ambassador.
Both in the coarse and in the fine woollen
manufacture, the machinery
employed
was much more imperfect in those ancient, than it is in the present
times.
It has since received three very capital improvements, besides,
probably,
many smaller ones, of which it may be difficult to ascertain
either
the number or the importance. The three capital improvements are,
first,
the exchange of the rock and spindle for the spinning-wheel, which,
with
the same quantity of labour, will perform more than double the quantity
of
work. Secondly, the use of several very ingenious machines, which
facilitate
and abridge, in a still greater proportion, the winding of the
worsted
and woollen yarn, or the proper arrangement of the warp and woof
before
they are put into the loom ; an operation which, previous to the
invention
of those machines, must have been extremely tedious and
troublesome.Thirdly,
the employment of the fulling-mill for thickening the
cloth,
instead of treading it in water. Neither wind nor water mills of any
kind
were known in England so early as the beginning of the sixteenth
century,
nor, so far as I know, in any other part of Europe north of the
Alps.
They had been introduced into Italy some time before.
The
consideration of these circumstances may, perhaps, in some measure,
explain
to us why the real price both of the coarse and of the fine
manufacture
was so much higher in those ancient than it is in the present
times.
It cost a greater quantity of labour to bring the goods to market.
When
they were brought thither, therefore, they must have purchased, or
exchanged
for the price of, a greater quantity.
The
coarse manufacture probably was, in those ancient times, carried on in
England
in the same manner as it always has been in countries where arts and
manufactures
are in their infancy. It was probably a household manufacture,
in
which every different part of the work was occasionally performed by all
the
different members of almost every private family, but so as to be their
work
only when they had nothing else to do, and not to be the principal
business
from which any of them derived the greater part of their
subsistence.
The work which is performed in this manner, it has already been
observed,
comes always much cheaper to market than that which is the
principal
or sole fund of the workman's subsistence. The fine manufacture,
on the
other hand, was not, in those times, carried on in England, but in
the
rich and commercial country of Flanders; and it was probably conducted
then,
in the same manner as now, by people who derived the whole, or the
principal
part of their subsistence from it. It was, besides, a foreign
manufacture,
and must have paid some duty, the ancient custom of tonnage and
poundage
at least, to the king. This duty, indeed, would not probably be
very
great. It was not then the policy of Europe to restrain, by high
duties,
the importation of foreign manufactures, but rather to encourage it,
in
order that merchants might be enabled to supply, at as easy a rate as
possible,
the great men with the conveniencies and luxuries which they
wanted,
and which the industry of their own country could not afford them.
The consideration
of these circumstances may, perhaps, in some measure
explain
to us why, in those ancient times, the real price of the coarse
manufacture
was, in proportion to that of the fine, so much lower than in
the
present times.
Conclusion
of the Chapter.
I shall
conclude this very long chapter with observing, that every
improvement
in the circumstances of the society tends, either directly or
indirectly,
to raise the real rent of land to increase the real wealth of
the
landlord, his power of purchasing the labour, or the produce of the
labour
of other people.
The
extension of improvement and cultivation tends to raise it directly. The
landlord's
share of the produce necessarily increases with the increase of
the
produce.
That
rise in the real price of those parts of the rude produce of land,
which
is first the effect of the extended improvement and cultivation, and
afterwards
the cause of their being still further extended, the rise in the
price
of cattle, for example, tends, too, to raise the rent of land
directly,
and in a still greater proportion. The real value of the
landlord's
share, his real command of the labour of other people, not only
rises
with the real value of the produce, but the proportion of his share to
the
whole produce rises with it.
That
produce, after the rise in its real price, requires no more labour to
collect
it than before. A smaller proportion of it will, therefore, be
sufficient
to replace, with the ordinary profit, the stock which employs
that labour.
A greater proportion of it must consequently belong to the
landlord.
All
those improvements in the productive powers of labour, which tend
directly
to reduce the rent price of manufactures, tend indirectly to raise
the
real rent of land. The landlord exchanges that part of his rude produce,
which
is over and above his own consumption, or, what comes to the same
thing,
the price of that part of it, for manufactured produce. Whatever
reduces
the real price of the latter, raises that of the former. An equal
quantity
of the former becomes thereby equivalent to a greater quantity of
the
latter ; and the landlord is enabled to purchase a greater quantity of
the
conveniencies, ornaments, or luxuries which he has occasion for.
Every increase in the real wealth of the
society, every increase in the
quantity
of useful labour employed within it, tends indirectly to raise the
real
rent of land. A certain proportion
of this labour naturally goes to
the
land. A greater number of men and cattle are employed in its
cultivation,
the produce increases with the increase of the stock which is
thus
employed in raising it, and the rent increases with the produce.
The
contrary circumstances, the neglect of cultivation and improvement, the
fall in
the real price of any part of the rude produce of land, the rise in
the
real price of manufactures from the decay of manufacturing art and
industry,
the declension of the real wealth of the society, all tend, on
the
other hand, to lower the real rent of land, to reduce the real wealth of
the
landlord, to diminish his power of purchasing either the labour, or the
produce
of the labour, of other people.
The
whole annual produce of the land and labour of every country, or, what
comes
to the same thing, the whole price of that annual produce, naturally
divides
itself, it has already been observed, into three parts; the rent of
land,
the wages of labour, and the profits of stock ; and constitutes a
revenue
to three different orders of people; to those who live by rent, to
those
who live by wages, and to those who live by profit. These are the
three
great, original, and constituent, orders of every civilized society,
from
whose revenue that of every other order is ultimately derived.
The
interest of the first of those three great orders, it appears from what
has
been just now said, is strictly and inseparably connected with the
general
interest of the society. Whatever either promotes or obstructs the
one,
necessarily promotes or obstructs the other. When the public
deliberates
concerning any regulation of commerce or police, the proprietors
of land
never can mislead it, with a view to promote the interest of their
own
particular order ; at least, if they have any tolerable knowledge of
that interest.
They are, indeed, too often defective in this tolerable
knowledge.
They are the only one of the three orders whose revenue costs
them
neither labour nor care, but comes to them, as it were, of its own
accord,
and independent of any plan or project of their own. That indolence
which
is the natural effect of the ease and security of their situation,
renders
them too often, not only ignorant, but incapable of that application
of
mind, which is necessary in order to foresee and understand the
consequence
of any public regulation.
The
interest of the second order, that of those who live by wages, is as
strictly
connected with the interest of the society as that of the first.
The
wages of the labourer, it has already been shewn, are never so high as
when
the demand for labour is continually rising, or when the quantity
employed
is every year increasing considerably. When this real wealth of the
society
becomes stationary, his wages are soon reduced to what is barely
enough
to enable him to bring up a family, or to continue the race of
labourers.
When the society declines, they fall even below this. The order
of
proprietors may perhaps gain more by the prosperity of the society than
that of
labourers; but there is no order that suffers so cruelly from its
decline.
But though the interest of the labourer is strictly connected with
that of
the society, he is incapable either of comprehending that interest,
or of
understanding its connexion with his own. His condition leaves him no
time to
receive the necessary information, and his education and habits are
commonly
such as to render him unfit to judge, even though he was fully
informed.
In the public deliberations, therefore, his voice is little heard,
and
less regarded; except upon particular occasions, when his clamour is
animated,
set on, and supported by his employers, not for his, but their own
particular
purposes.
His
employers constitute the third order, that of those who live by profit.
It is
the stock that is employed for the sake of profit, which puts into
motion
the greater part of the useful labour of every society. The plans and
projects
of the employers of stock regulate and direct all the most
important
operation of labour, and profit is the end proposed by all those
plans
and projects. But the rate of profit does not, like rent and wages,
rise
with the prosperity, and fall with the declension of the society. On
the
contrary, it is naturally low in rich, and high in poor countries, and
it is
always highest in the countries which are going fastest to ruin. The
interest
of this third order, therefore, has not the same connexion with the
general
interest of the society, as that of the other two. Merchants and
master
manufacturers are, in this order, the two classes of people who
commonly
employ the largest capitals, and who by their wealth draw to
themselves
the greatest share of the public consideration. As during their
whole
lives they are engaged in plans and projects, they have frequently
more
acuteness of understanding than the greater part of country gentlemen.
As
their thoughts, however, are commonly exercised rather about the interest
of
their own particular branch of business. than about that of the society,
their
judgment, even when given with the greatest candour (which it has not
been
upon every occasion), is much more to be depended upon with regard to
the
former of those two objects, than with regard to the latter. Their
superiority
over the country gentleman is, not so much in their knowledge of
the
public interest, as in their having a better knowledge of their own
interest
than he has of his. It is by this superior knowledge of their own
interest
that they have frequently imposed upon his generosity, and
persuaded
him to give up both his own interest and that of the public, from
a very
simple but honest conviction, that their interest, and not his, was
the
interest of the public. The interest of the dealers, however, in any
particular
branch of trade or manufactures, is always in some respects
different
from, and even opposite to, that of the public. To widen the
market,
and to narrow the competition, is always the interest of the
dealers.
To widen the market may frequently be agreeable enough to the
interest
of the public ; but to narrow the competition must always be
against
it, and can only serve to enable the dealers, by raising their
profits
above what they naturally would be, to levy, for their own benefit,
an
absurd tax upon the rest of their fellow-citizens. The proposal of any
new law
or regulation of commerce which comes from this order, ought always
to be
listened to with great precaution, and ought never to be adopted till
after
having been long and carefully examined, not only with the most
scrupulous,
but with the most suspicious attention. It comes from an order
of men,
whose interest is never exactly the same with that of the public,
who
have generally an interest to deceive and even to oppress the public,
and who
accordingly have, upon many occasions, both deceived and oppressed
it.
#
PRICES
OF WHEAT
Year Prices/Quarter Average of different
Average prices of
in each year prices in one year
each year in money
of 1776
£ s d
£ s d £ s
d
1202 0
12 0 1
16 0
1205 0
12 0
0
13 4 0 13 5 2 0 3
0
15 0
1223 0
12 0 1 16 0
1237 0
3 4 0
10 0
1243 0
2 0 0
6 0
1244 0
2 0 0
6 0
1246 0
16 0 2 8 0
1247 0
13 5 2
0 0
1257 1
4 0 3
12 0
1258 1
0 0
0
15 0 0 17 0 2 11 0
0
16 0
1270 4
16 0
6
8 0 5 12 0 16 16 0
1286 0
2 8
0
16 0 0 9 4 1 8 0
Total 35 9
3
Average 2
19 1¼
1287 0
3 4 0
10 0
1288 0
0 8
0
1 0
0
1 4
0
1 6
0
1 8 0 3 0¼ 0 9 1¾
0
2 0
0
3 4
0
9 4
1289 0
12 0
0
6 0
0
2 0 0 10 1½ 1 10 4½
0
10 8
1
0 0
1290 0
16 0 2
8 0
1294 0
16 0 2
8 0
1302 0
4 0 0
12 0
1309 0
7 2 1
1 6
1315 1
0 0 3
0 0
1316 1
0 0
1
10 0 1 10 6
4 11 6
1
12 0
2
0 0
1317 2
4 0
0
14 0
2
13 0 1 19 6 5 18 6
4
0 0
0
6 8
1336 0
2 0 0
6 0
1338 0
3 4 0
10 0
Total 23 4
11¼
Average 1 18
8
1339 0
9 0 1
7 0
1349 0
2 0 0
5 2
1359 1
6 8 3
2 2
1361 0
2 0 0
4 8
1363 0
15 0 1 15 0
1369 1
0 0
1
4 0 1 2 0 2 9 4
1379 0
4 0 0
9 4
1387 0
2 0 0
4 8
1390 0
13 4
0
14 0 0 14 5 1 13 7
0
16 0
1401 0
16 0 1
17 6
1407 0
4 4¾
0
3 4 0 3 10 0 8 10
1416 0
16 0 1 12 0
Total 15 9
4
Average 1 5
9½
1423 0
8 0 0
1425 0
4 0 0
1434 1
6 8 4
1435 0
5 4 8
1439 1
0 0
1
6 8 1 3 4 2 6 8
1440 1
4 0 2 8 0
1444 0
4 4 0 4 2 0 4 8
0
4 0
1445 0
4 6 0
9 0
1447 0
8 0 0
16 0
1448 0
6 8 0
13 4
1449 0
5 0 0
10 0
1451 0
8 0 0
16 0
Total 12 15
4
Average 1
1 3¹/³
1453 0
5 4 0
10 8
1455 0
1 2 0
2 4
1457 0
7 8 1
15 4
1459 0
5 0 0
10 0
1460 0
8 0 0
16 0
1463 0
2 0 0 1 10 0 3 8
0
1 8
1464 0
6 8 0
10 0
1486 1
4 0 1 17 0
1491 0
14 8 1
2 0
1494 0
4 0 0
6 0
1495 0
3 4 0
5 0
1497 1
0 0 1
11 0
Total 8 9
0
Average 0 14
1
1499 0
4 0 0
6 0
1504 0
5 8 0
8 6
1521 1
0 0 1
10 0
1551 0
8 0 0
8 0
1553 0
8 0 0
8 0
1554 0
8 0 0
8 0
1555 0
8 0 0
8 0
1556 0
8 0 0
8 0
1557 0
8 0
0
4 0 0 17 8½ 0 17 8½
0
5 0
2
13 4
1558 0
8 0 0
8 0
1559 0
8 0 0
8 0
1560 0
8 0 0
8 0
Total 6 0
2½
Average 0 10 0½
1561 0
8 0 0
8 0
1562 0
8 0 0
8 0
1574 2
16 0
1
4 0 2 0 0 2 0 0
1587 3
4 0 3
4 0
1594 2
16 0 2
16 0
1595 2
13 0 2
13 0
1596 4
0 0 4
0 0
1597 5
4 0
4
0 0 4 12
0 4 12
0
1598 2
16 8 2
16 8
1599 1
19 2 1
19 8
1600 1
17 8 1
17 8
1601 1
14 10 1
14 10
Total 28 9
4
Average 2 7
5½
PRICES
OF THE QUARTER OF NINE BUSHELS OF THE BEST OR HIGHEST
PRICED
WHEAT AT WINDSOR MARKET, ON LADY DAY AND MICHAELMAS,
FROM
1595 TO 1764 BOTH INCLUSIVE; THE PRICE OF EACH YEAR
BEING
THE MEDIUM BETWEEN THE HIGHEST PRICES OF THESE TWO
MARKET
DAYS.
£
s d
1595 2
0 0
1596 2
8 0
1597 3
9 6
1598 2
16 8
1599 1
19 2
1600 1
17 8
1601 1
14 10
1602 1
9 4
1603 1
15 4
1604 1
10 8
1605 1
15 10
1606 1
13 0
1607 1
16 8
1608 2
16 8
1609 2
10 0
1610 1
15 10
1611 1
18 8
1612 2
2 4
1613 2
8 8
1614 2
1 8½
1615 1
18 8
1616 2
0 4
1617 2
8 8
1618 2
6 8
1619 1
15 4
1620 1
10 4
26)54
0 6½
Average 2
1 6¾
1621 1
10 4
1622 2
18 8
1623 2
12 0
1624 2
8 0
1625 2
12 0
1626 2
9 4
1627 1
16 0
1628 1
8 0
1629 2
2 0
1630 2
15 8
1631 3
8 0
1632 2 13 4
1633 2
18 0
1634 2
16 0
1635 2
16 0
1636 2
16 8
16)40
0 0
Average 2
10 0
1637 2
13 0
1638 2
17 4
1639 2
4 10
1640 2
4 8
1641 2
8 0
1646 2
8 0
1647 3
13 0
1648 4
5 0
1649 4
0 0
1650 3
16 8
1651 3
13 4
1652 2
9 6
1653 1
15 6
1654 1
6 0
1655 1
13 4
1656 2
3 0
1657 2
6 8
1658 3
5 0
1659 3
6 0
1660 2
16 6
1661 3
10 0
1662 3
14 0
1663 2
17 0
1664 2
0 6
1665 2
9 4
1666 1
16 0
1667 1
16 0
1668 2
0 0
1669 2
4 4
1670 2
1 8
1671 2
2 0
1672 2
1 0
1673 2
6 8
1674 3
8 8
1675 3
4 8
1676 1
18 0
1677 2
2 0
1678 2
19 0
1679 3
0 0
1680 2
5 0
1681 2
6 8
1682 2
4 0
1683 2
0 0
1684 2
4 0
1685 2
6 8
1686 1
14 0
1687 1
5 2
1688 2
6 0
1689 1
10 0
1690 1
14 8
1691 1
14 0
1692 2 6 8
1693 3
7 8
1694 3
4 0
1695 2
13 0
1696 3
11 0
1697 3
0 0
1698 3
8 4
1699 3
4 0
1700 2
0 0
60) 153
1 8
Average
2 11 0¹/³
1701 1
17 8
1702 1
9 6
1703 1
16 0
1704 2
6 6
1705 1
10 0
1706 1
6 0
1707 1
8 6
1708 2
1 6
1709 3
18 6
1710 3
18 0
1711 2
14 0
1712 2
6 4
1713 2 11 0
1714 2
10 4
1715 2
3 0
1716 2
8 0
1717 2
5 8
1718 1
18 10
1719 1
15 0
1720 1
17 0
1721 1
17 6
1722 1
16 0
1723 1
14 8
1724 1
17 0
1725 2
8 6
1726 2
6 0
1727 2
2 0
1728 2
14 6
1729 2
6 10
1730 1
16 6
1731 1
12 10 1 12 10
1732 1
6 8 1 6 8
1733 1
8 4 1
8 4
1734 1
18 10 1 18 10
1735 2
3 0 2 3 0
1736 2
0 4 2 0 4
1737 1
18 0 1 18 0
1738 1
15 6 1
15 6
1739 1
18 6 1 18 6
1740 2
10 8 2 10 8
10)
18 12 8
1 17 3½
1741 2
6 8 2 6 8
1742 1
14 0 1 14 0
1743 1
4 10 1 4 10
1744 1
4 10 1 4 10
1745 1
7 6 1
7 6
1746 1
19 0 1 19 0
1747 1
14 10 1 14 10
1748 1
17 0 1 17 0
1749 1
17 0 1 17 0
1750 1
12 6 1 12
6
10)
16 18 2
1 13 9¾
1751 1
18 6
1752 2
1 10
1753 2
4 8
1754 1
13 8
1755 1
14 10
1756 2
5 3
1757 3
0 0
1758 2
10 0
1759 1
19 10
1760 1
16 6
1761 1
10 3
1762 1
19 0
1763 2
0 9
1764 2
6 9
64) 129
13 6
Average
2 0 6¾
BOOK II.
OF THE
NATURE, ACCUMULATION, AND EMPLOYMENT OF STOCK.
INTRODUCTION.
In that
rude state of society, in which there is no division of labour, in
which
exchanges are seldom made, and in which every man provides every thing
for
himself, it is not necessary that any stock should be accumulated, or
stored
up before-hand, in order to carry on the business of the society.
Every
man endeavours to supply, by his own industry, his own occasional
wants,
as they occur. When he is hungry, he goes to the forest to hunt ;
when
his coat is worn out, he clothes himself with the skin of the first
large
animal he kills : and when his hut begins to go to ruin, he repairs
it, as
well as he can, with the trees and the turf that are nearest it.
But
when the division of labour has once been thoroughly introduced, the
produce
of a man's own labour can supply but a very small part of his
occasional
wants. The far greater part of them are supplied by the produce
of
other men's labour, which he purchases with the produce, or, what is the
same
thing, with the price of the produce, of his own. But this purchase
cannot
be made till such time as the produce of his own labour has not only
been
completed, but sold. A stock of goods of different kinds, therefore,
must be
stored up somewhere, sufficient to maintain him, and to supply him
with
the materials and tools of his work, till such time at least as both
these
events can be brought about. A weaver cannot apply himself entirely to
his
peculiar business, unless there is before-hand stored up somewhere,
either
in his own possession, or in that of some other person, a stock
sufficient
te maintain him, and to supply him with the materials and tools
of his
work, till he has not only completed, but sold his web. This
accumulation
must evidently be previous to his applying his industry for so
long a
time to such a peculiar business.
As the
accumulation of stock must, in the nature of things, be previous to
the
division of labour, so labour can be more and more subdivided in
proportion
only as stock is previously more and more accumulated. The
quantity
of materials which the same number of people can work up, increases
in a
great proportion as labour comes to be more and more subdivided; and as
the
operations of each workman are gradually reduced to a greater degree of
simplicity,
a variety of new machines come to be invented for facilitating
and
abridging those operations. As the division of labour advances,
therefore,
in order to give constant employment to an equal number of
workmen,
an equal stock of provisions, and a greater stock of materials and
tools
than what would have been necessary in a ruder state of things, must
be
accumulated before-hand. But the number of workmen in every branch of
business
generally increases with the division of labour in that branch; or
rather
it is the increase of their number which enables them to class and
subdivide
themselves in this manner.
As the
accumulation of stock is previously necessary for carrying on this
great
improvement in the productive powers of labour, so that accumulation
naturally
leads to this improvement. The person who employs his stock in
maintaining
labour, necessarily wishes to employ it in such a manner as to
produce
as great a quantity of work as possible. He endeavours, therefore,
both to
make among his workmen the most proper distribution of employment,
and to
furnish them with the best machines which he can either invent or
afford
to purchase. His abilities, in both these respects, are generally in
proportion
to the extent of his stock, or to the number of people whom it
can
employ. The quantity of industry, therefore, not only increases in every
country
with the increase of the stock which employs it, but, in consequence
of that
increase, the same quantity of industry produces a much greater
quantity
of work.
Such
are in general the effects of the increase of stock upon industry and
its
productive powers.
In the
following book, I have endeavoured to explain the nature of stock,
the
effects of its accumulation into capital of different kinds, and the
effects
of the different employments of those capitals. This book is divided
into
five chapters. In the first chapter, I have endeavoured to shew what
are the
different parts or branches into which the stock, either of an
individual,
or of a great society, naturally divides itself. In the second,
I have
endeavoured to explain the nature and operation of money, considered
as a
particular branch of the general stock of the society. The stock which
is
accumulated into a capital, may either be employed by the person to whom
it
belongs, or it may be lent to some other person. In the third and fourth
chapters,
I have endeavoured to examine the manner in which it operates in
both
these situations. The fifth and last chapter treats of the different
effects
which the different employments of capital immediately produce upon
the
quantity, both of national industry, and of the annual produce of land
and
labour.
CHAPTER I.
OF THE
DIVISION OF STOCK.
When
the stock which a man possesses is no more than sufficient to maintain
him for
a few days or a few weeks, he seldom thinks of deriving any revenue
from
it. He consumes it as sparingly as he can, and endeavours, by his
labour,
to acquire something which may supply its place before it be
consumed
altogether. His revenue is, in this case, derived from his labour
only.
This is the state of the greater part of the labouring poor in all
countries.
But
when he possesses stock sufficient to maintain him for months or years,
he
naturally endeavours to derive a revenue from the greater part of it,
reserving
only so much for his immediate consumption as may maintain him
till
this revenue begins to come in. His whole stock, therefore, is
distinguished
into two parts. That part which he expects is to afford him
this
revenue is called his capital. The other is that which supplies his
immediate
consumption, and which consists either, first, in that portion of
his
whole stock which was originally reserved for this purpose; or,
secondly,
in his revenue, from whatever source derived, as it gradually
comes
in ; or, thirdly, in such things as had been purchased by either of
these
in former years, and which are not yet entirely consumed, such as a
stock
of clothes, household furniture, and the like. In one or other, or all
of
these three articles, consists the stock which men commonly reserve for
their
own immediate consumption.
There
are two different ways in which a capital may be employed so as to
yield a
revenue or profit to its employer.
First,
it maybe employed in raising, manufacturing, or purchasing goods, and
selling
them again with a profit. The capital employed in this manner yields
no
revenue or profit to its employer, while it either remains in his
possession,
or continues in the same shape. The goods of the merchant yield
him no
revenue or profit till he sells them for money, and the money yields
him as
little till it is again exchanged for goods. His capital is
continually
going from him in one shape, and returning to him in another ;
and it
is only by means of such circulation, or successive changes, that it
can
yield him any profit. Such capitals, therefore, may very properly be
called
circulating capitals.
Secondly,
it may be employed in the improvement of land, in the purchase of
useful
machines and instruments of trade, or in such like things as yield a
revenue
or profit without changing masters, or circulating any further. Such
capitals,
therefore, may very properly be called fixed capitals.
Different
occupations require very different proportions between the fixed
and
circulating capitals employed in them.
The
capital of a merchant, for example, is altogether a circulating capital.
He has
occasion for no machines or instruments of trade, unless his shop or
warehouse
be considered as such.
Some
part of the capital of every master artificer or manufacturer must be
fixed
in the instruments of his trade. This part, however, is very small in
some,
and very great in others, A master tailor requires no other
instruments
of trade but a parcel of needles. Those of the master shoemaker
are a
little, though but a very little, more expensive. Those of the weaver
rise a
good deal above those of the shoemaker. The far greater part of the
capital
of all such master artificers, however, is circulated either in the
wages
of their workmen, or in the price of their materials, and repaid, with
a
profit, by the price of the work.
In
other works a much greater fixed capital is required. In a great
iron-work,
for example, the furnace for melting the ore, the forge, the
slit-mill,
are instruments of trade which cannot be erected without a very
great
expense. In coal works, and mines of
every kind, the machinery
necessary,
both for drawing out the water, and for other purposes, is
frequently
still more expensive.
That
part of the capital of the farmer which is employed in the instruments
of
agriculture is a fixed, that which is employed in the wages and
maintenance
of his labouring servants is a circulating capital. He makes a
profit
of the one by keeping it in his own possession, and of the other by
parting
with it. The price or value of his labouring cattle is a fixed
capital,
in the same manner as that of the instruments of husbandry; their
maintenance
is a circulating capital, in the same manner as that of the
labouring
servants. The farmer makes his profit by keeping the labouring
cattle,
and by parting with their maintenance. Both the price and the
maintenance
of the cattle which are bought in and fattened, not for labour,
but for
sale, are a circulating capital. The farmer makes his profit by
parting
with them. A flock of sheep or a herd of cattle, that, in a breeding
country,
is brought in neither for labour nor for sale, but in order to make
a
profit by their wool, by their milk, and by their increase, is a fixed
capital.
The profit is made by keeping them. Their maintenance is a
circulating
capital. The profit is made by parting with it; and it comes
back
with both its own profit and the profit upon the whole price of the
cattle,
in the price of the wool, the milk, and the increase. The whole
value
of the seed, too, is properly a fixed capital. Though it goes
backwards
and forwards between the ground and the granary, it never changes
masters,
and therefore does not properly circulate. The farmer makes his
profit,
not by its sale, but by its increase.
The
general stock of any country or society is the same with that of all its
inhabitants
or members ; and, therefore, naturally divides itself into the
same
three portions, each of which has a distinct function or office.
The
first is that portion which is reserved for immediate consumption, and
of
which the characteristic is, that it affords no revenue or profit. It
consists
in the stock of food, clothes, household furniture, etc. which have
been
purchased by their proper consumers, but which are not yet entirely
consumed.
The whole stock of mere dwelling-houses, too, subsisting at anyone
time in
the country, make a part of this first portion. The stock that is
laid
out in a house, if it is to be the dwelling-house of the proprietor,
ceases
from that moment to serve in the function of a capital, or to afford
any
revenue to its owner. A dwelling-house, as such, contributes nothing to
the
revenue of its inhabitant ; and though it is, no doubt, extremely useful
to him,
it is as his clothes and household furniture are useful to him,
which,
however, make a part of his expense, and not of his revenue. If it is
to be
let to a tenant for rent, as the house itself can produce nothing, the
tenant
must always pay the rent out of some other revenue, which he derives,
either
from labour, or stock, or land. Though a house, therefore, may yield
a
revenue to its proprietor, and thereby serve in the function of a capital
to him,
it cannot yield any to the public, nor serve in the function of a
capital
to it, and the revenue of the whole body of the people can never be
in the
smallest degree increased by it. Clothes and household furniture, in
the
same manner, sometimes yield a revenue, and thereby serve in the
function
of a capital to particular persons. In countries where masquerades
are
common, it is a trade to let out masquerade dresses for a night.
Upholsterers
frequently let furniture by the month or by the year.
Undertakers
let the furniture of funerals by the day and by the week. Many
people
let furnished houses, and get a rent, not only for the use of the
house,
but for that of the furniture. The revenue, however, which is derived
from
such things, must always be ultimately drawn from some other source of
revenue.
Of all parts of the stock, either of an individual or of a society,
reserved
for immediate consumption, what is laid out in houses is most
slowly
consumed. A stock of clothes may last several years; a stock of
furniture
half a century or a century; but a stock of houses, well built and
properly
taken care of, may last many centuries. Though the period of their
total
consumption, however, is more distant, they are still as really a
stock
reserved for immediate consumption as either clothes or household
furniture.
The
second of the three portions into which the general stock of the society
divides
itself, is the fixed capital ; of which the characteristic is, that
it
affords a revenue or profit without circulating or changing masters. It
consists
chiefly of the four following articles.
First,
of all useful machines and instruments of trade, which facilitate and
abridge
labour.
Secondly,
of all those profitable buildings which are the means of procuring
a
revenue, not only to the proprietor who lets them for a rent, but to the
person
who possesses them, and pays that rent for them; such as shops,
warehouses,
work-houses, farm-houses, with all their necessary buildings,
stables,
granaries, etc. These are very different from mere dwelling-houses.
They
are a sort of instruments of trade, and may be considered in the same
light.
Thirdly,
of the improvements of land, of what has been profitably laid out
in
clearing, draining, inclosing, manuring, and reducing it into the
condition
most proper for tillage and culture. An improved farm may very
justly
be regarded in the same light as those useful machines which
facilitate
and abridge labour, and by means of which an equal circulating
capital
can afford a much greater revenue to its employer. An improved farm
is
equally advantageous and more durable than any of those machines,
frequently
requiring no other repairs than the most profitable application
of the
farmer's capital employed in cultivating it.
Fourthly,
of the acquired and useful abilities of all the inhabitants and
members
of the society. The acquisition of such talents, by the maintenance
of the
acquirer during his education, study, or apprenticeship, always costs
a real
expense, which is a capital fixed and realized, as it were, in his
person.
Those talents, as they make a part of his fortune, so do they
likewise
that of the society to which he belongs. The improved dexterity of
a
workman may be considered in the same light as a machine or instrument of
trade
which facilitates and abridges labour, and which, though it costs a
certain
expense, repays that expense with a profit.
The
third and last of the three portions into which the general stock of the
society
naturally divides itself, is the circulating capital, of which the
characteristic
is, that it affords a revenue only by circulating or changing
masters.
It is composed likewise of four parts.
First,
of the money, by means of which all the other three are circulated
and
distributed to their proper consumers.
Secondly,
of the stock of provisions which are in the possession of the
butcher,
the grazier, the farmer, the corn-merchant, the brewer, etc. and
from
the sale of which they expect to derive a profit.
Thirdly,
of the materials, whether altogether rude, or more or less
manufactured,
of clothes, furniture, and building which are not yet made up
into
any of those three shapes, but which remain in the hands of the
growers,
the manufacturers, the mercers, and drapers, the timber-merchants,
the
carpenters and joiners, the brick-makers, etc.
Fourthly,
and lastly, of the work which is made up and completed, but which
is
still in the hands of the merchant and manufacturer, and not yet disposed
of or
distributed to the proper consumers; such as the finished work which
we
frequently find ready made in the shops of the smith, the cabinet-maker,
the
goldsmith, the jeweller, the china-merchant, etc. The circulating
capital
consists, in this manner, of the provisions, materials, and finished
work of
all kinds that are in the hands of their respective dealers, and of
the
money that is necessary for circulating and distributing them to those
who are
finally to use or to consume them.
Of
these four parts, three - provisions, materials, and finished work, are
either
annually or in a longer or shorter period, regularly withdrawn from
it, and
placed either in the fixed capital, or in the stock reserved for
immediate
consumption.
Every
fixed capital is both originally derived from, and requires to be
continually
supported by, a circulating capital. All useful machines and
instruments
of trade are originally derived from a circulating capital,
which
furnishes the materials of which they are made, and the maintenance of
the
workmen who make them. They require, too, a capital of the same kind to
keep
them in constant repair.
No fixed
capital can yield any revenue but by means of a circulating capital
The
most useful machines and instruments of trade will produce nothing,
without
the circulating capital, which affords the materials they are
employed
upon, and the maintenance of the workmen who employ them. Land,
however
improved, will yield no revenue without a circulating capital, which
maintains
the labourers who cultivate and collect its produce.
To
maintain and augment the stock which maybe reserved for immediate
consumption,
is the sole end and purpose both of the fixed and circulating
capitals.
It is this stock which feeds, clothes, and lodges the people.
Their
riches or poverty depend upon the abundant or sparing supplies which
those
two capitals can afford to the stock reserved for immediate
consumption.
So
great a part of the circulating capital being continually withdrawn from
it, in
order to be placed in the other two branches of the general stock of
the
society, it must in its turn require continual supplies without which it
would
soon cease to exist. These supplies are principally drawn from three
sources;
the produce of land, of mines, and of fisheries. These afford
continual
supplies of provisions and materials, of which part is afterwards
wrought
up into finished work and by which are replaced the provisions,
materials,
and finished work, continually withdrawn from the circulating
capital.
From mines, too, is drawn what is necessary for maintaining and
augmenting
that part of it which consists in money. For though, in the
ordinary
course of business, this part is not, like the other three,
necessarily
withdrawn from it, in order to be placed in the other two
branches
of the general stock of the society, it must, however, like all
other
things, be wasted and worn out at last, and sometimes, too, be either
lost or
sent abroad, and must, therefore, require continual, though no doubt
much
smaller supplies.
Lands,
mines, and fisheries, require all both a fixed and circulating
capital
to cultivate them; and their produce replaces, with a profit not
only
those capitals, but all the others in the society. Thus the farmer
annually
replaces to the manufacturer the provisions which he had consumed,
and the
materials which he had wrought up the year before; and the
manufacturer
replaces to the farmer the finished work which he had wasted
and
worn out in the same time. This is the real exchange that is annually
made
between those two orders of people, though it seldom happens that the
rude
produce of the one, and the manufactured produce of the other, are
directly
bartered for one another ; because it seldom happens that the
farmer
sells his corn and his cattle, his flax and his wool, to the very
same
person of whom he chuses to purchase the clothes, furniture, and
instruments
of trade, which he wants. He sells, therefore, his rude produce
for
money, with which he can purchase, wherever it is to be had, the
manufactured
produce he has occasion for. Land even replaces, in part at
least,
the capitals with which fisheries and mines are cultivated. It is the
produce
of land which draws the fish from the waters ; and it is the produce
of the
surface of the earth which extracts the minerals from its bowels.
The
produce of land, mines, and fisheries, when their natural fertility is
equal,
is in proportion to the extent and proper application of the capitals
employed
about them. When the capitals are equal, and equally well applied,
it is
in proportion to their natural fertility.
In all
countries where there is a tolerable security, every man of common
understanding
will endeavour to employ whatever stock he can command, in
procuring
either present enjoyment or future profit. If it is employed in
procuring
present enjoyment, it is a stock reserved for immediate
consumption.
If it is employed in procuring future profit, it must procure
this
profit either by staying with him, or by going from him. In the one
case it
is a fixed, in the other it is a circulating capital. A man must be
perfectly
crazy, who, where there is a tolerable security, does not employ
all the
stock which he commands, whether it be his own, or borrowed of other
people,
in some one or other of those three ways.
In
those unfortunate countries, indeed, where men are continually afraid of
the
violence of their superiors, they frequently bury or conceal a great
part of
their stock, in order to have it always at hand to carry with them
to some
place of safety, in case of their being threatened with any of those
disasters
to which they consider themselves at all times exposed. This is
said to
be a common practice in Turkey, in Indostan, and, I believe, in most
other
governments of Asia. It seems to have been a common practice among our
ancestors
during the violence of the feudal government. Treasure-trove was,
in
these times, considered as no contemptible part of the revenue of the
greatest
sovereigns in Europe. It consisted in such treasure as was found
concealed
in the earth, and to which no particular person could prove any
right.
This was regarded, in those times, as so important an object, that it
was
always considered as belonging to the sovereign, and neither to the
finder
nor to the proprietor of the land, unless the right to it had been
conveyed
to the latter by an express clause in his charter. It was put upon
the
same footing with gold and silver mines, which, without a special clause
in the
charter, were never supposed to be comprehended in the general grant
of the
lands, though mines of lead, copper, tin, and coal were, as things of
smaller
consequence.
CHAPTER II.
OF
MONEY, CONSIDERED AS A PARTICULAR BRANCH OF THE GENERAL STOCK OF THE
SOCIETY,
OR OF THE EXPENSE OF MAINTAINING THE NATIONAL CAPITAL.
It has
been shown in the First Book, that the price of the greater part of
commodities
resolves itself into three parts, of which one pays the wages of
the
labour, another the profits of the stock, and a third the rent of the
land
which had been employed in producing and bringing them to market: that
there
are, indeed, some commodities of which the price is made up of two of
those
parts only, the wages of labour, and the profits of stock ; and a very
few in
which it consists altogether in one, the wages of labour; but that
the price
of every commodity necessarily resolves itself into some one or
other,
or all, of those three parts; every part of it which goes neither to
rent
nor to wages, being necessarily profit to some body.
Since
this is the case, it has been observed, with regard to every
particular
commodity, taken separately, it must be so with regard to all the
commodities
which compose the whole annual produce of the land and labour of
every
country, taken complexly. The whole price or exchangeable value of
that annual
produce must resolve itself into the same three parts, and be
parcelled
out among the different inhabitants of the country, either as the
wages
of their labour, the profits of their stock, or the rent of their
land.
But
though the whole value of the annual produce of the land and labour of
every
country, is thus divided among, and constitutes a revenue to, its
different
inhabitants ; yet, as in the rent of a private estate, we
distinguish
between the gross rent and the neat rent, so may we likewise in
the
revenue of all the inhabitants of a great country.
The
gross rent of a private estate comprehends whatever is paid by the
farmer;
the neat rent, what remains free to the landlord, after deducting
the
expense of management, of repairs, and all other necessary charges; or
what,
without hurting his estate, he can afford to place in his stock
reserved
for immediate consumption, or to spend upon his table, equipage,
the
ornaments of his house and furniture, his private enjoyments and
amusements.
His real wealth is in proportion, not to his gross, but to his
neat
rent.
The
gross revenue of all the inhabitants of a great country comprehends the
whole
annual produce of their land and labour; the neat revenue, what
remains
free to them, after deducting the expense of maintaining first,
their
fixed, and, secondly, their circulating capital, or what, without
encroaching
upon their capital, they can place in their stock reserved for
immediate
consumption, or spend upon their subsistence. conveniencies, and
amusements.
Their real wealth, too, is in proportion, not to their gross,
but to
their neat revenue.
The
whole expense of maintaining the fixed capital must evidently be
excluded
from the neat revenue of the society. Neither the materials
necessary
for supporting their useful machines and instruments of trade,
their
profitable buildings, etc. nor the produce of the labour necessary for
fashioning
those materials into the proper form, can ever make any part of
it. The
price of that labour may indeed make a part of it; as the workmen so
employed
may place the whole value of their wages in their stock reserved
for
immediate consumption. But in other sorts of labour, both the price and
the
produce go to this stock ; the price to that of the workmen, the produce
to that
of other people, whose subsistence, conveniencies, and amusements,
are
augmented by the labour of those workmen.
The
intention of the fixed capital is to increase the productive powers of
labour,
or to enable the same number of labourers to perform a much greater
quantity
of work. In a farm where all the necessary buildings, fences,
drains,
communications, etc. are in the most perfect good order, the same
number
of labourers and labouring cattle will raise a much greater produce,
than in
one of equal extent and equally good ground, but not furnished with
equal
conveniencies. In manufactures, the same number of hands, assisted
with
the best machinery, will work up a much greater quantity of goods than
with more
imperfect instruments of trade. The expense which is properly laid
out
upon a fixed capital of any kind, is always repaid with great profit,
and
increases the annual produce by a much greater value than that of the
support
which such improvements require. This support, however, still
requires
a certain portion of that produce. A certain quantity of materials,
and the
labour of a certain number of workmen, both of which might have been
immediately
employed to augment the food, clothing, and lodging, the
subsistence
and conveniencies of the society, are thus diverted to another
employment,
highly advantageous indeed, but still different from this one.
It is
upon this account that all such improvements in mechanics, as enable
the
same number of workmen to perform an equal quantity of work with cheaper
and
simpler machinery than had been usual before, are always regarded as
advantageous
to every society. A certain quantity of materials, and the
labour
of a certain number of workmen, which had before been employed in
supporting
a more complex and expensive machinery, can afterwards be applied
to
augment the quantity of work which that or any other machinery is useful
only
for performing. The undertaker of some great manufactory, who employs a
thousand
a-year in the maintenance of his machinery, if he can reduce this
expense
to five hundred, will naturally employ the other five hundred in
purchasing
an additional quantity of materials, to he wrought up by an
additional
number of workmen. The quantity of that work, therefore, which
his
machinery was useful only for performing, will naturally be augmented,
and
with it all the advantage and conveniency which the society can derive
from
that work.
The
expense of maintaining the fixed capital in a great country, may very
properly
be compared to that of repairs in a private estate. The expense of
repairs
may frequently be necessary for supporting the produce of the
estate,
and consequently both the gross and the neat rent of the landlord.
When by
a more proper direction, however, it can be diminished without
occasioning
any diminution of produce, the gross rent remains at least the
same as
before, and the neat rent is necessarily augmented.
But
though the whole expense of maintaining the fixed capital is thus
necessarily
excluded from the neat revenue of the society, it is not the
same
case with that of maintaining the circulating capital. Of the four
parts
of which this latter capital is composed, money, provisions,
materials,
and finished work, the three last, it has already been observed,
are
regularly withdrawn from it, and placed either in the fixed capital of
the
society, or in their stock reserved for immediate consumption. Whatever
portion
of those consumable goods is not employed in maintaining the former,
goes
all to the latter, and makes a part of the neat revenue of the society.
The
maintenance of those three parts of the circulating capital, therefore,
withdraws
no portion of the annual produce from the neat revenue of the
society,
besides what is necessary for maintaining the fixed capital.
The
circulating capital of a society is in this respect different from that
of an
individual. That of an individual is totally excluded from making any
part of
his neat revenue, which must consist altogether in his profits. But
though
the circulating capital of every individual makes a part of that of
the
society to which he belongs, it is not upon that account totally
excluded
from making a part likewise of their neat revenue. Though the whole
goods
in a merchant's shop must by no means be placed in his own stock
reserved
for immediate consumption, they may in that of other people, who,
from a
revenue derived from other funds, may regularly replace their value
to him,
together with its profits, without occasioning any diminution either
of his
capital or of theirs.
Money,
therefore, is the only part of the circulating capital of a society,
of
which the maintenance can occasion any diminution in their neat revenue.
The
fixed capital, and that part of the circulating capital which consists
in
money, so far as they affect the revenue of the society, bear a very
great
resemblance to one another.
First,
as those machines and instruments of trade, etc. require a certain
expense,
first to erect them, and afterwards to support them, both which
expenses,
though they make a part of the gross, are deductions from the neat
revenue
of the society ; so the stock of money which circulates in any
country
must require a certain expense, first to collect it, and afterwards
to
support it; both which expenses, though they make a part of the gross,
are, in
the same manner, deductions from the neat revenue of the society. A
certain
quantity of very valuable materials, gold and silver, and of very
curious
labour, instead of augmenting the stock reserved for immediate
consumption,
the subsistence, conveniencies, and amusements of individuals,
is
employed in supporting that great but expensive instrument of commerce,
by
means of which every individual in the society has his subsistence,
conveniencies,
and amusements, regularly distributed to him in their proper
proportions.
Secondly,
as the machines and instruments of trade, etc. which compose the
fixed
capital either of an individual or of a society, make no part either
of the
gross or of the neat revenue of either ; so money, by means of which
the
whole revenue of the society is regularly distributed among all its
different
members, makes itself no part of that revenue. The great wheel of
circulation
is altogether different from the goods which are circulated by
means
of it. The revenue of the society consists altogether in those goods,
and not
in the wheel which circulates them. In computing either the gross or
the
neat revenue of any society, we must always, from the whole annual
circulation
of money and goods, deduct the whole value of the money, of
which
not a single farthing can ever make any part of either.
It is
the ambiguity of language only which can make this proposition appear
either
doubtful or paradoxical. When properly explained and understood, it
is
almost self-evident.
When we
talk of any particular sum of money, we sometimes mean nothing but
the
metal pieces of which it is composed, and sometimes we include in our
meaning
some obscure reference to the goods which can be had in exchange for
it, or
to the power of purchasing which the possession of it conveys. Thus,
when we
say that the circulating money of England has been computed at
eighteen
millions, we mean only to express the amount of the metal pieces,
which
some writers have computed, or rather have supposed, to circulate in
that
country. But when we say that a man is worth fifty or a hundred pounds
a-year,
we mean commonly to express, not only the amount of the metal pieces
which
are annually paid to him, but the value of the goods which he can
annually
purchase or consume; we mean commonly to assertain what is or ought
to be
his way of living, or the quantity and quality of the necessaries and
conveniencies
of life in which he can with propriety indulge himself.
When,
by any particular sum of money, we mean not only to express the amount
of the
metal pieces of which it is composed, but to include in its
signification
some obscure reference to the goods which can be had in
exchange for them, the wealth or revenue which it in
this case denotes, is
equal
only to one of the two values which are thus intimated somewhat
ambiguously
by the same word, and to the latter more properly than to the
former,
to the money's worth more properly than to the money.
Thus,
if a guinea be the weekly pension of a particular person, he can in
the
course of the week purchase with it a certain quantity of subsistence,
conveniencies,
and amusements. In proportion as this quantity is great or
small,
so are his real riches, his real weekly revenue. His weekly revenue
is
certainly not equal both to the guinea and to what can be purchased with
it, but
only to one or other of those two equal values, and to the latter
more
properly than to the former, to the guinea's worth rather than to the
guinea.
If the
pension of such a person was paid to him, not in gold, but in a
weekly
bill for a guinea, his revenue surely would not so properly consist
in the
piece of paper, as in what he could get for it. A guinea may be
considered
as a bill for a certain quantity of necessaries and conveniencies
upon
all the tradesmen in the neighbourhood The revenue of the person to
whom it
is paid, does not so properly consist in the piece of gold, as in
what he
can get for it, or in what he can exchange it for. If it could be
exchanged
for nothing, it would, like a bill upon a bankrupt, be of no more
value
than the most useless piece of paper.
Though
the weekly or yearly revenue of all the different inhabitants of any
country,
in the same manner, may be, and in reality frequently is, paid to
them in
money, their real riches, however, the real weekly or yearly revenue
of all
of them taken together, must always be great or small, in proportion
to the
quantity of consumable goods which they can all of them purchase with
this
money. The whole revenue of all of them taken together is evidently not
equal
to both the money and the consumable goods, but only to one or other of
those
two values, and to the latter more properly than to the former.
Though
we frequently, therefore, express a person's revenue by the metal
pieces
which are annually paid to him, it is because the amount of those
pieces
regulates the extent of his power of purchasing, or the value of the
goods
which he can annually afford to consume. We still consider his revenue
as
consisting in this power of purchasing or consuming, and not in the
pieces
which convey it.
But if
this is sufficiently evident, even with regard to an individual, it
is
still more so with regard to a society. The amount of the metal pieces
which
are annually paid to an individual, is often precisely equal to his
revenue,
and is upon that account the shortest and best expression of its
value.
But the amount of the metal pieces which circulate in a society, can
never
be equal to the revenue of all its members. As the same guinea which
pays
the weekly pension of one man to-day, may pay that of another
to-morrow,
and that of a third the day thereafter, the amount of the metal
pieces
which annually circulate in any country, must always be of much less
value
than the whole money pensions annually paid with them. But the power
of
purchasing, or the goods which can successively be bought with the whole
of
those money pensions, as they are successively paid, must always be
precisely
of the same value with those pensions ; as must likewise be the
revenue
of the different persons to whom they are paid. That revenue,
therefore,
cannot consist in those metal pieces, of which the amount is so
much
inferior to its value, but in the power of purchasing, in the goods
which
can successively be bought with them as they circulate from hand to
hand.
Money,
therefore, the great wheel of circulation, the great instrument of
commerce,
like all other instruments of trade, though it makes a part, and a
very
valuable part, of the capital, makes no part of the revenue of the
society
to which it belongs; and though the metal pieces of which it is
composed,
in the course of their annual circulation, distribute to every man
the
revenue which properly belongs to him, they make themselves no part of
that
revenue.
Thirdly,
and lastly, the machines and instruments of trade, etc. which
compose
the fixed capital, bear this further resemblance to that part of the
circulating
capital which consists in money; that as every saving in the
expense
of erecting and supporting those machines, which does not diminish
the
introductive powers of labour, is an improvement of the neat revenue of
the
society ; so every saving in the expense of collecting and supporting
that
part of the circulating capital which consists in money is an
improvement
of exactly the same kind.
It is
sufficiently obvious, and it has partly, too, been explained already,
in what
manner every saving in the expense of supporting the fixed capital
is an
improvement of the neat revenue of the society. The whole capital of
the
undertaker of every work is necessarily divided between his fixed and his
circulating
capital. While his whole capital remains the same, the smaller
the one
part, the greater must necessarily be the other. It is the
circulating
capital which furnishes the materials and wages of labour, and
puts
industry into motion. Every saving, therefore, in the expense of
maintaining
the fixed capital, which does not diminish the productive powers
of
labour, must increase the fund which puts industry into motion, and
consequently
the annual produce of land and labour, the real revenue of
every
society.
The
substitution of paper in the room of gold and silver money, replaces a
very
expensive instrument of commerce with one much less costly, and
sometimes
equally convenient. Circulation comes to be carried on by a new
wheel,
which it costs less both to erect and to maintain than the old one.
But in
what manner this operation is performed, and in what manner it tends
to
increase either the gross or the neat revenue of the society, is not
altogether
so obvious, and may therefore require some further explication.
There
are several different sorts of paper money; but the circulating notes
of
banks and bankers are the species which is best known, and which seems
best
adapted for this purpose.
When
the people of any particular country have such confidence in the
fortune,
probity and prudence of a particular banker, as to believe that
he is
always ready to pay upon demand such of his promissory notes as are
likely
to be at any time presented to him, those notes come to have the same
currency
as gold and silver money, from the confidence that such money can
at any
time be had for them.
A
particular banker lends among his customers his own promissory notes, to
the
extent, we shall suppose, of a hundred thousand pounds. As those notes
serve
all the purposes of money, his debtors pay him the same interest as if
he had
lent them so much money. This interest is the source of his gain.
Though
some of those notes are continually coming back upon him for payment,
part of
them continue to circulate for months and years together. Though he
has
generally in circulation, therefore, notes to the extent of a hundred
thousand
pounds, twenty thousand pounds in gold and silver may, frequently,
be a
sufficient provision for answering occasional demands. By this
operation,
therefore, twenty thousand pounds in gold and silver perform all
the
functions which a hundred thousand could otherwise have performed. The
same
exchanges may be made, the same quantity of consumable goods may be
circulated
and distributed to their proper consumers, by means of his
promissory
notes, to the value of a hundred thousand pounds, as by an equal
value
of gold and silver money. Eighty thousand pounds of gold and silver,
therefore,
can in this manner be spared from the circulation of the country
; and
if different operations of the the same kind should, at the same time,
be
carried on by many different banks and bankers, the whole circulation
may
thus be conducted with a fifth part only of the gold and silver which
would
otherwise have been requisite.
Let us
suppose, for example, that the whole circulating money of some
particular
country amounted, at a particular time, to one million sterling,
that
sum being then sufficient for circulating the whole annual produce of
their
land and labour; let us suppose, too, that some time thereafter,
different
banks and bankers issued promissory notes payable to the bearer,
to the
extent of one million, reserving in their different coffers two
hundred
thousand pounds for answering occasional demands ; there would
remain,
therefore, in circulation, eight hundred thousand pounds in gold and
silver,
and a million of bank notes, or eighteen hundred thousand pounds of
paper
and money together. But the annual produce of the land and labour of
the
country had before required only one million to circulate and distribute
it to
its proper consumers, and that annual produce cannot be immediately
augmented
by those operations of banking. One million, therefore, will be
sufficient
to circulate it after them. The goods to be bought and sold being
precisely
the same as before, the same quantity of money will be sufficient
for
buying and selling them. The channel of circulation, if I may be allowed
such an
expression, will remain precisely the same as before. One million we
have
supposed sufficient to fill that channel. Whatever, therefore, is
poured
into it beyond this sum, cannot run into it, but must overflow. One
million
eight hundred thousand pounds are poured into it. Eight hundred
thousand
pounds, therefore, must overflow, that sum being over and above
what
can be employed in the circulation of the country. But though this sum
cannot
be employed at home, it is too valuable to be allowed to lie idle. It
will,
therefore, be sent abroad, in order to seek that profitable employment
which
it cannot find at home. But the paper cannot go abroad; because at a
distance
from the banks which issue it, and from the country in which
payment
of it can be exacted by law, it will not be received in common
payments.
Gold and silver, therefore, to the amount of eight hundred
thousand
pounds, will be sent abroad, and the channel of home circulation
will
remain filled with a million of paper instead of a million of those
metals
which filled it before.
But
though so great a quantity of gold and silver is thus sent abroad, we
must
not imagine that it is sent abroad for nothing, or that its proprietors
make a
present of it to foreign nations. They will exchange it for foreign
goods
of some kind or another, in order to supply the consumption either of
some
other foreign country, or of their own.
If they
employ it in purchasing goods in one
foreign country, in order to
supply
the consumption of another, or in what is called the carrying trade,
whatever
profit they make will be in addition to the neat revenue of their
own
country. It is like a new fund, created for carrying on a new trade;
domestic
business being now transacted by paper, and the gold and silver
being
converted into a fund for this new trade.
If they
employ it in purchasing foreign goods for home consumption, they may
either,
first, purchase such goods as are likely to be consumed by idle
people,
who produce nothing, such as foreign wines, foreign silks, etc. ;
or,
secondly, they may purchase an additional stock of materials, tools, and
provisions,
in order to maintain and employ an additional number of
industrious
people, who reproduce, with a profit, the value of their annual
consumption.
So far
as it is employed in the first way, it promotes prodigality,
increases
expense and consumption, without increasing production, or
establishing
any permanent fund for supporting that expense, and is in every
respect
hurtful to the society.
So far
as it is employed in the second way, it promotes industry ; and
though
it increases the consumption of the society, it provides a permanent
fund
for supporting that consumption; the people who consume reproducing,
with a
profit, the whole value of their annual consumption. The gross
revenue
of the society, the annual produce of their land and labour, is
increased
by the whole value which the labour of those workmen adds to the
materials
upon which they are employed, and their neat revenue by what
remains
of this value, after deducting what is necessary for supporting the
tools
and instruments of their trade.
That
the greater part of the gold and silver which being forced abroad by
those
operations of banking, is employed in purchasing foreign goods for
home
consumption, is, and must be, employed in purchasing those of this
second
kind, seems not only probable, but almost unavoidable. Though some
particular
men may sometimes increase their expense very considerably,
though
their revenue does not increase at all, we maybe assured that no
class
or order of men ever does so; because, though the principles of
common
prudence do not always govern the conduct of every individual, they
always
influence that of the majority of every class or order. But the
revenue
of idle people, considered as a class or order, cannot, in the
smallest
degree, be increased by those operations of banking. Their expense
in
general, therefore, cannot be much increased by them, though that of a
few
individuals among them may, and in reality sometimes is. The demand of
idle
people, therefore, for foreign goods, being the same, or very nearly
the
same as before, a very small part of the money which, being forced
abroad
by those operations of banking, is employed in purchasing foreign
goods
for home consumption, is likely to be employed in purchasing those for
their
use. The greater part of it will naturally be destined for the
employment
of industry, and not for the maintenance of idleness.
When we
compute the quantity of industry which the circulating capital of
any
society can employ, we must always have regard to those parts of it only
which
consist in provisions, materials, and finished work ; the other, which
consists
in money, and which serves only to circulate those three, must
always
be deducted. In order to put industry into motion, three things are
requisite
; materials to work upon, tools to work with, and the wages or
recompence
for the sake of which the work is done. Money is neither a
material
to work upon, nor a tool to work with ; and though the wages of the
workman
are commonly paid to him in money, his real revenue, like that of
all
other men, consists, not in the money, but in the money's worth; not in
the
metal pieces, but in what can be got for them.
The
quantity of industry which any capital can employ, must evidently be
equal
to the number of workmen whom it can supply with materials, tools, and
a
maintenance suitable to the nature of the work. Money may be requisite for
purchasing
the materials and tools of the work, as well as the maintenance
of the
workmen ; but the quantity of industry which the whole capital can
employ,
is certainly not equal both to the money which purchases, and to the
materials,
tools, and maintenance, which are purchased with it, but only to
one or
other of those two values, and to the latter more properly than to
the
former.
When
paper is substituted in the room of gold and silver money, the quantity
of the
materials, tools, and maintenance, which the whole circulating
capital
can supply, may be increased by the whole value of gold and silver
which
used to be employed in purchasing them. The whole value of the great
wheel
of circulation and distribution is added to the goods which are
circulated
and distributed by means of it. The operation, in some measure,
resembles
that of the undertaker of some great work, who, in consequence of
some
improvement in mechanics, takes down his old machinery, and adds the
difference
between its price and that of the new to his circulating capital,
to the
fund from which he furnishes materials and wages to his workmen.
What is
the proportion which the circulating money of any country bears to
the
whole value of the annual produce circulated by means of it, it is
perhaps
impossible to determine. It has been computed by different authors
at a
fifth, at a tenth, at a twentieth, and at a thirtieth, part of that
value.
But how small soever the proportion which the circulating money may
bear to
the whole value of the annual produce, as but a part, and frequently
but a
small part, of that produce, is ever destined for the maintenance of
industry,
it must always bear a very considerable proportion to that part.
When,
therefore, by the substitution of paper, the gold and silver
necessary
for circulation is reduced to, perhaps, a fifth part of the former
quantity,
if the value of only the greater part of the other four-fifths be
added
to the funds which are destined for the maintenance of industry, it
must
make a very considerable addition to the quantity of that industry,
and,
consequently, to the value of the annual produce of land and labour.
An
operation of this kind has, within these five-and-twenty or thirty years,
been
performed in Scotland, by the erection of new banking companies in
almost
every considerable town, and even in some country villages. The
effects
of it have been precisely those above described. The business of the
country
is almost entirely carried on by means of the paper of those
different
banking companies, with which purchases and payments of all kinds
are
commonly made. Silver very seldom appears, except in the change of a
twenty
shilling bank note, and gold still seldomer. But though the conduct
of all
those different companies has not been unexceptionable, and has
accordingly
required an act of parliament to regulate it, the country,
notwithstanding,
has evidently derived great benefit from their trade. I
have
heard it asserted, that the trade of the city of Glasgow doubled in
about
fifteen years after the first erection of the banks there; and that
the
trade of Scotland has more than quadrupled since the first erection of
the two
public banks at Edinburgh; of which the one, called the Bank of
Scotland,
was established by act of parliament in 1695, and the other,
called
the Royal Bank, by royal charter in 1727. Whether the trade, either
of
Scotland in general, or of the city of Glasgow in particular, has really
increased
in so great a proportion, during so short a period, I do not
pretend
to know. If either of them has increased in this proportion, it
seems
to be an effect too great to be accounted for by the sole operation of
this
cause. That the trade and industry of Scotland, however, have increased
very
considerably during this period, and that the banks have contributed a
good
deal to this increase, cannot be doubted.
The
value of the silver money which circulated in Scotland before the Union
in 1707,
and which, immediately after it, was brought into the Bank of
Scotland,
in order to be recoined, amounted to £411,117: 10: 9 sterling. No
account
has been got of the gold coin ; but it appears from the ancient
accounts
of the mint of Scotland, that the value of the gold annually coined
somewhat
exceeded that of the silver. There were
a good many people, too,
upon
this occasion, who, from a diffidence of repayment, did not bring their
silver
into the Bank of Scotland; and there was, besides, some English coin,
which
was not called in. The whole value of the gold and silver, therefore,
which
circulated in Scotland before the Union, cannot be estimated at less
than a
million sterling. It seems to have constituted almost the whole
circulation
of that country; for though the circulation of the Bank of
Scotland,
which had then no rival, was considerable, it seems to have made
but a
very small part of the whole. In the present times, the whole
circulation
of Scotland cannot be estimated at less than two millions, of
which
that part which consists in gold and silver, most probably, does not
amount
to half a million. But though the circulating gold and silver of
Scotland
have suffered so great a diminution during this period, its real
riches
and prosperity do not appear to have suffered any. Its agriculture,
manufactures,
and trade, on the contrary, the annual produce of its land and
labour,
have evidently been augmented.
It is
chiefly by discounting bills of exchange, that is, by advancing money
upon
them before they are due, that the greater part of banks and bankers
issue
their promissory notes. They deduct always, upon whatever sum they
advance,
the legal interest till the bill shall become due. The payment of
the
bill, when it becomes due, replaces to the bank the value of what had
been
advanced, together with a clear profit of the interest. The banker, who
advances
to the merchant whose bill he discounts, not gold and silver, but
his own
promissory notes, has the advantage of being able to discount to a
greater
amount by the whole value of his promissory notes, which he finds,
by
experience, are commonly in circulation. He is thereby enabled to make
his
clear gain of interest on so much a larger sum.
The
commerce of Scotland, which at present is not very great, was still more
inconsiderable
when the two first banking companies were established ; and
those
companies would have had but little trade, had they confined their
business
to the discounting of bills of exchange. They invented, therefore,
another
method of issuing their promissory notes; by granting what they call
cash
accounts, that is, by giving credit, to the extent of a certain sum
(two or
three thousand pounds for example), to any individual who could
procure
two persons of undoubted credit and good landed estate to become
surety
for him, that whatever money should be advanced to him, within the
sum for
which the credit had been given, should be repaid upon demand,
together
with the legal interest. Credits of this kind are, I believe,
commonly
granted by banks and bankers in all different parts of the world.
But the
easy terms upon which the Scotch banking companies accept of
repayment
are, so far as I know, peculiar to them, and have perhaps been the
principal
cause, both of the great trade of those companies,and of the
benefit
which the country has received from it.
Whoever
has a credit of this kind with one of those companies, and borrows a
thousand
pounds upon it, for example, may repay this sum piece-meal, by
twenty
and thirty pounds at a time, the company discounting a proportionable
part of
the interest of the great sum, from the day on which each of those
small
sums is paid in, till the whole be in this manner repaid. All
merchants,
therefore, and almost all men of business, find it convenient to
keep
such cash accounts with them, and are thereby interested to promote the
trade
of those companies, by readily receiving their notes in all payments,
and by
encouraging all those with whom they have any influence to do the
same.
The banks, when their customers apply to them for money, generally
advance
it to them in their own promissory notes. These the merchants pay
away to
the manufacturers for goods, the manufacturers to the farmers for
materials
and provisions, the farmers to their landlords for rent; the
landlords
repay them to the merchants for the conveniencies and luxuries
with
which they supply them, and the merchants again return them to the
banks,
in order to balance their cash accounts, or to replace what they my
have
borrowed of them ; and thus almost the whole money business of the
country
is transacted by means of them. Hence the great trade of those
companies.
By
means of those cash accounts, every merchant can, without imprudence,
carry
on a greater trade than he otherwise could do. If there are two
merchants,
one in London and the other in Edinburgh, who employ equal stocks
in the
same branch of trade, the Edinburgh merchant can, without imprudence,
carry
on a greater trade, and give employment to a greater number of people,
than
the London merchant. The London merchant must always keep by him a
considerable
sum of money, either in his own coffers, or in those of his
banker,
who gives him no interest for it, in order to answer the demands
continually
coming upon him for payment of the goods which he purchases upon
credit.
Let the ordinary amount of this sum be supposed five hundred pounds
; the
value of the goods in his warehouse must always be less, by five
hundred
pounds, than it would have been, had he not been obliged to keep
such a
sum unemployed. Let us suppose that he generally disposes of his
whole
stock upon hand, or of goods to the value of his whole stock upon
hand,
once in the year. By being obliged to keep so great a sum unemployed,
he must
sell in a year five hundred pounds worth less goods than he might
otherwise
have done. His annual profits must be less by all that he could
have
made by the sale of five hundred pounds worth more goods ; and the
number
of people employed in preparing his goods for the market must be less
by all
those that five hundred pounds more stock could have employed. The
merchant
in Edinburgh, on the other hand, keeps no money unemployed for
answering
such occasional demands. When they
actually come upon him, he
satisfies
them from his cash account with the bank, and gradually replaces
the sum
borrowed with the money or paper which comes in from the occasional
sales
of his goods. With the same stock, therefore, he can, without
imprudence,
have at all times in his warehouse a larger quantity of goods
than
the London merchant ; and can thereby both make a greater profit
himself,
and give constant employment to a greater number of industrious
people
who prepare those goods for the market. Hence the great benefit which
the
country has derived from this trade.
The
facility of discounting bills of exchange, it may be thought, indeed,
gives
the English merchants a conveniency equivalent to the cash accounts of
the
Scotch merchants. But the Scotch merchants, it must be remembered, can
discount
their bills of exchange as easily as the English merchants; and
have,
besides, the additional conveniency of their cash accounts.
The
whole paper money of every kind which can easily circulate in any
country,
never can exceed the value of the gold and silver, of which it
supplies
the place, or which (the commerce being supposed the same) would
circulate
there, if there was no paper money. If twenty shilling notes, for
example,
are the lowest paper money current in Scotland, the whole of that
currency
which can easily circulate there, cannot exceed the sum of gold and
silver
which would be necessary for transacting the annual exchanges of
twenty
shillings value and upwards usually transacted within that country.
Should
the circulating paper at any time exceed that sum, as the excess
could
neither be sent abroad nor be employed in the circulation of the
country,
it must immediately return upon the banks, to be exchanged for gold
and
silver. Many people would immediately perceive that they had more of
this
paper than was necessary for transacting their business at home; and as
they
could not send it abroad, they would immediately demand payment for it
from the
banks. When this superfluous paper was converted into gold and
silver,
they could easily find a use for it, by sending it abroad; but they
could
find none while it remained in the shape of paper. There would
immediately,
therefore, be a run upon the banks to the whole extent of this
superfluous
paper, and if they showed any difficulty or backwardness in
payment,
to a much greater extent ; the alarm which this would occasion
necessarily
increasing the run.
Over
and above the expenses which are common to every branch of trade, such
as the
expense of house-rent, the wages of servants, clerks, accountants,
etc.
the expenses peculiar to a bank consist chiefly in two articles: first,
in the
expense of keeping at all times in its coffers, for answering the
occasional
demands of the holders of its notes, a large sum of money, of
which
it loses the interest; and, secondly, in the expense of replenishing
those
coffers as fast as they are emptied by answering such occasional
demands.
A
banking company which issues more paper than can be employed in the
circulation
of the country, and of which the excess is continually returning
upon
them for payment, ought to increase the quantity of gold and silver
which
they keep at all times in their coffers, not only in proportion to
this
excessive increase of their circulation, but in a much greater
proportion;
their notes returning upon them much faster than in proportion
to the
excess of their quantity. Such a company, therefore, ought to
increase
the first article of their expense, not only in proportion to this
forced
increase of their business, but in a much greater proportion.
The
coffers of such a company, too, though they ought to be filled much
fuller,
yet must empty themselves much faster than if their business was
confined
within more reasonable bounds, and must require not only a more
violent,
but a more constant and uninterrupted exertion of expense, in order
to
replenish them, The coin, too, which is thus continually drawn in such
large
quantities from their coffers, cannot be employed in the circulation
of the
country. It comes in place of a paper which is over and above what can
be
employed in that circulation, and is, therefore, over and above what can
be
employed in it too. But as that coin will not be allowed to lie idle, it
must,
in one shape or another, be sent abroad, in order to find that
profitable
employment which it cannot find at home; and this continual
exportation
of gold and silver, by enhancing the difficulty, must
necessarily
enhance still farther the expense of the bank, in finding new
gold
and silver in order to replenish those coffers, which empty themselves
so very
rapidly. Such a company, therefore, must in proportion to this
forced
increase of their business, increase the second article of their
expense
still more than the first.
Let us
suppose that all the paper of a particular bank, which the
circulation
of the country can easily absorb and employ, amounts exactly to
forty
thousand pounds, and that, for answering occasional demands, this bank
is
obliged to keep at all times in its coffers ten thousand pounds in gold
and
silver. Should this bank attempt to circulate forty-four thousand
pounds,
the four thousand pounds which are over and above what the
circulation
can easily absorb and employ, will return upon it almost as fast
as they
are issued. For answering occasional demands, therefore, this bank
ought
to keep at all times in its coffers, not eleven thousand pounds only,
but
fourteen thousand pounds. It will thus gain nothing by the interest of
the
four thousand pounds excessive circulation ; and it will lose the whole
expense
of continually collecting four thousand pounds in gold and silver,
which
will be continually going out of its coffers as fast as they are
brought
into them.
Had
every particular banking company always understood and attended to its
own
particular interest, the circulation never could have been overstocked
with
paper money. But every particular banking company has not always
understood
or attended to its own particular interest, and the circulation
has
frequently been overstocked with paper money.
By
issuing too great a quantity of paper, of which the excess was
continually
returning, in order to be exchanged for gold and silver, the
Bank of
England was for many years together obliged to coin gold to the
extent
of between eight hundred thousand pounds and a million a-year; or, at
an
average, about eight hundred and fifty thousand pounds. For this great
coinage,
the bank (inconsequence of the worn and degraded state into which
the
gold coin had fallen a few years ago) was frequently obliged to purchase
gold
bullion at the high price of four pounds an ounce, which it soon after
issued
in coin at £3:17:10 1/2 an ounce, losing in this manner between two
and a
half and three per cent. upon the coinage of so very large a sum.
Though
the bank, therefore, paid no seignorage, though the government was
properly
at the expense of this coinage, this liberality of government did
not
prevent altogether the expense of the bank.
The
Scotch banks, in consequence of an excess of the same kind, were all
obliged
to employ constantly agents at London to collect money for them, at
an
expense which was seldom below one and a half or two per cent. This money
was
sent down by the waggon, and insured by the carriers at an additional
expense
of three quarters per cent. or fifteen shillings on the hundred
pounds.
Those agents were not always able to replenish the coffers of their
employers
so fast as they were emptied. In this case, the resource of the
banks
was, to draw upon their correspondents in London bills of exchange, to
the
extent of the sum which they wanted. When those correspondents
afterwards
drew upon them for the payment of this sum, together with the
interest
and commission, some of those banks, from the distress into which
their
excessive circulation had thrown them, had sometimes no other means of
satisfying
this draught, but by drawing a second set of bills, either upon
the
same, or upon some other correspondents in London; and the same sum, or
rather
bills for the same sum, would in this manner make sometimes more than
two or
three journeys ; the debtor bank paying always the interest and
commission
upon the whole accumulated sum. Even those Scotch banks which
never
distinguished themselves by their extreme imprudence, were sometimes
obliged
to employ this ruinous resource.
The
gold coin which was paid out, either by the Bank of England or by the
Scotch
banks, in exchange for that part of their paper which was over and
above
what could be employed in the circulation of the country, being
likewise
over and above what could be employed in that circulation, was
sometimes
sent abroad in the shape of coin, sometimes melted down and sent
abroad
in the shape of bullion, and sometimes melted down and sold to the
Bank of
England at the high price of four pounds an ounce. It was the
newest,
the heaviest, and the best pieces only, which were carefully picked
out of
the whole coin, and either sent abroad or melted down. At home, and
while
they remained in the shape of coin, those heavy pieces were of no more
value
than the light ; but they were of more value abroad, or when melted
down
into bullion at home. The Bank of England, notwithstanding their great
annual
coinage, found, to their astonishment, that there was every year the
same
scarcity of coin as there had been the year before ; and that,
notwithstanding
the great quantity of good and new coin which was every year
issued
from the bank, the state of the coin, instead of growing better and
better,
became every year worse and worse. Every year they found themselves
under
the necessity of coining nearly the same quantity of gold as they had
coined
the year before ; and from the continual rise in the price of gold
bullion,
in consequence of the continual wearing and clipping of the coin,
the
expense of this great annual coinage became, every year, greater and
greater.
The Bank of England, it is to be observed, by supplying its own
coffers
with coin, is indirectly obliged to supply the whole kingdom, into
which
coin is continually flowing from those coffers in a great variety of
ways.
Whatever coin, therefore, was wanted to support this excessive
circulation
both of Scotch and English paper money, whatever vacuities this
excessive
circulation occasioned in the necessary coin of the kingdom, the
Bank of
England was obliged to supply them. The Scotch banks, no doubt, paid
all of
them very dearly for their own imprudence and inattention : but the
Bank of
England paid very dearly, not only for its own imprudence, but for
the
much greater imprudence of almost all the Scotch banks.
The over-trading of some bold projectors in
both parts of the united
kingdom,
was the original cause of this excessive circulation of paper
money.
What a
bank can with propriety advance to a merchant or undertaker of any
kind,
is not either the whole capital with which he trades, or even any
considerable
part of that capital; but that part of it only which he would
otherwise
be obliged to keep by him unemployed and in ready money, for
answering
occasional demands. If the paper money which the bank advances
never
exceeds this value, it can never exceed the value of the gold and
silver
which would necessarily circulate in the country if there was no
paper
money; it can never exceed the quantity which the circulation of the
country
can easily absorb and employ.
When a
bank discounts to a merchant a real bill of exchange, drawn by a real
creditor
upon a real debtor, and which, as soon as it becomes due, is really
paid by
that debtor ; it only advances to him a part of the value which he
would
otherwise be obliged to keep by him unemployed and in ready money, for
answering
occasional demands. The payment of the bill, when it becomes due,
replaces
to the bank the value of what it had advanced, together with the
interest.
The coffers of the bank, so far as its dealings are confined to
such
customers, resemble a water-pond, from which, though a stream is
continually
running out, yet another is continually running in, fully equal
to that
which runs out; so that, without any further care or attention, the
pond
keeps always equally, or very near equally full. Little or no expense
can
ever be necessary for replenishing the coffers of such a bank.
A
merchant, without over-trading, may frequently have occasion for a sum of
ready
money, even when he has no bills to discount. When a bank, besides
discounting
his bills, advances him likewise, upon such occasions, such sums
upon
his cash account, and accepts of a piece-meal repayment, as the money
comes
in from the occasional sale of his goods, upon the easy terms of the
banking
companies of Scotland; it dispenses him entirely from the necessity
of
keeping any part of his stock by him unemployed and in ready money for
answering
occasional demands. When such demands actually come upon him, he
can
answer them sufficiently from his cash account. The bank, however, in
dealing
with such customers, ought to observe with great attention, whether,
in the
course of some short period (of four, five, six, or eight months, for
example),
the sum of the repayments which it commonly receives from them,
is, or
is not, fully equal to that of the advances which it commonly makes
to
them. If, within the course of such short periods, the sum of the
repayments
from certain customers is, upon most occasions, fully equal to
that of
the advances, it may safely continue to deal with such customers.
Though
the stream which is in this case continually running out from its
coffers
may be very large, that which is continually running into them must
be at
least equally large. so that, without any further care or attention,
those
coffers are likely to be always equally or very near equally full, and
scarce
ever to require any extraordinary expense to replenish them. If, on
the
contrary, the sum of the repayments from certain other customers, falls
commonly
very much short of the advances which it makes to them, it cannot
with
any safety continue to deal with such customers, at least if they
continue
to deal with it in this manner. The stream which is in this case
continually
running out from its coffers, is necessarily much larger than
that
which is continually running in ; so that, unless they are replenished
by some
great and continual effort of expense, those coffers must soon be
exhausted
altogether.
The
banking companies of Scotland, accordingly, were for a long time very
careful
to require frequent and regular repayments from all their customers,
and did
not care to deal with any person, whatever might be his fortune or
credit,
who did not make, what they called, frequent and regular operations
with
them. By this attention, besides saving almost entirely the
extraordinary
expense of replenishing their coffers, they gained two other
very
considerable advantages.
First,
by this attention they were enabled to make some tolerable judgment
concerning
the thriving or declining circumstances of their debtors, without
being
obliged to look out for any other evidence besides what their own
books
afforded them ; men being, for the most part, either regular or
irregular
in their repayments, according as their circumstances are either
thriving
or declining. A private man who lends out his money to perhaps half
a dozen
or a dozen of debtors, may, either by himself or his agents, observe
and
inquire both constantly and carefully into the conduct and situation of
each of
them. But a banking company, which lends money to perhaps five
hundred
different people, and of which the attention is continually occupied
by
objects of a very different kind, can have no regular information
concerning
the conduct and circumstances of the greater part of its debtors,
beyond
what its own books afford it. In requiring frequent and regular
repayments
from all their customers, the banking companies of Scotland had
probably
this advantage in view.
Secondly,
by this attention they secured themselves from the possibility of
issuing
more paper money than what the circulation of the country could
easily
absorb and employ. When they observed, that within moderate periods
of
time, the repayments of a particular customer were, upon most occasions,
fully
equal to the advances which they had made to him, they might be
assured
that the paper money which they had advanced to him had not, at any
time,
exceeded the quantity of gold and silver which he would otherwise have
been
obliged to keep by him for answering occasional demands; and that,
consequently,
the paper money, which they had circulated by his means, had
not at
any time exceeded the quantity of gold and silver which would have
circulated
in the country, had there been no paper money. The frequency,
regularity,
and amount of his repayments, would sufficiently demonstrate
that
the amount of their advances had at no time exceeded that part of his
capital
which he would otherwise have been obliged to keep by him
unemployed,
and in ready money, for answering occasional demands; that is,
for the
purpose of keeping the rest of his capital in constant employment.
It is
this part of his capital only which, within moderate periods of time,
is
continually returning to every dealer in the shape of money, whether
paper
or coin, and continually going from him in the same shape. If the
advances
of the bank had commonly exceeded this part of his capital, the
ordinary
amount of his repayments could not, within moderate periods of
time,
have equalled the ordinary amount of its advances. The stream which,
by
means of his dealings, was continually running into the coffers of the
bank,
could not have been equal to the stream which, by means of the same
dealings
was continually running out. The advances of the bank paper, by
exceeding
the quantity of gold and silver which, had there been no such
advances,
he would have been obliged to keep by him for answering occasional
demands,
might soon come to exceed the whole quantity of gold and silver
which (
the commerce being supposed the same ) would have circulated in the
country,
had there been no paper money; and, consequently, to exceed the
quantity
which the circulation of the country could easily absorb and employ
; and
the excess of this paper money would immediately have returned upon
the
bank, in order to be exchanged for gold and silver. This second
advantage,
though equally real, was not, perhaps, so well understood by all
the
different banking companies in Scotland as the first.
When,
partly by the conveniency of discounting bills, and partly by that of
cash
accounts, the creditable traders of any country can be dispensed from
the
necessity of keeping any part of their stock by them unemployed, and in
ready
money, for answering occasional demands, they can reasonably expect no
farther
assistance from hanks and bankers, who, when they have gone thus
far,
cannot, consistently with their own interest and safety, go farther. A
bank
cannot, consistently with its own interest, advance to a trader the
whole,
or even the greater part of the circulating capital with which he
trades
; because, though that capital is continually returning to him in the
shape
of money, and going from him in the same shape, yet the whole of the
returns
is too distant from the whole of the outgoings, and the sum of his
repayments
could not equal the sum of his advances within such moderate
periods
of time as suit the conveniency of a bank. Still less could a bank
afford
to advance him any considerable part of his fixed capital ; of the
capital
which the undertaker of an iron forge, for example, employs in
erecting
his forge and smelting-houses, his work-houses, and warehouses, the
dwelling-houses
of his workmen, etc. ; of the capital which the undertaker
of a
mine employs in sinking his shafts, in erecting engines for drawing out
the
water, in making roads and waggon-ways, etc. ; of the capital which the
person
who undertakes to improve land employs in clearing, draining,
inclosing,
manuring, and ploughing waste and uncultivated fields; in
building
farmhouses, with all their necessary appendages of stables,
granaries,
etc. The returns of the fixed
capital are, in almost all
cases,
much slower than those of the circulating capital : and such
expenses,
even when laid out with the greatest prudence and judgment, very
seldom
return to the undertaker till after a period of many years, a period
by far
too distant to suit the conveniency of a bank. Traders and other
undertakers
may, no doubt with great propriety, carry on a very considerable
part of
their projects with borrowed money. In justice to their creditors,
however,
their own capital ought in this case to be sufficient to insure, if
I may
say so, the capital of those creditors; or to render it extremely
improbable
that those creditors should incur any loss, even though the
success
of the project should fall very much short of the expectation of the
projectors.
Even with this precaution, too, the money which is borrowed, and
which
it is meant should not be repaid till after a period of several years,
ought
not to be borrowed of a bank, but ought to be borrowed upon bond or
mortgage,
of such private people as propose to live upon the interest of
their
money, without taking the trouble themselves to employ the capital,
and who
are, upon that account, willing to lend that capital to such people
of good
credit as are likely to keep it for several years. A bank, indeed,
which
lends its money without the expense of stamped paper, or of attorneys'
fees
for drawing bonds and mortgages, and which accepts of repayment upon
the
easy terms of the banking companies of Scotland, would, no doubt, be a
very
convenient creditor to such traders and undertakers. But such traders
and
undertakers would surely be most inconvenient debtors to such a bank.
It is
now more than five and twenty years since the paper money issued by
the
different banking companies of Scotland was fully equal, or rather was
somewhat
more than fully equal, to what the circulation of the country could
easily
absorb and employ. Those companies, therefore, had so long ago given
all the
assistance to the traders and other undertakers of Scotland which it
is
possible for banks and bankers, consistently with their own interest, to
give.
They had even done somewhat more. They had over-traded a little, and
had
brought upon themselves that loss, or at least that diminution of
profit,
which, in this particular business, never fails to attend the
smallest
degree of over-trading. Those traders and other undertakers, having
got so
much assistance from banks and bankers, wished to get still more. The
banks,
they seem to have thought, could extend their credits to whatever sum
might
be wanted, without incurring any other expense besides that of a few
reams
of paper. They complained of the contracted views and dastardly spirit
of the
directors of those banks, which did not, they said, extend their
credits
in proportion to the extension of the trade of the country ;
meaning,
no doubt, by the extension of that trade, the extension of their
own
projects beyond what they could carry on either with their own capital,
or with
what they had credit to borrow of private people in the usual way of
bond or
mortgage. The banks, they seem to have thought, were in honour bound
to
supply the deficiency, and to provide them with all the capital which
they
wanted to trade with. The banks, however, were of a different opinion ;
and
upon their refusing to extend their credits, some of those traders had
recourse
to an expedient which, for a time, served their purpose, though at
a much
greater expense, yet as effectually as the utmost extension of bank
credits
could have done. This expedient was no other than the well known
shift
of drawing and redrawing; the shift to which unfortunate traders have
sometimes
recourse, when they are upon the brink of bankruptcy. The practice
of
raising money in this manner had been long known in England ; and, during
the
course of the late war, when the high profits of trade afforded a great
temptation
to over-trading, is said to have been carried on to a very great
extent.
From England it was brought into Scotland, where, in proportion to
the
very limited commerce, and to the very moderate capital of the country,
it was
soon carried on to a much greater extent than it ever had been in
England.
The
practice of drawing and redrawing is so well known to all men of
business,
that it may, perhaps, be thought unnecessary to give any account
of it.
But as this book may come into the hands of many people who are not
men of
business, and as the effects of this practice upon the banking trade
are
not, perhaps, generally understood, even by men of business themselves, I
shall
endeavour to explain it as distinctly as I can.
The customs of merchants, which were
established when the barbarous laws
of
Europe did not enforce the performance of their contracts, and which,
during
the course of the two last centuries, have been adopted into the laws
of all
European nations, have given such extraordinary privileges to bills
of
exchange, that money is more readily advanced upon them than upon any
other
species of obligation; especially when they are made payable within so
short a
period as two or three months after their date. If, when the bill
becomes
due, the acceptor does not pay it as soon as it is presented, he
becomes
from that moment a bankrupt. The bill is protested, and returns upon
the
drawer, who, if he does not immediately pay it, becomes likewise a
bankrupt.
If, before it came to the person who presents it to the acceptor
for
payment, it had passed through the hands of several other persons, who
had
successively advanced to one another the contents of it, either in money
or
goods, and who, to express that each of them had in his turn received
those
contents, had all of them in their order indorsed, that is, written
their
names upon the back of the bill; each indorser becomes in his turn
liable
to the owner of the bill for those contents, and, if he fails to pay,
he
becomes too, from that moment, a bankrupt. Though the drawer, acceptor,
and
indorsers of the bill, should all of them be persons of doubtful credit;
yet,
still the shortness of the date gives some security to the owner of the
bill.
Though all of them may be very likely to become bankrupts, it is a
chance
if they all become so in so short a time. The house is crazy, says a
weary
traveller to himself, and will not stand very long; but it is a chance
if it
falls to-night, and I will venture, therefore, to sleep in it
to-night.
The
trader A in Edinburgh, we shall suppose, draws a bill upon B in London,
payable
two months after date. In reality B in London owes nothing to A in
Edinburgh;
but he agrees to accept of A 's bill, upon condition, that before
the
term of payment he shall redraw upon A in Edinburgh for the same sum,
together
with the interest and a commission, another bill, payable likewise
two
months after date. B accordingly, before the expiration of the first two
months,
redraws this bill upon A in Edinburgh ; who, again before the
expiration
of the second two months, draws a second bill upon B in London,
payable
likewise two months after date; and before the expiration of the
third
two months, B in London redraws upon A in Edinburgh another bill
payable
also two months after date. This practice has sometimes gone on, not
only
for several months, but for several years together, the bill always
returning
upon A in Edinburgh with the accumulated interest and commission
of all
the former bills. The interest was five per cent. in the year, and
the
commission was never less than one half per cent. on each draught. This
commission
being repeated more than six times in the year, whatever money A
might
raise by this expedient might necessarily have cost him something more
than
eight per cent. in the year and sometimes a great deal more, when
either
the price of the commission happened to rise, or when he was obliged
to pay
compound interest upon the interest and commission of former bills.
This
practice was called raising money by circulation.
In a
country where the ordinary profits of stock, in the greater part of
mercantile
projects, are supposed to run between six and ten per cent. it
must
have been a very fortunate speculation, of which the returns could not
only
repay the enormous expense at which the money was thus borrowed for
carrying
it on, but afford, besides, a good surplus profit to the projector.
Many
vast and extensive projects, however, were undertaken, and for several
years
carried on, without any other fund to support them besides what was
raised
at this enormous expense. The projectors, no doubt, had in their
golden
dreams the most distinct vision of this great profit. Upon their
awakening,
however, either at the end of their projects, or when they were
no
longer able to carry them on, they very seldom, I believe, had the good
fortune
to find it .
{The
method described in the text was by no means either the most common or
the
most expensive one in which those adventurers sometimes raised money by
circulation.
It frequently happened, that A in Edinburgh would enable B in
London
to pay the first bill of exchange, by drawing, a few days before it
became
due, a second bill at three months date upon the same B in London.
This
bill, being payable to his own order, A sold in Edinburgh at par ; and
with
its contents purchased bills upon London, payable at sight to the order
of B,
to whom he sent them by the post. Towards the end of the late war, the
exchange
between Edinburgh and London was frequently three per cent. against
Edinburgh,
and those bills at sight must frequently have cost A that
premium.
This transaction, therefore, being repeated at least four times in
the
year, and being loaded with a commission of at least one half per cent.
upon
each repetition, must at that period have cost A, at least, fourteen
per
cent. in the year. At other times A would enable to discharge the first
bill of
exchange, by drawing, a few days before it became due, a second bill
at two
months date, not upon B, but upon some third person, C, for example,
in
London. This other bill was made payable to the order of B, who, upon its
being
accepted by C, discounted it with some banker in London ; and A
enabled
C to discharge it, by drawing, a few day's before it became due, a
third
bill likewise at two months date, sometimes upon his first
correspondent
B, and sometimes upon some fourth or fifth person, D or E, for
example.
This third bill was made payable to the order of C, who, as soon as
it was
accepted, discounted it in the same manner with some banker in
London.
Such operations being repeated at least six times in the year, and
being
loaded with a commission of at least one half per cent. upon each
repetition,
together with the legal interest of five per cent. this method
of
raising money, in the same manner as that described in the text, must
have
cost A something more than eight per cent. By saving, however, the
exchange
between Edinburgh and London, it was less expensive than that
mentioned
in the foregoing part of this note ; but then it required an
established
credit with more houses than one in London, an advantage which
many of
these adventurers could not always find it easy to procure.}
The
bills which A in Edinburgh drew upon B in London, he regularly
discounted
two months before they were due, with some bank or banker in
Edinburgh
; and the bills which B in London redrew upon A in Edinburgh, he
as
regularly discounted, either with the Bank of England, or with some other
banker
in London. Whatever was advanced upon such circulating bills was in
Edinburgh
advanced in the paper of the Scotch banks ; and in London, when
they
were discounted at the Bank of England in the paper of that bank.
Though
the bills upon which this paper had been advanced were all of them
repaid
in their turn as soon as they became due, yet the value which had
been
really advanced upon the first bill was never really returned to the
banks
which advanced it ; because, before each bill became due, another bill
was
always drawn to somewhat a greater amount than the bill which was soon
to be
paid: and the discounting of this other bill was essentially necessary
towards
the payment of that which was soon to be due. This payment,
therefore,
was altogether fictitious. The stream which, by means of those
circulating
bills of exchange, had once been made to run out from the
coffers
of the banks, was never replaced by any stream which really ran into
them.
The
paper which was issued upon those circulating bills of exchange
amounted,
upon many occasions, to the whole fund destined for carrying on
some
vast and extensive project of agriculture, commerce, or manufactures ;
and not
merely to that part of it which, had there been no paper money, the
projector
would have been obliged to keep by him unemployed, and in ready
money,
for answering occasional demands. The greater part of this paper was,
consequently,
over and above the value of the gold and silver which would
have
circulated in the country, had there been no paper money. It was over
and
above, therefore, what the circulation of the country could easily
absorb
and employ, and upon that account, immediately returned upon the
banks,
in order to be exchanged for gold and silver, which they were to find
as they
could. It was a capital which those projectors had very artfully
contrived
to draw from those banks, not only without their knowledge or
deliberate
consent, but for some time, perhaps, without their having the
most
distant suspicion that they had really advanced it.
When
two people, who are continually drawing and redrawing upon one another,
discount
their bills always with the same banker, he must immediately
discover
what they are about, and see clearly that they are trading, not
with
any capital of their own, but with the capital which he advances to
them.
But this discovery is not altogether so easy when they discount their
bills
sometimes with one banker, and sometimes with another, and when the
two
same persons do not constantly draw and redraw upon one another, but
occasionally
run the round of a great circle of projectors, who find it for
their
interest to assist one another in this method of raising money and to
render
it, upon that account, as difficult as possible to distinguish
between
a real and a fictitious bill of exchange, between a bill drawn by a
real
creditor upon a real debtor, and a bill for which there was properly no
real
creditor but the bank which discounted it, nor any real debtor but the
projector
who made use of the money. When a banker had even made this
discovery,
he might sometimes make it too late, and might find that he had
already
discounted the bills of those projectors to so great an extent,
that,
by refusing to discount any more, he would necessarily make them all
bankrupts
; and thus by ruining them, might perhaps ruin himself. For his
own
interest and safety, therefore, he might find it necessary, in this very
perilous
situation, to go on for some time, endeavouring, however, to
withdraw
gradually, and, upon that account, making every day greater and
greater
difficulties about discounting, in order to force these projectors
by
degrees to have recourse, either to other bankers, or to other methods of
raising
money : so as that he himself might, as soon as possible, get out of
the
circle. The difficulties, accordingly, which the Bank of England, which
the
principal bankers in London, and which even the more prudent Scotch
banks
began, after a certain time, and when all of them had already gone too
far, to
make about discounting, not only alarmed, but enraged, in the
highest
degree, those projectors. Their own distress, of which this prudent
and
necessary reserve of the banks was, no doubt, the immediate occasion,
they
called the distress of the country ; and this distress of the country,
they
said, was altogether owing to the ignorance, pusillanimity, and bad
conduct
of the banks, which did not give a sufficiently liberal aid to the
spirited
undertakings of those who exerted themselves in order to beautify,
improve,
and enrich the country. It was the duty of the banks, they seemed
to
think, to lend for as long a time, and to as great an extent, as they
might
wish to borrow. The banks, however,
by refusing in this manner to
give
more credit to those to whom they had already given a great deal too
much,
took the only method by which it was now possible to save either their
own credit,
or the public credit of the country.
In the
midst of this clamour and distress, a new bank was established in
Scotland,
for the express purpose of relieving the distress of the country.
The
design was generous ; but the execution was imprudent, and the nature
and
causes of the distress which it meant to relieve, were not, perhaps,
well
understood. This bank was more liberal than any other had ever been,
both in
granting cash-accounts, and in discounting bills of exchange. With
regard
to the latter, it seems to have made scarce any distinction between
real
and circulating bills, but to have discounted all equally. It was the
avowed
principle of this bank to advance upon any reasonable security, the
whole
capital which was to be employed in those improvements of which the
returns
are the most slow and distant, such as the improvements of land. To
promote
such improvements was even said to be the chief of the
public-spirited
purposes for which it was instituted. By its liberality in
granting
cash-accounts, and in discounting bills of exchange, it, no doubt,
issued
great quantities of its bank notes. But those bank notes being, the
greater
part of them, over and above what the circulation of the country
could
easily absorb and employ, returned upon it, in order to be exchanged
for
gold and silver, as fast as they were issued. Its coffers were never
well
filled. The capital which had been subscribed to this bank, at two
different
subscriptions, amounted to one hundred and sixty thousand pounds,
of
which eighty per cent. only was paid up. This sum ought to have been paid
in at
several different instalments. A great part of the proprietors, when
they
paid in their first instalment, opened a cash-account with the bank;
and the
directors, thinking themselves obliged to treat their own
proprietors
with the same liberality with which they treated all other men,
allowed
many of them to borrow upon this cash-account what they paid in upon
all
their subsequent instalments. Such payments, therefore, only put into
one
coffer what had the moment before been taken out of another. But had the
coffers
of this bank been filled ever so well, its excessive circulation
must
have emptied them faster than they could have been replenished by any
other
expedient but the ruinous one of drawing upon London; and when the
bill
became due, paying it, together with interest and commission, by
another
draught upon the same place. Its coffers having been filled so very
ill, it
is said to have been driven to this resource within a very few
months
after it began to do business. The estates of the proprietors of this
bank
were worth several millions, and, by their subscription to the original
bond or
contract of the bank, were really pledged for answering all its
engagements.
By means of the great credit which so great a pledge
necessarily
gave it, it was, notwithstanding its too liberal conduct,
enabled
to carry on business for more than two years. When it was obliged to
stop,
it had in the circulation about two hundred thousand pounds in bank
notes.
In order to support the circulation of those notes, which were
continually
returning upon it as fast as they were issued, it had been
constantly
in the practice of drawing bills of exchange upon London, of
which
the number and value were continually increasing, and. when it stopt,
amounted
to upwards of six hundred thousand pounds. This bank, therefore,
had, in
little more than the course of two years, advanced to different
people
upwards of eight hundred thousand pounds at five per cent. Upon the
two
hundred thousand pounds which it circulated in bank notes, this five per
cent.
might perhaps be considered as a clear gain, without any other
deduction
besides the expense of management. But upon upwards of six hundred
thousand
pounds, for which it was continually drawing bills of exchange upon
London,
it was paying, in the way of interest and commission, upwards of
eight
per cent. and was consequently losing more than three per cent. upon
more
than three fourths of all its dealings.
The
operations of this bank seem to have produced effects quite opposite to
those
which were intended by the particular persons who planned and directed
it.
They seem to have intended to support the spirited undertakings, for as
such
they considered them, which were at that time carrying on in different
parts
of the country ; and, at the same time, by drawing the whole banking
business
to themselves, to supplant all the other Scotch banks, particularly
those
established at Edinburgh, whose backwardness in discounting bills of
exchange
had given some offence. This bank, no doubt, gave some temporary
relief
to those projectors, and enabled them to carry on their projects for
about
two years longer than they could otherwise have done. But it thereby
only
enabled them to get so much deeper into debt ; so that, when ruin came,
it fell
so much the heavier both upon them and upon their creditors. The
operations
of this bank, therefore, instead of relieving, in reality
aggravated
in the long-run the distress which those projectors had brought
both
upon themselves and upon their country. It would have been much better
for
themselves, their creditors, and their country, had the greater part of
them
been obliged to stop two years sooner than they actually did. The
temporary
relief, however, which this bank afforded to those projectors,
proved
a real and permanent relief to the other Scotch banks. All the
dealers
in circulating bills of exchange, which those other banks had become
so
backward in discounting, had recourse to this new bank, where they were
received
with open arms. Those other banks, therefore, were enabled to get
very
easily out of that fatal circle, from which they could not otherwise
have
disengaged themselves without incurring a considerable loss, and
perhaps,
too, even some degree of discredit.
In the
long-run, therefore, the operations of this bank increased the real
distress
of the country, which it meant to relieve ; and effectually
relieved,
from a very great distress, those rivals whom it meant to
supplant.
At the
first setting out of this bank, it was the opinion of some people,
that
how fast soever its coffers might be emptied, it might easily replenish
them,
by raising money upon the securities of those to whom it had advanced
its
paper. Experience, I believe, soon convinced them that this method of
raising
money was by much too slow to answer their purpose; and that coffers
which
originally were so ill filled, and which emptied themselves so very
fast,
could be replenished by no other expedient but the ruinous one of
drawing
bills upon London, and when they became due, paying them by other
draughts
on the same place, with accumulated interest and commission. But
though
they had been able by this method to raise money as fast as they
wanted
it, yet, instead of making a profit, they must have suffered a loss
of
every such operation ; so that in the long-run they must have ruined
themselves
as a mercantile company, though perhaps not so soon as by the
more
expensive practice of drawing and redrawing. They could still have made
nothing
by the interest of the paper, which, being over and above what the
circulation
of the country could absorb and employ, returned upon them in
order
to be exchanged for gold and silver, as fast as they issued it ; and
for the
payment of which they were themselves continually obliged to borrow
money.
On the contrary, the whole expense of this borrowing, of employing
agents
to look out for people who had money to lend, of negotiating with
those
people, and of drawing the proper bond or assignment, must have fallen
upon
them, and have been so much clear loss upon the balance of their
accounts.
The project of replenishing their coffers in this manner may be
compared
to that of a man who had a water-pond from which a stream was
continually
running out, and into which no stream was continually running,
but who
proposed to keep it always equally full, by employing a number of
people
to go continually with buckets to a well at some miles distance, in
order
to bring water to replenish it.
But
though this operation had proved not only practicable, but profitable to
the
bank, as a mercantile company; yet the country could have derived no
benefit
front it, but, on the contrary, must have suffered a very
considerable
loss by it. This operation could not augment, in the smallest
degree,
the quantity of money to be lent. It could only have erected this
bank
into a sort of general loan office for the whole country. Those who
wanted
to borrow must have applied to this bank, instead of applying to the
private
persons who had lent it their money. But a bank which lends money,
perhaps
to five hundred different people, the greater part of whom its
directors
can know very little about, is not likely to be more judicious in
the
choice of its debtors than a private person who lends out his money
among a
few people whom he knows, and in whose sober and frugal conduct he
thinks
he has good reason to confide. The debtors of such a bank as that
whose
conduct I have been giving some account of were likely, the greater
part of
them, to be chimerical projectors, the drawers and redrawers of
circulating
bills of exchange, who would employ the money in extravagant
undertakings,
which, with all the assistance that could be given them, they
would
probably never be able to complete, and which, if they should be
completed,
would never repay the expense which they had really cost, would
never
afford a fund capable of maintaining a quantity of labour equal to
that
which had been employed about them. The sober and frugal debtors of
private
persons, on the contrary, would be more likely to employ the money
borrowed
in sober undertakings which were proportioned to their capitals,
and
which, though they might have less of the grand and the marvellous,
would
have more of the solid and the profitable ; which would repay with a
large
profit whatever had been laid out upon them, and which would thus
afford
a fund capable of maintaining a much greater quantity of labour than
that
which had been employed about them. The success of this operation,
therefore,
without increasing in the smallest degree the capital of the
country,
would only have transferred a great part of it from prudent and
profitable
to imprudent and unprofitable undertakings.
That
the industry of Scotland languished for want of money to employ it, was
the
opinion of the famous Mr Law. By establishing a bank of a particular
kind,
which he seems to have imagined might issue paper to the amount of the
whole
value of all the lands in the country, he proposed to remedy this want
of
money. The parliament of Scotland, when he first proposed his project,
did not
think proper to adopt it. It was afterwards adopted, with some
variations,
by the Duke of Orleans, at that time regent of France. The idea
of the
possibility of multiplying paper money to almost any extent was the
real
foundation of what is called the Mississippi scheme, the most
extravagant
project, both of banking and stock-jobbing, that perhaps the
world
ever saw. The different operations of this scheme are explained so
fully,
so clearly, and with so much order and distinctness, by Mr Du Verney,
in his
Examination of the Political Reflections upon commerce and finances
of Mr
Du Tot, that I shall not give any account of them. The principles upon
which
it was founded are explained by Mr Law himself, in a discourse
concerning
money and trade, which he published in Scotland when he first
proposed
his project. The splendid but visionary ideas which are set forth
in that
and some other works upon the same principles, still continue to
make an
impression upon many people, and have, perhaps, in part, contributed
to that
excess of banking, which has of late been complained of, both in
Scotland
and in other places.
The
Bank of England is the greatest bank of circulation in Europe. It was
incorporated,
in pursuance of an act of parliament, by a charter under the
great
seal, dated the 27th of July 1694. It at that time advanced to
government
the sum of £1,200,000 for an annuity of £100,000, or for £
96,000
a-year, interest at the rate of eight per cent. and £4,000 year for
the
expense of management. The credit of the new government, established by
the
Revolution, we may believe, must have been very low, when it was obliged
to
borrow at so high an interest.
In
1697, the bank was allowed to enlarge its capital stock, by an
ingraftment
of £1,001,171:10s. Its whole capital stock, therefore, amounted
at this
time to £2,201,171: 10s. This ingraftment is said to have been for
the
support of public credit. In 1696, tallies had been at forty, and fifty,
and
sixty. per cent. discount, and bank notes at twenty per cent. {James
Postlethwaite's
History of the Public Revenue, p.301.} During the great
re-coinage
of the silver, which was going on at this time, the bank had
thought
proper to discontinue the payment of its notes, which necessarily
occasioned
their discredit.
In pursuance of the 7th Anne, c. 7, the bank
advanced and paid into the
exchequer
the sum of £400,000; making in all the sum of £1,600,000, which
it had
advanced upon its original annuity of £96,000 interest, and £4,000
for
expense of management. In 1708, therefore, the credit of government was
as good
as that of private persons, since it could borrow at six per cent.
interest,
the common legal and market rate of those times. In pursuance of
the
same act, the bank cancelled exchequer bills to the amount of £
1,775,027:
17s: 10½d. at six per cent. interest, and was at the same time
allowed
to take in subscriptions for doubling its capital. In 1703,
therefore,
the capital of the bank amounted to £4,402,343 ; and it had
advanced
to government the sum of £3,375,027:17:10½d.
By a
call of fifteen per cent. in 1709, there was paid in, and made stock, £
656,204:1:9d.;
and by another of ten per cent. in 1710, £501,448:12:11d. In
consequence
of those two calls, therefore, the bank capital amounted to £
5,559,995:14:8d.
In
pursuance of the 3rd George I. c.8, the bank delivered up two millions of
exchequer
Bills to be cancelled. It had at this time, therefore, advanced to
government
£5,375,027:17 10d. In pursuance of the 8th George I. c.21, the
bank
purchased of the South-sea company, stock to the amount of £4,000,000:
and in
1722, in consequence of the subscriptions which it had taken in for
enabling
it to make this purchase, its capital stock was increased by £
3,400,000.
At this time, therefore, the bank had advanced to the public £
9,375,027
17s. 10½d.; and its capital stock amounted only to £
8,959,995:14:8d.
It was upon this occasion that the sum which the bank had
advanced
to the public, and for which it received interest, began first to
exceed
its capital stock, or the sum for which it paid a dividend to the
proprietors
of bank stock ; or, in other words, that the bank began to have
an
undivided capital, over and above its divided one. It has continued to
have an
undivided capital of the same kind ever since. In 1746, the bank
had,
upon different occasions, advanced to the public £11,686,800, and its
divided
capital had been raised by different calls and subscriptions to £
10,780,000.
The state of those two sums has continued to be the same ever
since.
In pursuance of the 4th of George III. c.25, the bank agreed to pay
to
government for the renewal of its charter £110,000, without interest or
re-payment.
This sum, therefore did not increase either of those two other
sums.
The dividend
of the bank has varied according to the variations in the rate
of the
interest which it has, at different times, received for the money it
had
advanced to the public, as well as according to other circumstances.
This
rate of interest has gradually been reduced from eight to three per
cent.
For some years past, the bank dividend has been at five and a half per
cent.
The
stability of the bank of England is equal to that of the British
government.
All that it has advanced to the public must be lost before its
creditors
can sustain any loss. No other banking company in England can be
established
by act of parliament, or can consist of more than six members.
It
acts, not only as an ordinary bank, but as a great engine of state. It
receives
and pays the greater part of the annuities which are due to the
creditors
of the public ; it circulates exchequer bills ; and it advances to
government
the annual amount of the land and malt taxes, which are
frequently
not paid up till some years thereafter. In these different
operations,
its duty to the public may sometimes have obliged it, without
any
fault of its directors, to overstock the circulation with paper money.
It
likewise discounts merchants' bills, and has, upon several different
occasions,
supported the credit of the principal houses, not only of
England,
but of Hamburgh and Holland. Upon one occasion, in 1763, it is said
to have
advanced for this purpose, in one week, about £1,600,000, a great
part of
it in bullion. I do not, however, pretend to warrant either the
greatness
of the sum, or the shortness of the time. Upon other occasions,
this
great company has been reduced to the necessity of paying in sixpences.
It is
not by augmenting the capital of the country, but by rendering a
greater
part of that capital active and productive than would otherwise be
so,
that the most judicious operations of banking can increase the industry
of the
country. That part of his capital which a dealer is obliged to keep
by him
unemployed and in ready money, for answering occasional demands, is
so much
dead stock, which, so long as it remains in this situation, produces
nothing,
either to him or to his country. The judicious operations of
banking
enable him to convert this dead stock into active and productive
stock ;
into materials to work upon ; into tools to work with ; and into
provisions
and subsistence to work for ; into stock which produces something
both to
himself and to his country. The gold and silver money which
circulates
in any country, and by means of which, the produce of its land
and
labour is annually circulated and distributed to the proper consumers,
is, in
the same manner as the ready money of the dealer, all dead stock. It
is a
very valuable part of the capital of the country, which produces
nothing
to the country. The judicious operations of banking, by substituting
paper
in the room of a great part of this gold and silver, enable the
country
to convert a great part of this dead stock into active and
productive
stock; into stock which produces something to the country. The
gold
and silver money which circulates in any country may very properly be
compared
to a highway, which, while it circulates and carries to market all
the
grass and corn of the country, produces itself not a single pile of
either.
The judicious operations of banking, by providing, if I may be
allowed
so violent a metaphor, a sort of waggon-way through the air, enable
the
country to convert, as it were, a great part of its highways into good
pastures,
and corn fields, and thereby to increase, very considerably, the
annual
produce of its land and labour. The commerce and industry of the
country,
however, it must be acknowledged, though they may be somewhat
augmented,
cannot be altogether so secure, when they are thus, as it were,
suspended
upon the Daedalian wings of paper money, as when they travel about
upon
the solid ground of gold and silver. Over and above the accidents to
which
they are exposed from the unskilfulness of the conductors of this
paper
money, they are liable to several others, from which no prudence or
skill
of those conductors can guard them.
An
unsuccessful war, for example, in which the enemy got possession of the
capital,
and consequently of that treasure which supported the credit of the
paper
money, would occasion a much greater confusion in a country where the
whole
circulation was carried on by paper, than in one where the greater
part of
it was carried on by gold and silver. The usual instrument of
commerce
having lost its value, no exchanges could be made but either by
barter
or upon credit. All taxes having been usually paid in paper money,
the
prince would not have wherewithal either to pay his troops, or to
furnish
his magazines; and the state of the country would be much more
irretrievable
than if the greater part of its circulation had consisted in
gold
and silver. A prince, anxious to maintain his dominions at all times in
the
state in which he can most easily defend them, ought upon this account
to
guard not only against that excessive multiplication of paper money which
ruins
the very banks which issue it, but even against that multiplication of
it
which enables them to fill the greater part of the circulation of the
country
with it.
The
circulation of every country may be considered as divided into two
different
branches; the circulation of the dealers with one another, and the
circulation
between the dealers and the consumers. Though the same pieces of
money,
whether paper or metal, may be employed sometimes in the one
circulation
and sometimes in the other; yet as both are constantly going on
at the
same time, each requires a certain stock of money, of one kind or
another,
to carry it on. The value of the goods circulated between the
different
dealers never can exceed the value of those circulated between the
dealers
and the consumers ; whatever is bought by the dealers being
ultimately
destined to be sold to the consumers. The circulation between the
dealers,
as it is carried on by wholesale, requires generally a pretty large
sum for
every particular transaction. That between the dealers and the
consumers,
on the contrary, as it is generally carried on by retail,
frequently
requires but very small ones, a shilling, or even a halfpenny,
being
often sufficient. But small sums circulate much faster than large
ones. A
shilling changes masters more frequently than a guinea, and a
halfpenny
more frequently than a shilling. Though the annual purchases of
all the
consumers, therefore, are at least equal in value to those of all
the
dealers, they can generally be transacted with a much smaller quantity
of
money ; the same pieces, by a more rapid circulation, serving as the
instrument
of many more purchases of the one kind than of the other.
Paper
money may be so regulated as either to confine itself very much to the
circulation
between the different dealers, or to extend itself likewise to a
great
part of that between the dealers and the consumers. Where no bank
notes are
circulated under £10 value, as in London, paper money confines
itself
very much to the circulation between the dealers. When a ten pound
bank
note comes into the hands of a consumer, he is generally obliged to
change
it at the first shop where he has occasion to purchase five shillings
worth
of goods; so that it often returns into the hands of a dealer before
the
consumer has spent the fortieth part of the money. Where bank notes are
issued
for so small sums as 20s. as in Scotland, paper money extends itself
to a
considerable part of the circulation between dealers and consumers.
Before
the Act of parliament which put a stop to the circulation of ten and
five
shilling notes, it filled a still greater part of that circulation. In
the
currencies of North America, paper was commonly issued for so small a
sum as
a shilling, and filled almost the whole of that circulation. In some
paper
currencies of Yorkshire, it was issued even for so small a sum as a
sixpence.
Where
the issuing of bank notes for such very small sums is allowed, and
commonly
practised, many mean people are both enabled and encouraged to
become
bankers. A person whose promissory note for £5, or even for 20s.
would
be rejected by every body, will get it to be received without scruple
when it
is issued for so small a sum as a sixpence. But the frequent
bankruptcies
to which such beggarly bankers must be liable, may occasion a
very
considerable inconveniency, and sometimes even a very great calamity,
to many
poor people who had received their notes in payment.
It were
better, perhaps, that no bank notes were issued in any part of the
kingdom
for a smaller sum than £5. Paper money would then, probably, confine
itself,
in every part of the kingdom, to the circulation between the
different
dealers, as much as it does at present in London, where no bank
notes
are issued under £10 value ; £5 being, in most part of the kingdom,
a sum
which, though it will purchase, perhaps, little more than half the
quantity
of goods, is as much considered, and is as seldom spent all at
once,
as £10 are amidst the profuse expense of London.
Where
paper money, it is to be observed, is pretty much confined to the
circulation
between dealers and dealers, as at London, there is always
plenty
of gold and silver. Where it extends itself to a considerable part of
the
circulation between dealers and consumers, as in Scotland, and still
more in
North America, it banishes gold and silver almost entirely from the
country
; almost all the ordinary transactions of its interior commerce
being
thus carried on by paper. The suppression of ten and five shilling
bank
notes, somewhat relieved the scarcity of gold and. silver in Scotland;
and the
suppression of twenty shilling notes will probably relieve it still
more.
Those metals are said to have become more abundant in America, since
the
suppression of some of their paper currencies. They are said, likewise,
to have
been more abundant before the institution of those currencies.
Though
paper money should be pretty much confined to the circulation between
dealers
and dealers, yet banks and bankers might still be able to give
nearly
the same assistance to the industry and commerce of the country, as
they
had done when paper money filled almost the whole circulation. The
ready
money which a dealer is obliged to keep by him, for answering
occasional
demands, is destined altogether for the circulation between
himself
and other dealers of whom he buys goods. He has no occasion to keep
any by
him for the circulation between himself and the consumers, who are
his
customers, and who bring ready money to him, instead of taking any from
him.
Though no paper money, therefore, was allowed to be issued, but for
such
sums as would confine it pretty much to the circulation between dealers
and
dealers; yet partly by discounting real bills of exchange, and partly by
lending
upon cash-accounts, banks and bankers might still be able to relieve
the
greater part of those dealers from the necessity of keeping any
considerable
part of their stock by them unemployed, and in ready money, for
answering
occasional demands. They might still be able to give the utmost
assistance
which banks and bankers can with propriety give to traders of
every
kind.
To restrain
private people, it may be said, from receiving in payment the
promissory
notes of a banker for any sum, whether great or small, when they
themselves
are willing to receive them; or, to restrain a banker from
issuing
such notes, when all his neighbours are willing to accept of them,
is a
manifest violation of that natural liberty, which it is the proper
business
of law not to infringe, but to support. Such regulations may, no
doubt,
be considered as in some respect a violation of natural liberty. But
those
exertions of the natural liberty of a few individuals, which might
endanger
the security of the whole society, are, and ought to be, restrained
by the
laws of all governments ; of the most free, as well as or the most
despotical.
The obligation of building party walls, in order to prevent the
communication
of fire, is a violation of natural liberty, exactly of the
same
kind with the regulations of the banking trade which are here proposed.
A paper
money, consisting in bank notes, issued by people of undoubted
credit,
payable upon demand, without any condition, and, in fact, always
readily
paid as soon as presented, is, in every respect, equal in value to
gold
and silver money, since gold and silver money can at anytime be had for
it. Whatever
is either bought or sold for such paper, must necessarily be
bought
or sold as cheap as it could have been for gold and silver.
The
increase of paper money, it has been said, by augmenting the quantity,
and
consequently diminishing the value, of the whole currency, necessarily
augments
the money price of commodities. But as the quantity of gold and
silver,
which is taken from the currency, is always equal to the quantity of
paper
which is added to it, paper money does not necessarily increase the
quantity
of the whole currency. From the beginning of the last century to
the
present time, provisions never were cheaper in Scotland than in 1759,
though,
from the circulation of ten and five shilling bank notes, there was
then
more paper money in the country than at present. The proportion
between
the price of provisions in Scotland and that in England is the same
now as
before the great multiplication of banking companies in Scotland.
Corn
is, upon most occasions, fully as cheap in England as in France, though
there
is a great deal of paper money in England, and scarce any in France.
In 1751
and 1752, when Mr Hume published his Political Discourses, and soon
after
the great multiplication of paper money in Scotland, there was a very
sensible
rise in the price of provisions, owing, probably, to the badness of
the
seasons, and not to the multiplication of paper money.
It
would be otherwise, indeed, with a paper money, consisting in promissory
notes,
of which the immediate payment depended, in any respect, either upon
the
good will of those who issued them, or upon a condition which the holder
of the
notes might not always have it in his power to fulfil, or of which
the
payment was not exigible till after a certain number of years, and
which,
in the mean time, bore no interest. Such a paper money would, no
doubt,
fall more or less below the value of gold and silver, according as
the
difficulty or uncertainty of obtaining immediate payment was supposed to
be
greater or less, or according to the greater or less distance of time at
which
payment was exigible.
Some
years ago the different banking companies of Scotland were in the
practice
of inserting into their bank notes, what they called an optional
clause;
by which they promised payment to the bearer, either as soon as the
note
should be presented, or, in the option of the directors, six months
after
such presentment, together with the legal interest for the said six
months.
The directors of some of those banks sometimes took advantage of
this
optional clause, and sometimes threatened those who demanded gold and
silver
in exchange for a considerable number of their notes, that they would
take
advantage of it, unless such demanders would content themselves with a
part of
what they demanded. The promissory notes of those banking companies
constituted,
at that time, the far greater part of the currency of Scotland,
which
this uncertainty of payment necessarily degraded below value of gold
and
silver money. During the continuance of this abuse (which prevailed
chiefly
in 1762, 1763, and 1764), while the exchange between London and
Carlisle
was at par, that between London and Dumfries would sometimes be
four
per cent. against Dumfries, though this town is not thirty miles
distant
from Carlisle. But at Carlisle,
bills were paid in gold and
silver
; whereas at Dumfries they were paid in Scotch bank notes ; and the
uncertainty
of getting these bank notes exchanged for gold and silver coin,
had
thus degraded them four per cent. below the value of that coin. The same
act of
parliament which suppressed ten and five shilling bank notes,
suppressed
likewise this optional clause, and thereby restored the exchange
between
England and Scotland to its natural rate, or to what the course of
trade
and remittances might happen to make it.
In the
paper currencies of Yorkshire, the payment of so small a sum as 6d.
sometimes
depended upon the condition, that the holder of the note should
bring
the change of a guinea to the person who issued it; a condition which
the
holders of such notes might frequently find it very difficult to fulfil,
and
which must have degraded this currency below the value of gold and
silver
money. An act of parliament, accordingly, declared all such clauses
unlawful,
and suppressed, in the same manner as in Scotland, all promissory
notes,
payable to the bearer, under 20s. value.
The
paper currencies of North America consisted, not in bank notes payable
to the
bearer on demand, but in a government paper, of which the payment was
not
exigible till several years after it was issued ; and though the colony
governments
paid no interest to the holders of this paper, they declared it
to be,
and in fact rendered it, a legal tender of payment for the full value
for
which it was issued. But allowing the colony security to be perfectly
good,
£100, payable fifteen years hence, for example, in a country where
interest
is at six per cent., is worth little more than £40 ready money. ,
To
oblige a creditor, therefore, to accept of this as full payment for a
debt of
£100, actually paid down in ready money, was an act of such violent
injustice,
as has scarce, perhaps, been attempted by the government of any
other
country which pretended to be free. It bears the evident marks of
having
originally been, what the honest and downright Doctor Douglas assures
us it
was, a scheme of fraudulent debtors to cheat their creditors. The
government
of Pennsylvania, indeed, pretended, upon their first emission of
paper money,
in 1722, to render their paper of equal value with gold and
silver,
by enacting penalties against all those who made any difference in
the
price of their goods when they sold them for a colony paper, and when
they
sold them for gold and silver, a regulation equally tyrannical, but
much
less, effectual, than that which it was meant to support. A positive
law may
render a shilling a legal tender for a guinea, because it may direct
the
courts of justice to discharge the debtor who has made that tender ; but
no
positive law can oblige a person who sells goods, and who is at liberty
to sell
or not to sell as he pleases, to accept of a shilling as equivalent
to a
guinea in the price of them. Notwithstanding any regulation of this
kind,
it appeared, by the course of exchange with Great Britain, that £100
sterling
was occasionally considered as equivalent, in some of the colonies,
to
£130, and in others to so great a sum as £1100 currency ; this difference
in the
value arising from the difference in the quantity of paper emitted in
the
different colonies, and in the distance and probability of the term of
its
final discharge and redemption.
No law,
therefore, could be more equitable than the act of parliament, so
unjustly
complained of in the colonies, which declared, that no paper
currency
to be emitted there in time coming, should be a legal tender of
payment.
Pennsylvania
was always more moderate in its emissions of paper money than
any
other of our colonies. Its paper currency, accordingly, is said never to
have
sunk below the value of the gold and silver which was current in the
colony
before the first emission of its paper money. Before that emission,
the
colony had raised the denomination of its coin, and had, by act of
assembly,
ordered 5s. sterling to pass in the colonies for 6s:3d., and
afterwards
for 6s:8d. A pound, colony currency, therefore, even when that
currency
was gold and silver, was more than thirty per cent. below the value
of £1
sterling; and when that currency was turned into paper, it was seldom
much
more than thirty per cent. below that value. The pretence for raising
the
denomination of the coin was to prevent the exportation of gold and
silver,
by making equal quantities of those metals pass for greater sums in
the
colony than they did in the mother country. It was found, however, that
the
price of all goods from the mother country rose exactly in proportion as
they
raised the denomination of their coin, so that their gold and silver
were
exported as fast as ever.
The
paper of each colony being received in the payment of the provincial
taxes,
for the full value for which it had been issued, it necessarily
derived
from this use some additional value, over and above what it would
have
had, from the real or supposed distance of the term of its final
discharge
and redemption. This additional value was greater or less,
according
as the quantity of paper issued was more or less above what could
be
employed in the payment of the taxes of the particular colony which
issued
it. It was in all the colonies very much above what could be employed
in this
manner.
A
prince, who should enact that a certain proportion of his taxes should be
paid in
a paper money of a certain kind, might thereby . give a certain
value
to this paper money, even though the term of its final discharge and
redemption
should depend altogether upon the will of the prince. If the bank
which
issued this paper was careful to keep the quantity of it always
somewhat
below what could easily be employed in this manner, the demand for
it
might be such as to make it even bear a premium, or sell for somewhat more
in the
market than the quantity of gold or silver currency for which it
was
issued. Some people account in this manner for what is called the agio
of the
bank of Amsterdam, or for the superiority of bank money over
current
money, though this bank money, as they pretend, cannot be taken
out of
the bank at the will of the owner. The greater part of foreign bills
of
exchange must be paid in bank money, that is, by a transfer in the
books
of the bank ; and the directors of the bank, they allege, are
careful
to keep the whole quantity of bank money always below what this
use
occasions a demand for. It is upon this account, they say, the bank
money
sells for a premium, or bears an agio of four or five per cent. above
the
same nominal sum of the gold and silver currency of the country. This
account
of the bank of Amsterdam, however, it will appear hereafter, is in a
great
measure chimerical.
A paper
currency which falls below the value of gold and silver coin, does
not
thereby sink the value of those metals, or occasion equal quantities of
them to
exchange for a smaller quantity of goods of any other kind. The
proportion
between the value of gold and silver and that of goods of any
other
kind, depends in all cases, not upon the nature and quantity of any
particular
paper money, which may be current in any particular country, but
upon
the richness or poverty of the mines, which happen at any particular
time to
supply the great market of the commercial world with those metals.
It
depends upon the proportion between the quantity of labour which is
necessary
in order to bring a certain quantity of gold and silver to market,
and
that which is necessary in order to bring thither a certain quantity of
any
other sort of goods.
If
bankers are restrained from issuing any circulating bank notes, or notes
payable
to the bearer, for less than a certain sum; and if they are
subjected
to the obligation of an immediate and unconditional payment of
such
bank notes as soon as presented, their trade may, with safety to the
public,
be rendered in all other respects perfectly free. The late
multiplication
of banking companies in both parts of the united kingdom, an
event
by which many people have been much alarmed, instead of diminishing,
increases
the security of the public. It obliges all of them to be more
circumspect
in their conduct, and, by not extending their currency beyond
its due
proportion to their cash, to guard themselves against those
malicious
runs, which the rivalship of so many competitors is always ready
to
bring upon them. It restrains the circulation of each particular company
within
a narrower circle, and reduces their circulating notes to a smaller
number.
By dividing the whole circulation into a greater number of parts,
the
failure of any one company, an accident which, in the course of things,
must
sometimes happen, becomes of less consequence to the public. This free
competition,
too, obliges all bankers to be more liberal in their dealings
with
their customers, lest their rivals should carry them away. In general,
if any
branch of trade, or any division of labour, be advantageous to the
public,
the freer and more general the competition, it will always be the
more
so.
CHAPTER III.
OF THE
ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL, OR OF
PRODUCTIVE
AND UNPRODUCTIVE LABOUR.
There
is one sort of labour which adds to the value of the subject upon
which
it is bestowed ; there is another which has no such effect. The former
as it
produces a value, may be called productive, the latter, unproductive
labour.
{ Some French authors of great learning and ingenuity have used
those
words in a different sense. In the last chapter of the fourth book, I
shall
endeavour to shew that their sense is an improper one.} Thus the labour
of a
manufacturer adds generally to the value of the materials which he
works
upon, that of his own maintenance, and of his master's profit. The
labour
of a menial servant, on the contrary, adds to the value of nothing.
Though
the manufacturer has his wages advanced to him by his master, he in
reality
costs him no expense, the value of those wages being generally
restored,
together with a profit, in the improved value of the subject upon
which
his labour is bestowed. But the maintenance of a menial servant never
is
restored. A man grows rich by employing a multitude of manufacturers ;
he
grows poor by maintaining a multitude or menial servants. The labour of
the
latter, however, has its value, and deserves its reward as well as that
of the
former. But the labour of the manufacturer fixes and realizes itself
in some
particular subject or vendible commodity, which lasts for some time
at
least after that labour is past. It is, as it were, a certain quantity of
labour
stocked and stored up, to be employed, if necessary, upon some other
occasion.
That subject, or, what is the same thing, the price of that
subject,
can afterwards, if necessary, put into motion a quantity of labour
equal
to that which had originally produced it. The labour of the menial
servant,
on the contrary, does not fix or realize itself in any particular
subject
or vendible commodity. His services generally perish in the very
instant
of their performance, and seldom leave any trace of value behind
them,
for which an equal quantity of service could afterwards be procured.
The labour of some of the most respectable
orders in the society is, like
that of
menial servants, unproductive of any value, and does not fix or
realize
itself in any permanent subject, or vendible commodity, which
endures
after that labour is past, and for which an equal quantity of labour
could
afterwards be procured. The sovereign, for example, with all the
officers
both of justice and war who serve under him, the whole army and
navy,
are unproductive labourers. They are the servants of the public, and
are
maintained by a part of the annual produce of the industry of other
people.
Their service, how honourable, how useful, or how necessary soever,
produces
nothing for which an equal quantity of service can afterwards be
procured.
The protection, security, and defence, of the commonwealth, the
effect
of their labour this year, will not purchase its protection,
security,
and defence, for the year to come. In the same class must be
ranked,
some both of the gravest and most important, and some of the most
frivolous
professions; churchmen, lawyers, physicians, men of letters of all
kinds ;
players, buffoons, musicians, opera-singers, opera-dancers, etc.
The
labour of the meanest of these has a certain value, regulated by the
very
same principles which regulate that of every other sort of labour; and
that of
the noblest and most useful, produces nothing which could afterwards
purchase
or procure an equal quantity of labour. Like the declamation of the
actor,
the harangue of the orator, or the tune of the musician, the work of
all of
them perishes in the very instant of its production.
Both
productive and unproductive labourers, and those who do not labour at
all,
are all equally maintained by the annual produce of the land and labour
of the
country. This produce, how great soever, can never be infinite, but
must have
certain limits. According, therefore, as a smaller or greater
proportion
of it is in any one year employed in maintaining unproductive
hands,
the more in the one case, and the less in the other, will remain for
the
productive, and the next year's produce will be greater or smaller
accordingly
; the whole annual produce, if we except the spontaneous
productions
of the earth, being the effect of productive labour.
Though
the whole annual produce of the land and labour of every country is
no
doubt ultimately destined for supplying the consumption of its
inhabitants,
and for procuring a revenue to them; yet when it first comes
either
from the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, it
naturally
divides itself into two parts. One of them, and frequently the
largest,
is, in the first place, destined for replacing a capital, or for
renewing
the provisions, materials, and finished work, which had been
withdrawn
from a capital ; the other for constituting a revenue either to
the
owner of this capital, as the profit of his stock, or to some other
person,
as the rent of his land. Thus, of the produce of land, one part
replaces
the capital of the farmer ; the other pays his profit and the rent
of the
landlord ; and thus constitutes a revenue both to the owner of this
capital,
as the profits of his stock, and to some other person as the rent
of his
land. Of the produce of a great manufactory, in the same manner, one
part,
and that always the largest, replaces the capital of the undertaker of
the
work ; the other pays his profit, and thus constitutes a revenue to the
owner
of this capital.
That
part of the annual produce of the land and labour of any country which
replaces
a capital, never is immediately employed to maintain any but
productive
hands. It pays the wages of productive labour only. That which is
immediately
destined for constituting a revenue, either as profit or as
rent,
may maintain indifferently either productive or unproductive hands.
Whatever
part of his stock a man employs as a capital, he always expects it
to be
replaced to him with a profit. He employs it, therefore, in
maintaining
productive hands only ; and after having served in the function
of a
capital to him, it constitutes a revenue to them. Whenever he employs
any
part of it in maintaining unproductive hands of any kind, that part is
from
that moment withdrawn from his capital, and placed in his stock
reserved
for immediate consumption.
Unproductive
labourers, and those who do not labour at all, are all
maintained
by revenue; either, first, by that part of the annual produce
which
is originally destined for constituting a revenue to some particular
persons,
either as the rent of land, or as the profits of stock ; or,
secondly,
by that part which, though originally destined for replacing a
capital,
and for maintaining productive labourers only, yet when it comes
into
their hands, whatever part of it is over and above their necessary
subsistence,
may be employed in maintaining indifferently either productive
or
unproductive hands. Thus, not only the great landlord or the rich
merchant,
but even the common workman, if his wages are considerable, may
maintain
a menial servant; or he may sometimes go to a play or a
puppet-show,
and so contribute his share towards maintaining one set of
unproductive
labourers; or he may pay some taxes, and thus help to maintain
another
set, more honourable and useful, indeed, but equally unproductive.
No part
of the annual produce, however, which had been originally destined
to
replace a capital, is ever directed towards maintaining unproductive
hands,
till after it has put into motion its full complement of productive
labour,
or all that it could put into motion in the way in which it was
employed.
The workman must have earned his wages by work done, before he can
employ
any part of them in this manner. That part, too, is generally but a
small
one. It is his spare revenue only, of which productive labourers have
seldom
a great deal. They generally have some, however ; and in the payment
of
taxes, the greatness of their number may compensate, in some measure, the
smallness
of their contribution. The rent of land and the profits of stock
are
everywhere, therefore, the principal sources from which unproductive
hands
derive their subsistence. These are the two sorts of revenue of which
the
owners have generally most to spare. They might both maintain
indifferently,
either productive or unproductive hands. They seem, however,
to have
some predilection for the latter. The expense of a great lord feeds
generally
more idle than industrious people The rich merchant, though with
his
capital he maintains industrious people only, yet by his expense, that
is, by
the employment of his revenue, he feeds commonly the very same sort
as the
great lord.
The
proportion, therefore, between the productive and unproductive hands,
depends
very much in every country upon the proportion between that part of
the
annual produce, which, as soon as it comes either from the ground, or
from
the hands of the productive labourers, is destined for replacing a
capital,
and that which is destined for constituting a revenue, either as
rent or
as profit. This proportion is very different in rich from what it is
in poor
countries.
Thus,
at present, in the opulent countries of Europe, a very large,
frequently
the largest, portion of the produce of the land, is destined for
replacing
the capital of the rich and independent farmer ; the other for
paying
his profits, and the rent of the landlord. But anciently, during the
prevalency
of the feudal government, a very small portion of the produce was
sufficient
to replace the capital employed in cultivation. It consisted
commonly
in a few wretched cattle, maintained altogether by the spontaneous
produce
of uncultivated land, and which might, therefore, be considered as a
part of
that spontaneous produce. It generally, too, belonged to the
landlord,
and was by him advanced to the occupiers of the land. All the rest
of the
produce properly belonged to him too, either as rent for his land, or
as
profit upon this paltry capital. The occupiers of land were generally
bond-men,
whose persons and effects were equally his property. Those who were
not
bond-men were tenants at will; and though the rent which they paid was
often
nominally little more than a quit-rent, it really amounted to the
whole
produce of the land. Their lord could at all times command their
labour
in peace and their service in war. Though they lived at a distance
from
his house, they were equally dependent upon him as his retainers who
lived
in it. But the whole produce of the land undoubtedly belongs to him,
who can
dispose of the labour and service of all those whom it maintains. In
the
present state of Europe, the share of the landlord seldom exceeds a
third,
sometimes not a fourth part of the whole produce of the land. The
rent of
land, however, in all the improved parts of the country, has been
tripled
and quadrupled since those ancient times; and this third or fourth
part of
the annual produce is, it seems, three or four times greater than
the
whole had been before. In the progress of improvement, rent, though it
increases
in proportion to the extent, diminishes in proportion to the
produce
of the land.
In the
opulent countries of Europe, great capitals are at present employed
in
trade and manufactures. In the ancient state, the little trade that was
stirring,
and the few homely and coarse manufactures that were carried on,
required
but very small capitals. These, however, must have yielded very
large
profits. The rate of interest was nowhere less than ten per cent. and
their
profits must have been sufficient to afford this great interest. At
present,
the rate of interest, in the improved parts of Europe, is nowhere
higher
than six per cent.; and in some of the most improved, it is so low as
four,
three, and two per cent. Though that part of the revenue of the
inhabitants
which is derived from the profits of stock, is always much
greater
in rich than in poor countries, it is because the stock is much
greater
; in proportion to the stock, the profits are generally much less.
That
part of the annual produce, therefore, which, as soon as it comes
either
from the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, is
destined
for replacing a capital, is not only much greater in rich than in
poor
countries, but bears a much greater proportion to that which is
immediately
destined for constituting a revenue either as rent or as profit.
The
funds destined for the maintenance of productive labour are not only
much
greater in the former than in the latter, but bear a much greater
proportion
to those which, though they may be employed to maintain either
productive
or unproductive hands, have generally a predilection for the
latter.
The
proportion between those different funds necessarily determines in every
country
the general character of the inhabitants as to industry or idleness.
We are
more industrious than our forefathers, because, in the present times,
the
funds destined for the maintenance of industry are much greater in
proportion
to those which are likely to be employed in the maintenance of
idleness,
than they were two or three centuries ago. Our ancestors were idle
for
want of a sufficient encouragement to industry. It is better, says the
proverb,
to play for nothing, than to work for nothing. In mercantile
and
manufacturing towns, where the inferior ranks of people are chiefly
maintained
by the employment of capital, they are in general industrious,
sober,
and thriving; as in many English, and in most Dutch towns. In those
towns
which are principally supported by the constant or occasional
residence
of a court, and in which the inferior ranks of people are chiefly
maintained
by the spending of revenue, they are in general idle, dissolute,
and
poor; as at Rome, Versailles, Compeigne, and Fontainbleau. If you except
Rouen
and Bourdeaux, there is little trade or industry in any of the
parliament
towns of France; and the inferior ranks of people, being chiefly
maintained
by the expense of the members of the courts of justice, and of
those
who come to plead before them, are in general idle and poor. The great
trade
of Rouen and Bourdeaux seems to be altogether the effect of their
situation.
Rouen is necessarily the entrepot of almost all the goods which
are
brought either from foreign countries, or from the maritime provinces of
France,
for the consumption of the great city of Paris. Bourdeaux is, in the
same
manner, the entrepot of the wines which grow upon the banks of the
Garronne,
and of the rivers which run into it, one of the richest wine
countries
in the world, and which seems to produce the wine fittest for
exportation,
or best suited to the taste of foreign nations. Such
advantageous
situations necessarily attract a great capital by the great
employment
which they afford it ; and the employment of this capital is the
cause
of the industry of those two cities.
In the other parliament towns
of
France, very little more capital seems to be employed than what is
necessary
for supplying their own consumption; that is, little more than the
smallest
capital which can be employed in them. The same thing may be said
of
Paris, Madrid, and Vienna. Of those three cities, Paris is by far the
most
industrious, but Paris itself is the principal market of all the
manufactures
established at Paris, and its own consumption is the principal
object
of all the trade which it carries on. London, Lisbon, and Copenhagen,
are,
perhaps, the only three cities in Europe, which are both the constant
residence
of a court, and can at the same time be considered as trading
cities,
or as cities which trade not only for their own consumption, but for
that of
other cities and countries. The situation of all the three is
extremely
advantageous, and naturally fits them to be the entrepots of a
great
part of the goods destined for the consumption of distant places. In a
city
where a great revenue is spent, to employ with advantage a capital for
any
other purpose than for supplying the consumption of that city, is
probably
more difficult than in one in which the inferior ranks of people
have no
other maintenance but what they derive from the employment of such a
capital.
The idleness of the greater part of the people who are maintained
by the
expense of revenue, corrupts, it is probable, the industry of those
who
ought to be maintained by the employment of capital, and renders it less
advantageous
to employ a capital there than in other places. There was
little
trade or industry in Edinburgh before the Union. When the Scotch
parliament
was no longer to be assembled in it, when it ceased to be the
necessary
residence of the principal nobility and gentry of Scotland, it
became
a city of some trade and industry. It still continues, however, to
be the
residence of the principal courts of justice in Scotland, of the
boards
of customs and excise, etc. A considerable revenue, therefore, still
continues
to be spent in it. In trade and industry, it is much inferior to
Glasgow,
of which the inhabitants are chiefly maintained by the employment
of
capital. The inhabitants of a large village, it has sometimes been
observed,
after having made considerable progress in manufactures, have
become
idle and poor, in consequence of a great lord's having taken up his
residence
in their neighbourhood.
The
proportion between capital and revenue, therefore, seems everywhere to
regulate
the proportion between industry and idleness Wherever capital
predominates,
industry prevails ; wherever revenue, idleness. Every increase
or
diminution of capital, therefore, naturally tends to increase or diminish
the
real quantity of industry, the number of productive hands, and
consequently
the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the land and
labour
of the country, the real wealth and revenue of all its inhabitants.
Capitals
are increased by parsimony, and diminished by prodigality and
misconduct.
Whatever
a person saves from his revenue he adds to his capital, and either
employs
it himself in maintaining an additional number of productive hands,
or
enables some other person to do so, by lending it to him for an interest,
that
is, for a share of the profits. As the capital of an individual can be
increased
only by what he saves from his annual revenue or his annual gains,
so the
capital of a society, which is the same with that of all the
individuals
who compose it, can be increased only in the same manner.
Parsimony,
and not industry, is the immediate cause of the increase of
capital.
Industry, indeed, provides the subject which parsimony accumulates;
but
whatever industry might acquire, if parsimony did not save and store up,
the
capital would never be the greater.
Parsimony,
by increasing the fund which is destined for the maintenance of
productive
hands, tends to increase the number of those hands whose labour
adds to
the value of the subject upon winch it is bestowed. It tends,
therefore,
to increase the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the
land
and labour of the country. It puts into motion an additional quantity
of
industry, which gives an additional value to the annual produce.
What is
annually saved, is as regularly consumed as what is annually spent,
and
nearly in the same time too : but it is consumed by a different set of
people.
That portion of his revenue which a rich man annually spends, is, in
most
cases, consumed by idle guests and menial servants, who leave nothing
behind
them in return for their consumption. That portion which he annually
saves,
as, for the sake of the profit, it is immediately employed as a
capital,
is consumed in the same manner, and nearly in the same time too,
but by
a different set of people: by labourers, manufacturers, and
artificers,
who reproduce, with a profit, the value of their annual
consumption.
His revenue, we shall suppose, is paid him in money. Had he
spent
the whole, the food, clothing, and lodging, which the whole could have
purchased,
would have been distributed among the former set of people. By
saving
a part of it, as that part is, for the sake of the profit,
immediately
employed as a capital, either by himself or by some other
person,
the food, clothing, and lodging, which may be purchased with it, are
necessarily
reserved for the latter. The consumption is the same, but the
consumers
are different.
By what
a frugal man annually saves, he not only affords maintenance to an
additional
number of productive hands, for that of the ensuing year, but
like
the founder of a public work-house he establishes, as it were, a
perpetual
fund for the maintenance of an equal number in all times to come.
The
perpetual allotment and destination of this fund, indeed, is not always
guarded
by any positive law, by any trust-right or deed of mortmain. It is
always
guarded, however, by a very powerful principle, the plain and evident
interest
of every individual to whom any share of it shall ever belong. No
part of
it can ever afterwards be employed to maintain any but productive
hands,
without an evident loss to the person who thus perverts it from its
proper
destination.
The
prodigal perverts it in this manner: By not confining his expense within
his
income, he encroaches upon his capital. Like him who perverts the
revenues
of some pious foundation to profane purposes, he pays the wages of
idleness
with those funds which the frugality of his forefathers had, as it
were,
consecrated to the maintenance of industry. By diminishing the funds
destined
for the employment of productive labour, he necessarily diminishes,
so far
as it depends upon him, the quantity of that labour which adds a
value
to the subject upon which it is bestowed, and, consequently, the value
of the
annual produce of the land and labour of the whole country, the real
wealth
and revenue of its inhabitants. If the prodigality of some were not
compensated
by the frugality of others, the conduct of every prodigal, by
feeding
the idle with the bread of the industrious, would tend not only to
beggar
himself, but to impoverish his country.
Though
the expense of the prodigal should be altogether in home made, and no
part of
it in foreign commodities, its effect upon the productive funds of
the
society would still be the same. Every year there would still be a
certain
quantity of food and clothing, which ought to have maintained
productive,
employed in maintaining unproductive hands. Every year,
therefore,
there would still be some diminution in what would otherwise have
been
the value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the country.
This
expense, it may be said, indeed, not being in foreign goods, and not
occasioning
any exportation of gold and silver, the same quantity of money
would
remain in the country as before. But if the quantity of food and
clothing
which were thus consumed by unproductive, had been distributed
among
productive hands, they would have reproduced, together with a profit,
the
full value of their consumption. The same quantity of money would, in
this
case, equally have remained in the country, and there would, besides,
have
been a reproduction of an equal value of consumable goods. There would
have
been two values instead of one.
The
same quantity of money, besides, can. not long remain in any country in
which
the value of the annual produce diminishes. The sole use of money is
to
circulate consumable goods. By means of it, provisions, materials, and
finished
work, are bought and sold, and distributed to their proper
consumers.
The quantity of money, therefore, which can be annually employed
in any
country, must be determined by the value of the consumable goods
annually
circulated within it. These must consist, either in the immediate
produce
of the land and labour of the country itself, or in something which
had
been purchased with some part of that produce. Their value, therefore,
must
diminish as the value of that produce diminishes, and along with it the
quantity
of money which can be employed in circulating them. But the money
which,
by this annual diminution of produce, is annually thrown out of
domestic
circulation, will not be allowed to lie idle. The interest of
whoever
possesses it requires that it should be employed; but having no
employment
at home, it will, in spite of all laws and prohibitions, be sent
abroad,
and employed in purchasing consumable goods, which may be of some
use at
home. Its annual exportation will, in this manner, continue for some
time to
add something to the annual consumption of the country beyond the
value
of its own annual produce. What in the days of its prosperity had been
saved
from that annual produce, and employed in purchasing gold and silver.
will
contribute, for some little time, to support its consumption in
adversity.
The exportation of gold and silver is, in this case, not the
cause,
but the effect of its declension, and may even, for some little time,
alleviate
the misery of that declension.
The
quantity of money, on the contrary, must in every country naturally
increase
as the value of the annual produce increases. The value of the
consumable
goods annually circulated within the society being greater, will
require
a greater quantity of money to circulate them. A part of the
increased
produce, therefore, will naturally be employed in purchasing,
wherever
it is to be had, the additional quantity of gold and silver
necessary
for circulating the rest. The increase of those metals will, in
this
case, be the effect, not the cause, of the public prosperity. Gold and
silver
are purchased everywhere in the same manner. The food, clothing, and
lodging,
the revenue and maintenance, of all those whose labour or stock is
employed
in bringing them from the mine to the market, is the price paid for
them in
Peru as well as in England. The country which has this price to pay,
will
never belong without the quantity of those metals which it has occasion
for;
and no country will ever long retain a quantity which it has no
occasion
for.
Whatever,
therefore, we may imagine the real wealth and revenue of a country
to
consist in, whether in the value of the annual produce of its land and
labour,
as plain reason seems to dictate, or in the quantity of the precious
metals
which circulate within it, as vulgar prejudices suppose ; in either
view of
the matter, every prodigal appears to be a public enemy, and every
frugal
man a public benefactor.
The
effects of misconduct are often the same as those of prodigality. Every
injudicious
and unsuccessful project in agriculture, mines, fisheries,
trade,
or manufactures, tends in the same manner to diminish the funds
destined
for the maintenance of productive labour. In every such project,
though
the capital is consumed by productive hands only, yet as, by the
injudicious
manner in which they are employed, they do not reproduce the
full
value of their consumption, there must always be some diminution in
what
would otherwise have been the productive funds of the society.
It can
seldom happen, indeed, that the circumstances of a great nation can
be much
affected either by the prodigality or misconduct of individuals; the
profusion
or imprudence of some being always more than compensated by the
frugality
and good conduct of others.
With
regard to profusion, the principle which prompts to expense is the
passion
for present enjoyment; which, though sometimes violent and very
difficult
to be restrained, is in general only momentary and occasional. But
the
principle which prompts to save, is the desire of bettering our condition; a
desire
which,
though generally calm and dispassionate, comes with us from the womb,
and
never leaves us till we go into the grave. In the whole interval which
separates
those two moments, there is scarce, perhaps, a single instance, in
which
any man is so perfectly and completely satisfied with his situation,
as to
be without any wish of alteration or improvement of any kind. An
augmentation
of fortune is the means by which the greater part of men
propose
and wish to better their condition. It is the means the most vulgar
and the
most obvious; and the most likely way of augmenting their fortune,
is to
save and accumulate some part of what they acquire, either regularly
and
annually, or upon some extraordinary occasion. Though the principle
of
expense, therefore, prevails in almost all men upon some occasions, and in
some
men upon almost all occasions ; yet in the greater part of men, taking
the
whole course of their life at an average, the principle of frugality
seems
not only to predominate, but to predominate very greatly.
With
regard to misconduct, the number of prudent and successful undertakings
is
everywhere much greater than that of injudicious and unsuccessful ones.
After
all our complaints of the frequency of bankruptcies, the unhappy men
who
fall into this misfortune, make but a very small part of the whole
number
engaged in trade, and all other sorts of business; not much more,
perhaps,
than one in a thousand. Bankruptcy is, perhaps, the greatest and
most
humiliating calamity which can befal an innocent man. The greater part
of men,
therefore, are sufficiently careful to avoid it. Some, indeed, do
not
avoid it; as some do not avoid the gallows.
Great
nations are never impoverished by private, though they sometimes are
by
public prodigality and misconduct. The whole, or almost the whole public
revenue
is, in most countries, employed in maintaining unproductive hands.
Such
are the people who compose a numerous and splendid court, a great
ecclesiastical
establishment, great fleets and armies, who in time of peace
produce
nothing, and in time of war acquire nothing which can compensate the
expense
of maintaining them, even while the war lasts. Such people, as they
themselves
produce nothing, are all maintained by the produce of other men's
labour.
When multiplied, therefore, to an unnecessary number, they may in a
particular
year consume so great a share of this produce, as not to leave a
sufficiency
for maintaining the productive labourers, who should reproduce
it next
year. The next year's produce, therefore, will be less than that of
the
foregoing ; and if the same disorder should continue, that of the third
year
will be still less than that of the second. Those unproductive hands
who
should be maintained by a part only of the spare revenue of the people,
may
consume so great a share of their whole revenue, and thereby oblige so
great a
number to encroach upon their capitals, upon the funds destined for
the
maintenance of productive labour, that all the frugality and good
conduct
of individuals may not be able to compensate the waste and
degradation
of produce occasioned by this violent and forced encroachment.
This
frugality and good conduct, however, is, upon most occasions, it
appears
from experience, sufficient to compensate, not only the private
prodigality
and misconduct of individuals, but the public extravagance of
government.
The uniform, constant, and uninterrupted effort of every man to
better
his condition, the principle from which public and national, as well
as
private opulence is originally derived,is frequently powerful enough to
maintain
the natural progress of things towards improvement, in spite both
of the
extravagance of government, and of the greatest errors of
administration.
Like the unknown principle of animal life, it frequently
restores
health and vigour to the constitution, in spite not only of the
disease,
but of the absurd prescriptions of the doctor.
The
annual produce of the land and labour of any nation can be increased in
its
value by no other means, but by increasing either the number of its
productive
labourers, or the productive powers of those labourers who had
before
been employed. The number of its productive labourers, it is evident,
can
never be much increased, but in consequence of an increase of capital,
or of
the funds destined for maintaining them. The productive powers of the
same
number of labourers cannot be increased, but in consequence either of
some
addition and improvement to those machines and instruments which
facilitate
and abridge labour, or of more proper division and distribution
of
employment. In either case, an additional capital is almost always
required.
It is by means of an additional capital only, that the undertaker
of any
work can either provide his workmen with better machinery, or make a
more
proper distribution of employment among them. When the work to be done
consists
of a number of parts, to keep every man constantly employed in one
way,
requires a much greater capital than where every man is occasionally
employed
in every different part of the work. When we compare, therefore,
the
state of a nation at two different periods, and find that the annual
produce
of its land and labour is evidently greater at the latter than at
the
former, that its lands are better cultivated, its manufactures more
numerous
and more flourishing, and its trade more extensive; we may be
assured
that its capital must have increased during the interval between
those
two periods, and that more must have been added to it by the good
conduct
of some, than had been taken from it either by the private
misconduct
of others, or by the public extravagance of government. But we
shall
find this to have been the case of almost all nations, in all
tolerably
quiet and peaceable times, even of those who have not enjoyed the
most
prudent and parsimonious governments. To form a right judgment of it,
indeed,
we must compare the state of the country at periods somewhat distant
from
one another. The progress is frequently so gradual, that, at near
periods,
the improvement is not only not sensible, but, from the declension
either
of certain branches of industry, or of certain districts of the
country,
things which sometimes happen, though the country in general is in
great
prosperity, there frequently arises a suspicion, that the riches and
industry
of the whole are decaying.
The
annual produce of the land and labour of England, for example, is
certainly
much greater than it was a little more than a century ago, at the
restoration
of Charles II. Though at present few people, I believe, doubt of
this,
yet during this period five years have seldom passed away, in which
some
book or pamphlet has not been published, written, too, with such
abilities
as to gain some authority with the public, and pretending to
demonstrate
that the wealth of the nation was fast declining; that the
country
was depopulated, agriculture neglected, manufactures decaying, and
trade
undone. Nor have these publications been all party pamphlets, the
wretched
offspring of falsehood and venality. Many of them have been written
by very
candid and very intelligent people, who wrote nothing but what they
believed,
and for no other reason but because they believed it.
The
annual produce of the land and labour of England, again, was certainly
much
greater at the Restoration than we can suppose it to have been about a
hundred
years before, at the accession of Elizabeth. At this period, too, we
have
all reason to believe, the country was much more advanced in
improvement,
than it had been about a century before, towards the close of
the
dissensions between the houses of York and Lancaster. Even then it was,
probably,
in a better condition than it had been at the Norman conquest: and
at the
Norman conquest, than during the confusion of the Saxon heptarchy.
Even at
this early period, it was certainly a more improved country than at
the
invasion of Julius Caesar, when its inhabitants were nearly in the same
state
with the savages in North America.
In each
of those periods, however, there was not only much private and
public
profusion, many expensive and unnecessary wars, great perversion of
the
annual produce from maintaining productive to maintain unproductive
hands;
but sometimes, in the confusion of civil discord, such absolute waste
and
destruction of stock, as might be supposed, not only to retard, as it
certainly
did, the natural accumulation of riches, but to have left the
country,
at the end of the period, poorer than at the beginning. Thus, in
the
happiest and most fortunate period of them all, that which has passed
since
the Restoration, how many disorders and misfortunes have occurred,
which,
could they have been foreseen, not only the impoverishment, but the
total
ruin of the country would have been expected from them ? The fire and
the
plague of London, the two Dutch wars, the disorders of the revolution,
the war
in Ireland, the four expensive French wars of 1688, 1701, 1742, and
1756,
together with the two rebellions of 1715 and 1745. In the course of
the
four French wars, the nation has contracted more than £145,000,000 of
debt,
over and above all the other extraordinary annual expense which they
occasioned
; so that the whole cannot be computed at less than £200,000,000.
So
great a share of the annual produce of the land and labour of the
country,
has, since the Revolution, been employed upon different occasions,
in
maintaining an extraordinary number of unproductive hands. But had not
those
wars given this particular direction to so large a capital, the
greater
part of it would naturally have been employed in maintaining
productive
hands, whose labour would have replaced, with a profit, the whole
value
of their consumption. The value of the annual produce of the land and
labour
of the country would have been considerably increased by it every
year,
and every years increase would have augmented still more that of the
following
year. More houses would have been built, more lands would have
been
improved, and those which had been improved before would have been
better
cultivated; more manufactures would have been established, and those
which
had been established before would have been more extended ; and to
what
height the real wealth and revenue of the country might by this time
have
been raised, it is not perhaps very easy even to imagine.
But
though the profusion of government must undoubtedly have retarded the
natural
progress of England towards wealth and improvement, it has not been
able to
stop it. The annual produce of its land and labour is undoubtedly
much
greater at present than it was either at the Restoration or at the
Revolution.
The capital, therefore, annually employed in cultivating this
land,
and in maintaining this labour, must likewise be much greater. In the
midst
of all the exactions of government, this capital has been silently and
gradually
accumulated by the private frugality and good conduct of
individuals,
by their universal, continual, and uninterrupted effort to
better
their own condition. It is this effort, protected by law, and allowed
by
liberty to exert itself in the manner that is most advantageous, which
has
maintained the progress of England towards opulence and improvement in
almost
all former times, and which, it is to be hoped, will do so in all
future
times. England, however, as it has never been blessed with a very
parsimonious
government, so parsimony has at no time been the characteristic
virtue
of its inhabitants. It is the highest impertinence and presumption,
therefore,
in kings and ministers to pretend to watch over the economy of
private
people, and to restrain their expense, either by sumptuary laws, or
by
prohibiting the importation of foreign luxuries. They are themselves
always,
and without any exception, the greatest spendthrifts in the society.
Let
them look well after their own expense, and they may safely trust
private
people with theirs. If their own extravagance does not ruin the
state.
that of the subject never will.
As
frugality increases, and prodigality diminishes, the public capital, so
the
conduct of those whose expense just equals their revenue, without either
accumulating
or encroaching, neither increases nor diminishes it. Some modes
of
expense, however, seem to contribute more to the growth of public
opulence
than others.
The
revenue of an individual may be spent, either in things which are
consumed
immediately, and in which one day's expense can neither alleviate
nor
support that of another ; or it may be spent in things mere durable,
which
can therefore be accumulated, and in which every day's expense may, as
he
chooses, either alleviate, or support and heighten, the effect of that of
the
following day. A man of fortune, for example, may either spend his
revenue
in a profuse and sumptuous table, and in maintaining a great number
of
menial servants, and a multitude of dogs and horses; or, contenting
himself
with a frugal table, and few attendants, he may lay out the greater
part of
it in adorning his house or his country villa, in useful or
ornamental
buildings, in useful or ornamental furniture, in collecting
books,
statues, pictures ; or in things more frivolous, jewels, baubles,
ingenious
trinkets of different kinds; or, what is most trifling of all, in
amassing
a great wardrobe of fine clothes, like the favourite and minister
of a
great prince who died a few years ago. Were two men of equal fortune to
spend
their revenue, the one chiefly in the one way, the other in the other,
the
magnificence of the person whose expense had been chiefly in durable
commodities,
would be continually increasing, every day's expense
contributing
something to support and heighten the effect of that of the
following
day ; that of the other, on the contrary, would be no greater at
the end
of the period than at the beginning. The former too would, at the
end of
the period, be the richer man of the two. He would have a stock of
goods
of some kind or other, which, though it might not be worth all that it
cost,
would always be worth something. No trace or vestige of the expense of
the
latter would remain, and the effects of ten or twenty years' profusion
would
be as completely annihilated as if they had never existed.
As the
one mode of expense is more favourable than the other to the opulence
of an
individual, so is it likewise to that of a nation. The houses, the
furniture,
the clothing of the rich, in a little time, become useful to the
inferior
and middling ranks of people. They are able to purchase them when
their
superiors grow weary of them ; and the general accommodation of the
whole
people is thus gradually improved, when this mode of expense becomes
universal
among men of fortune. In countries which have long been rich, you
will
frequently find the inferior ranks of people in possession both of
houses
and furniture perfectly good and entire, but of which neither the one
could
have been built, nor the other have been made for their use. What was
formerly
a seat of the family of Seymour, is now an inn upon the Bath road.
The
marriage-bed of James I. of Great Britain, which his queen brought with
her
from Denmark, as a present fit for a sovereign to make to a sovereign,
was, a
few years ago, the ornament of an alehouse at Dunfermline. In some
ancient
cities, which either have been long stationary, or have gone
somewhat
to decay, you will sometimes scarce find a single house which could
have
been built for its present inhabitants. If you go into those houses,
too,
you will frequently find many excellent, though antiquated pieces of
furniture,
which are still very fit for use, and which could as little have
been
made for them. Noble palaces, magnificent villas, great collections of
books, statues,
pictures, and other curiosities, are frequently both an
ornament
and an honour, not only to the neighbourhood, but to the whole
country
to which they belong. Versailles is an ornament and an honour to
France,
Stowe and Wilton to England. Italy still continues to command some
sort of
veneration, by the number of monuments of this kind which it
possesses,
though the wealth which produced them has decayed, and though the
genius
which planned them seems to be extinguished, perhaps from not having
the
same employment.
The
expense, too, which is laid out in durable commodities, is favourable
not
only to accumulation, but to frugality. If a person should at any time
exceed
in it, he can easily reform without exposing himself to the censure
of the
public. To reduce very much the number of his servants, to reform his
table
from great profusion to great frugality, to lay down his equipage
after
he has once set it up, are changes which cannot escape the observation
of his
neighbours, and which are supposed to imply some acknowledgment of
preceding
bad conduct. Few, therefore, of those who have once been so
unfortunate
as to launch out too far into this sort of expense, have
afterwards
the courage to reform, till ruin and bankruptcy oblige them. But
if a
person has, at any time, been at too great an expense in building, in
furniture,
in books, or pictures, no imprudence can be inferred from his
changing
his conduct. These are things in which further expense is
frequently
rendered unnecessary by former expense; and when a person stops
short,
he appears to do so, not because he has exceeded his fortune, but
because
he has satisfied his fancy.
The
expense, besides, that is laid out in durable commodities, gives
maintenance,
commonly, to a greater number of people than that which is
employed
in the most profuse hospitality. Of two or three hundred weight of
provisions,
which may sometimes be served up at a great festival, one half,
perhaps,
is thrown to the dunghill, and there is always a great deal wasted
and
abused. But if the expense of this entertainment had been employed in
setting
to work masons, carpenters, upholsterers, mechanics, etc. a quantity
of
provisions of equal value would have been distributed among a still
greater
number of people, who would have bought them in pennyworths and
pound
weights, and not have lost or thrown away a single ounce of them. In
the one
way, besides, this expense maintains productive, in the other
unproductive
hands. In the one way, therefore, it increases, in the other it
does
not increase the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the land
and
labour of the country.
I would
not, however, by all this, be understood to mean, that the one
species
of expense always betokens a more liberal or generous spirit than
the
other. When a man of fortune spends his revenue chiefly in hospitality,
he
shares the greater part of it with his friends and companions; but when
he
employs it in purchasing such durable commodities, he often spends the
whole
upon his own person, and gives nothing to any body without an
equivalent.
The latter species of expense, therefore, especially when
directed
towards frivolous objects, the little ornaments of dress and
furniture,
jewels, trinkets, gew-gaws, frequently indicates, not only a
trifling,
but a base and selfish disposition. All that I mean is, that the
one
sort of expense, as it always occasions some accumulation of valuable
commodities,
as it is more favourable to private frugality, and,
consequently,
to the increase of the public capital, and as it maintains
productive
rather than unproductive hands, conduces more than the other to
the
growth of public opulence.
CHAPTER IV.
OF
STOCK LENT AT INTEREST.
The
stock which is lent at interest is always considered as a capital by the
lender.
He expects that in due time it is to be restored to him, and that,
in the
mean time, the borrower is to pay him a certain annual rent for the
use of
it. The borrower may use it either as a capital, or as a stock
reserved
for immediate consumption. If he uses it as a capital, he employs
it in
the maintenance of productive labourers, who reproduce the value, with
a
profit. He can, in this case, both restore the capital, and pay the
interest,
without alienating or encroaching upon any other source of
revenue.
If he uses it as a stock reserved for immediate consumption, he
acts
the part of a prodigal, and dissipates, in the maintenance of the idle,
what
was destined for the support of the industrious. He can, in this case,
neither
restore the capital nor pay the interest, without either alienating
or
encroaching upon some other source of revenue, such as the property or
the
rent of land.
The
stock which is lent at interest is, no doubt, occasionally employed in
both
these ways, but in the former much more frequently than in the latter.
The man
who borrows in order to spend will soon be ruined, and he who lends
to him
will generally have occasion to repent of his folly. To borrow or to
lend for
such a purpose, therefore, is, in all cases, where gross usury is
out of
the question, contrary to the interest of both parties; and though it
no
doubt happens sometimes, that people do both the one and the other, yet,
from
the regard that all men have for their own interest, we may be assured,
that it
cannot happen so very frequently as we are sometimes apt to imagine.
Ask any
rich man of common prudence, to which of the two sorts of people he
has
lent the greater part of his stock, to those who he thinks will employ
it
profitably, or to those who will spend it idly, and he will laugh at you
for
proposing the question. Even among borrowers, therefore, not the people
in the
world most famous for frugality, the number of the frugal and
industrious
surpasses considerably that of the prodigal and idle.
The
only people to whom stock is commonly lent, without their being expected
to make
any very profitable use of it, are country gentlemen, who borrow
upon
mortgage. Even they scarce ever borrow merely to spend. What they
borrow,
one may say, is commonly spent before they borrow it. They have
generally
consumed so great a quantity of goods, advanced to them upon
credit
by shop-keepers and tradesmen, that they find it necessary to borrow
at interest,
in order to pay the debt. The capital borrowed replaces the
capitals
of those shop-keepers and tradesmen which the country gentlemen
could
not have replaced from the rents of their estates. It is not properly
borrowed
in order to be spent, but in order to replace a capital which had
been
spent before.
Almost
all loans at interest are made in money, either of paper, or of gold
and
silver ; but what the borrower really wants, and what the lender readily
supplies
him with, is not the money, but the money's worth, or the goods
which
it can purchase. If he wants it as a stock for immediate consumption,
it is
those goods only which he can place in that stock. If he wants it as a
capital
for employing industry, it is from those goods only that the
industrious
can be furnished with the tools, materials, and maintenance
necessary
for carrying on their work. By means of the loan, the lender, as
it
were, assigns to the borrower his right to a certain portion of the
annual
produce of the land and labour of the country, to be employed as the
borrower
pleases.
The
quantity of stock, therefore, or, as it is commonly expressed, of money,
which
can be lent at interest in any country, is not regulated by the value
of the
money, whether paper or coin, which serves as the instrument of the
different
loans made in that country, but by the value of that part of the
annual
produce, which, as soon as it comes either from the ground, or from
the
hands of the productive labourers, is destined, not only for replacing a
capital,
but such a capital as the owner does not care to be at the trouble
of
employing himself. As such capitals are commonly lent out and paid back
in
money, they constitute what is called the monied interest. It is
distinct,
not only from the landed, but from the trading and manufacturing
interests,
as in these last the owners themselves employ their own capitals.
Even in
the monied interest, however, the money is, as it were, but the deed
of
assignment, which conveys from one hand to another those capitals which
the
owners do not care to employ themselves. Those capitals may be greater,
in
almost any proportion, than the amount of the money which serves as the
instrument
of their conveyance; the same pieces of money successively
serving
for many different loans, as well as for many different purchases.
A, for
example, lends to W £1000, with which W immediately purchases of B
£1000
worth of goods. B having no occasion for the money himself, lends the
identical
pieces to X, with which X immediately purchases of C another £1000
worth
of goods. C, in the same manner, and for the same reason, lends them
to Y,
who again purchases goods with them of D. In this manner, the same
pieces,
either of coin or of paper, may, in the course of a few days, serve
as the
Instrument of three different loans, and of three different
purchases,
each of which is, in value, equal to the whole amount of those
pieces.
What the three monied men, A, B, and C, assigned to the three
borrowers,
W, X, and Y, is the power of making those purchases. In this
power
consist both the value and the use of the loans. The stock lent by the
three
monied men is equal to the value of the goods which can be purchased
with
it, and is three times greater than that of the money with which the
purchases
are made. Those loans, however, may be all perfectly well secured,
the
goods purchased by the different debtors being so employed as, in due
time,
to bring back, with a profit, an equal value either of coin or of
paper.
And as the same pieces of money can thus serve as the instrument of
different
loans to three, or, for the same reason, to thirty times their
value,
so they may likewise successively serve as the instrument of
repayment.
A
capital lent at interest may, in this manner, be considered as an
assignment,
from the lender to the borrower, of a certain considerable
portion
of the annual produce, upon condition that the burrower in return
shall,
during the continuance of the loan, annually assign to the lender a
small
portion, called the interest ; and, at the end of it, a portion
equally
considerable with that which had originally been assigned to him,
called
the repayment. Though money, either coin or paper, serves generally
as the
deed of assignment, both to the smaller and to the more considerable
portion,
it is itself altogether different from what is assigned by it.
In
proportion as that share of the annual produce which, as soon as it comes
either
from the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, is
destined
for replacing a capital, increases in any country, what is called
the
monied interest naturally increases with it. The increase of those
particular
capitals from which the owners wish to derive a revenue, without
being at
the trouble of employing them themselves, naturally accompanies the
general
increase of capitals ; or, in other words, as stock increases, the
quantity
of stock to be lent at interest grows gradually greater and
greater.
As the
quantity of stock to be lent at interest increases, the interest, or
the
price which must be paid for the use of that stock, necessarily
diminishes,
not only from those general causes which make the market price
of
things commonly diminish as their quantity increases, but from other
causes
which are peculiar to this particular case. As capitals increase in
any
country, the profits which can be made by employing them necessarily
diminish.
It becomes gradually more and more difficult to find within the
country
a profitable method of employing any new capital. There arises, in
consequence,
a competition between different capitals, the owner of one
endeavouring
to get possession of that employment which is occupied by
another;
but, upon most occasions, he can hope to justle that other out of
this
employment by no other means but by dealing upon more reasonable terms.
He must
not only sell what he deals in somewhat cheaper, but, in order to
get it
to sell, he must sometimes, too, buy it dearer. The demand for
productive
labour, by the increase of the funds which are destined for
maintaining
it, grows every day greater and greater. Labourers easily find
employment;
but the owners of capitals find it difficult to get labourers to
employ.
Their competition raises the wages of labour, and sinks the profits
of
stock. But when the profits which can be made by the use of a capital
are in
this manner diminished, as it were, at both ends, the price which can
be paid
for the use of it, that is, the rate of interest, must necessarily
be
diminished with them.
Mr
Locke, Mr Lawe, and Mr Montesquieu, as well as many other writers, seem
to have
imagined that the increase of the quantity of gold and silver, in
consequence
of the discovery of the Spanish West Indies, was the real cause
of the
lowering of the rate of interest through the greater part of Europe.
Those
metals, they say, having become of less value themselves, the use of
any
particular portion of them necessarily became of less value too, and,
consequently,
the price which could be paid for it. This notion, which at
first
sight seems so plausible, has been so fully exposed by Mr Hume, that
it is,
perhaps, unnecessary to say any thing more about it. The following
very
short and plain argument, however, may serve to explain more distinctly
the
fallacy which seems to have misled those gentlemen.
Before
the discovery of the Spanish West Indies, ten per cent. seems to have
been
the common rate of interest through the greater part of Europe. It has
since
that time, in different countries, sunk to six, five, four, and three
per
cent. Let us suppose, that in every particular country the value of
silver
has sunk precisely in the same proportion as the rate of interest;
and
that in those countries, for example, where interest has been reduced
from
ten to five per cent. the same quantity of silver can now purchase just
half
the quantity of goods which it could have purchased before. This
supposition
will not, I believe, be found anywhere agreeable to the truth ;
but it
is the most favourable to the opinion which we are going to examine;
and,
even upon this supposition, it is utterly impossible that the lowering
of the
value of silver could have the smallest tendency to lower the rate of
interest.
If £100 are in those countries now of no more value than £50 were
then,
£10 must now be of no more value than £5 were then. Whatever were the
causes
which lowered the value of the capital, the same must necessarily
have
lowered that of the interest, and exactly in the same proportion. The
proportion
between the value of the capital and that of the interest must
have
remained the same, though the rate had never been altered. By altering
the
rate, on the contrary, the proportion between those two values is
necessarily
altered. If £100 now are worth no more than £50 were then, £5
now can
be worth no more than £2:10s. were then. By reducing the rate of
interest,
therefore, from ten to five per cent. we give for the use of a
capital,
which is supposed to be equal to one half of its former value, an
interest
which is equal to one fourth only of the value of the former
interest.
An
increase in the quantity of silver, while that of the commodities
circulated
by means of it remained the same, could have no other effect than
to
diminish the value of that metal. The nominal value of all sorts of goods
would
be greater, but their real value would be precisely the same as
before.
They would be exchanged for a greater number of pieces of silver;
but the
quantity of labour which they could command, the number of people
whom
they could maintain and employ, would be precisely the same. The
capital
of the country would be the same, though a greater number of pieces
might
be requisite for conveying any equal portion of it from one hand to
another.
The deeds of assignment, like the conveyances of a verbose
attorney,
would be more cumbersome; but the thing assigned would be
precisely
the same as before, and could produce only the same effects. The
funds
for maintaining productive labour being the same, the demand for it
would
be the same. Its price or wages, therefore, though nominally greater,
would
really be the same. They would be paid in a greater number of pieces
of
silver, but they would purchase only the same quantity of goods. The
profits
of stock would be the same, both nominally and really. The wages of
labour
are commonly computed by the quantity of silver which is paid to the
labourer.
When that is increased, therefore, his wages appear to be
increased,
though they may sometimes be no greater than before. But the
profits
of stock are not computed by the number of pieces of silver with
which
they are paid, but by the proportion which those pieces bear to the
whole
capital employed. Thus, in a particular country, 5s. a-week are said
to be
the common wages of labour, and ten per cent. the common profits of
stock ;
but the whole capital of the country being the same as before, the
competition
between the different capitals of individuals into which it was
divided
would likewise be the same. They would all trade with the same
advantages
and disadvantages. The common proportion between capital and
profit,
therefore, would be the same, and consequently the common interest
of
money; what can commonly be given for the use of money being necessarily
regulated
by what can commonly be made by the use of it.
Any
increase in the quantity of commodities annually circulated within the
country,
while that of the money which circulated them remained the same,
would,
on the contrary, produce many other important effects, besides that
of
raising the value of the money. The capital of the country, though it
might
nominally be the same, would really be augmented. It might continue to
be
expressed by the same quantity of money, but it would command a greater
quantity
of labour. The quantity of productive labour which it could
maintain
and employ would be increased, and consequently the demand for that
labour.
Its wages would naturally rise with the demand, and yet might appear
to
sink. They might be paid with a smaller quantity of money, but that
smaller
quantity might purchase a greater quantity of goods than a greater
had
done before. The profits of stock would be diminished, both really and
in
appearance. The whole capital of the country being augmented, the
competition
between the different capitals of which it was composed would
naturally
be augmented along with it. The owners of those particular
capitals
would be obliged to content themselves with a smaller proportion of
the
produce of that labour which their respective capitals employed. The
interest
of money, keeping pace always with the profits of stock, might, in
this
manner, be greatly diminished, though the value of money, or the
quantity
of goods which any particular sum could purchase, was greatly
augmented.
In some
countries the interest of money has been prohibited by law. But as
something
can everywhere be made by the use of money, something ought
everywhere
to be paid for the use of it. This regulation, instead of
preventing,
has been found from experience to increase the evil of usury.
The
debtor being obliged to pay, not only for the use of the money, but for
the
risk which his creditor runs by accepting a compensation for that use,
he is
obliged, if one may say so, to insure his creditor from the penalties
of
usury.
In
countries where interest is permitted, the law in order to prevent the
extortion
of usury, generally fixes the highest rate which can be taken
without
incurring a penalty. This rate ought always to be somewhat above the
lowest
market price, or the price which is commonly paid for the use of
money
by those who can give the most undoubted security. If this legal rate
should
be fixed below the lowest market rate, the effects of this fixation
must be
nearly the same as those of a total prohibition of interest. The
creditor
will not lend his money for less than the use of it is worth, and
the
debtor must pay him for the risk which he runs by accepting the full
value
of that use. If it is fixed precisely at the lowest market price, it
ruins,
with honest people who respect the laws of their country, the credit
of all
those who cannot give the very best security, and obliges them to
have
recourse to exorbitant usurers. In a country such as Great Britain,
where
money is lent to government at three per cent. and to private people,
upon
good security, at four and four and a-half, the present legal rate,
five
per cent. is perhaps as proper as any.
The
legal rate, it is to be observed, though it ought to be somewhat above,
ought
not to be much above the lowest market rate. If the legal rate of
interest
in Great Britain, for example, was fixed so high as eight or ten
per
cent. the greater part of the money which was to be lent, would be lent
to
prodigals and projectors, who alone would be willing to give this high
interest.
Sober people, who will give for the use of money no more than a
part of
what they are likely to make by the use of it, would not venture
into
the competition. A great part of the capital of the country would thus
be kept
out of the hands which were most likely to make a profitable and
advantageous
use of it, and thrown into those which were most likely to
waste
and destroy it. Where the legal rate of interest, on the contrary, is
fixed
but a very little above the lowest market rate, sober people are
universally
preferred, as borrowers, to prodigals and projectors. The person
who
lends money gets nearly as much interest from the former as he dares to
take
from the latter, and his money is much safer in the hands of the one
set of
people than in those of the other. A great part of the capital of the
country
is thus thrown into the hands in which it is most likely to be
employed
with advantage.
No law
can reduce the common rate of interest below the lowest ordinary
market
rate at the time when that law is made. Notwithstanding the edict of
1766,
by which the French king attempted to reduce the rate of interest from
five to
four per cent. money continued to be lent in France at five per
cent.
the law being evaded in several different ways.
The
ordinary market price of land, it is to be observed, depends everywhere
upon
the ordinary market rate of interest. The person who has a capital from
which
he wishes to derive a revenue, without taking the trouble to employ it
himself,
deliberates whether he should buy land with it, or lend it out at
interest.
The superior security of land, together with some other advantages
which
almost everywhere attend upon this species of property, will generally
dispose
him to content himself with a smaller revenue from land, than what
he
might have by lending out his money at interest. These advantages are
sufficient
to compensate a certain difference of revenue; but they will
compensate
a certain difference only ; and if the rent of land should fall
short
of the interest of money by a greater difference, nobody would buy
land,
which would soon reduce its ordinary price. On the contrary, if the
advantages
should much more than compensate the difference, everybody would
buy
land, which again would soon raise its ordinary price. When interest was
at ten
per cent. land was commonly sold for ten or twelve years purchase. As
interest
sunk to six, five, and four per cent. the price of land rose to
twenty,
five-and-twenty, and thirty years purchase. The market rate of
interest
is higher in France than in England, and the common price of land
is
lower. In England it commonly sells at thirty, in France at twenty years
purchase.
CHAPTER V.
OF THE
DIFFERENT EMPLOYMENTS OF CAPITALS.
Though
all capitals are destined for the maintenance of productive labour
only,
yet the quantity of that labour which equal capitals are capable of
putting
into motion, varies extremely according to the diversity of their
employment;
as does likewise the value which that employment adds to the
annual
produce of the land and labour of the country.
A
capital may be employed in four different ways; either, first, in
procuring
the rude produce annually required for the use and consumption of
the
society ; or, secondly, in manufacturing and preparing that rude produce
for
immediate use and consumption; or, thirdly in transporting either the
rude or
manufactured produce from the places where they abound to those
where
they are wanted ; or, lastly, in dividing particular portions of
either
into such small parcels as suit the occasional demands of those who
want
them. In the first way are employed the capitals of all those who
undertake
improvement or cultivation of lands, mines, or fisheries; in the
second,
those of all master manufacturers ; in the third, those of all
wholesale
merchants; and in the fourth, those of all retailers. It is
difficult
to conceive that a capital should be employed in any way which may
not be
classed under some one or other of those four.
Each of
those four methods of employing a capital is essentially necessary,
either
to the existence or extension of the other three, or to the general
conveniency
of the society.
Unless
a capital was employed in furnishing rude produce to a certain degree
of
abundance, neither manufactures nor trade of any kind could exist.
Unless
a capital was employed in manufacturing that part of the rude
produce
which requires a good deal of preparation before it can be fit for
use and
consumption, it either would never be produced, because there could
be no
demand for it; or if it was produced spontaneously, it would be of no
value
in exchange, and could add nothing to the wealth of the society.
Unless
a capital was employed in transporting either the rude or
manufactured
produce from the places where it abounds to those where it is
wanted,
no more of either could be produced than was necessary for the
consumption
of the neighbourhood. The capital of the merchant exchanges the
surplus
produce of one place for that of another, and thus encourages the
industry,
and increases the enjoyments of both.
Unless
a capital was employed in breaking and dividing certain portions
either
of the rude or manufactured produce into such small parcels as suit
the
occasional demands of those who want them, every man would be obliged to
purchase
a greater quantity of the goods he wanted than his immediate
occasions
required. If there was no such trade as a butcher, for example,
every
man would be obliged to purchase a whole ox or a whole sheep at a
time.
This would generally be inconvenient to the rich, and much more so to
the poor.
If a poor workman was obliged to purchase a month's or six months'
provisions
at a time, a great part of the stock which he employs as a
capital
in the instruments of his trade, or in the furniture of his shop,
and
which yields him a revenue, he would be forced to place in that part of
his
stock which is reserved for immediate consumption, and which yields him
no
revenue. Nothing can be more convenient for such a person than to be able
to
purchase his subsistence from day to day, or even from hour to hour, as
he
wants it. He is thereby enabled to employ almost his whole stock as a
capital.
He is thus enabled to furnish work to a greater value; and the
profit
which he makes by it in this way much more than compensates the
additional
price which the profit of the retailer imposes upon the goods.
The
prejudices of some political writers against shopkeepers and tradesmen
are
altogether without foundation. So far is it from being necessary either
to tax
them, or to restrict their numbers, that they can never be multiplied
so as
to hurt the public, though they may so as to hurt one another. The
quantity
of grocery goods, for example, which can be sold in a particular
town,
is limited by the demand of that town and its neighbourhood. The
capital,
therefore, which can be employed in the grocery trade, cannot
exceed
what is sufficient to purchase that quantity. If this capital is
divided
between two different grocers, their competition will tend to make
both of
them sell cheaper than if it were in the hands of one only ; and if
it were
divided among twenty, their competition would be just so much the
greater,
and the chance of their combining together, in order to raise the
price,
just so much the less. Their competition might, perhaps, ruin some of
themselves;
but to take care of this, is the business of the parties
concerned,
and it may safely be trusted to their discretion. It can never
hurt
either the consumer or the producer ; on the contrary, it must tend to
make
the retailers both sell cheaper and buy dearer, than if the whole trade
was
monopolized by one or two persons. Some of them, perhaps, may sometimes
decoy a
weak customer to buy what he has no occasion for. This evil,
however,
is of too little importance to deserve the public attention, nor
would
it necessarily be prevented by restricting their numbers. It is not
the
multitude of alehouses, to give the must suspicious example, that
occasions
a general disposition to drunkenness among the common people; but
that
disposition, arising from other causes, necessarily gives employment to
a
multitude of alehouses.
The
persons whose capitals are employed in any of those four ways, are
themselves
productive labourers. Their labour, when properly directed, fixes
and
realizes itself in the subject or vendible commodity upon which it is
bestowed,
and generally adds to its price the value at least of their own
maintenance
and consumption. The profits of the farmer, of the manufacturer,
of the
merchant, and retailer, are all drawn from the price of the goods
which
the two first produce, and the two last buy and sell. Equal capitals.
however,
employed in each of those four different ways, will immediately put
into
motion very different quantities of productive labour ; and augment,
too, in
very different proportions, the value of the annual produce of the
land
and labour of the society to which they belong.
The
capital of the retailer replaces, together with its profits, that of the
merchant
of whom he purchases goods, and thereby enables him to continue his
business.
The retailer himself is the only productive labourer whom it
immediately
employs. In his profit consists the whole value which its
employment
adds to the annual produce of the land and labour of the society.
The
capital of the wholesale merchant replaces, together with their
profits,
the capital's of the farmers and manufacturers of whom he purchases
the
rude and manufactured produce which he deals in, and thereby enables
them to
continue their respective trades. It is by this service chiefly that
he
contributes indirectly to support the productive labour of the society,
and to
increase the value of its annual produce. His capital employs, too,
the
sailors and carriers who transport his goods from one place to another ;
and it
augments the price of those goods by the value, not only of his
profits,
but of their wages. This is all the productive labour which it
immediately
puts into motion, and all the value which it immediately adds to
the
annual produce. Its operation in both these respects is a good deal
superior
to that of the capital of the retailer.
Part of
the capital of the master manufacturer is employed as a fixed
capital
in the instruments of his trade, and replaces, together with its
profits,
that of some other artificer of whom he purchases them. Part of his
circulating
capital is employed in purchasing materials, and replaces, with
their
profits, the capitals of the farmers and miners of whom he purchases
them.
But a great part of it is always, either annually, or in a much
shorter
period, distributed among the different workmen whom he employs. It
augments
the value of those materials by their wages, and by their masters'
profits
upon the whole stock of wages, materials, and instruments of trade
employed
in the business. It puts immediately into motion, therefore, a much
greater
quantity of productive labour, and adds a much greater value to the
annual
produce of the land and labour of the society, than an equal capital
in the
hands of any wholesale merchant.
No
equal capital puts into motion a greater quantity of productive labour
than
that of the farmer. Not only his labouring servants, but his labouring
cattle,
are productive labourers. In agriculture, too, Nature labours along
with
man ; and though her labour costs no expense, its produce has its
value,
as well as that of the most expensive workmen. The most important
operations
of agriculture seem intended, not so much to increase, though
they do
that too, as to direct the fertility of Nature towards the
production
of the plants most profitable to man. A field overgrown with
briars
and brambles, may frequently produce as great a quantity of
vegetables
as the best cultivated vineyard or corn field. Planting and
tillage
frequently regulate more than they animate the active fertility of
Nature;
and after all their labour, a great part of the work always remains
to be
done by her. The labourers and labouring cattle, therefore, employed
in
agriculture, not only occasion, like the workmen in manufactures, the
reproduction
of a value equal to their own consumption, or to the capital
which
employs them, together with its owner's profits, but of a much greater
value.
Over and above the capital of the farmer, and all its profits, they
regularly
occasion the reproduction of the rent of the landlord. This rent
may be
considered as the produce of those powers of Nature, the use of which
the
landlord lends to the farmer. It is greater or smaller, according to the
supposed
extent of those powers, or, in other words, according to the
supposed
natural or improved fertility of the land. It is the work of Nature
which
remains, after deducting or compensating every thing which can be
regarded
as the work of man. It is seldom less than a fourth, and
frequently
more than a third, of the whole produce. No equal quantity of
productive
labour employed in manufactures, can ever occasion so great
reproduction.
In them Nature does nothing ; man does all ; and the
reproduction
must always be in proportion to the strength of the agents that
occasion
it. The capital employed in agriculture, therefore, not only puts
into
motion a greater quantity of productive labour than any equal capital
employed
in manufactures; but in proportion, too, to the quantity of
productive
labour which it employs, it adds a much greater value to the
annual
produce of the land and labour of the country, to the real wealth and
revenue
of its inhabitants. Of all the ways in which a capital can be
employed,
it is by far the most advantageous to society.
The
capitals employed in the agriculture and in the retail trade of any
society,
must always reside within that society. Their employment is
confined
almost to a precise spot, to the farm, and to the shop of the
retailer.
They must generally, too, though there are some exceptions to
this,
belong to resident members of the society.
The
capital of a wholesale merchant, on the contrary, seems to have no fixed
or
necessary residence anywhere, but may wander about from place to place,
according
as it can either buy cheap or sell dear.
The
capital of the manufacturer must, no doubt, reside where the manufacture
is
carried on ; but where this shall be, is not always necessarily
determined.
It may frequently be at a great distance, both from the place
where
the materials grow, and from that where the complete manufacture is
consumed.
Lyons is very distant, both from the places which afford the
materials
of its manufactures, and from those which consume them. The people
of
fashion in Sicily are clothed in silks made in other countries, from the
materials
which their own produces. Part of the wool of Spain is
manufactured
in Great Britain, and some part of that cloth is afterwards
sent
back to Spain.
Whether
the merchant whose capital exports the surplus produce of any
society,
be a native or a foreigner, is of very little importance. If he is
a
foreigner, the number of their productive labourers is necessarily less
than if
he had been a native, by one man only ; and the value of their
annual
produce, by the profits of that one man. The sailors or carriers whom
he
employs, may still belong indifferently either to his country, or to
their
country, or to some third country, in the same manner as if he had
been a
native. The capital of a foreigner gives a value to their surplus
produce
equally with that of a native, by exchanging it for something for
which
there is a demand at home. It as effectually replaces the capital of
the
person who produces that surplus, and as effectually enables him to
continue
his business, the service by which the capital of a wholesale
merchant
chiefly contributes to support the productive labour, and to
augment
the value of the annual produce of the society to which he belongs.
It is
of more consequence that the capital of the manufacturer should reside
within
the country. It necessarily puts into motion a greater quantity of
productive
labour, and adds a greater value to the annual produce of the
land
and labour of the society. It may, however, be very useful to the
country,
though it should not reside within it. The capitals of the British
manufacturers
who work up the flax and hemp annually imported from the
coasts
of the Baltic, are surely very useful to the countries which produce
them.
Those materials are a part of the surplus produce of those countries,
which,
unless it was annually exchanged for something which is in demand
here,
would be of no value, and would soon cease to be produced. The
merchants
who export it, replace the capitals of the people who produce it,
and
thereby encourage them to continue the production ; and the British
manufacturers
replace the capitals of those merchants.
A
particular country, in the same manner as a particular person, may
frequently
not have capital sufficient both to improve and cultivate all its
lands,
to manufacture and prepare their whole rude produce for immediate use
and
consumption, and to transport the surplus part either of the rude or
manufactured
produce to those distant markets, where it can be exchanged for
something
for which there is a demand at home. The inhabitants of many
different
parts of Great Britain have not capital sufficient to improve and
cultivate
all their lands. The wool of the southern counties of Scotland is,
a great
part of it, after a long land carriage through very bad roads,
manufactured
in Yorkshire, for want of a capital to manufacture it at home.
There
are many little manufacturing towns in Great Britain, of which the
inhabitants
have not capital sufficient to transport the produce of their
own
industry to those distant markets where there is demand and consumption
for it.
If there are any merchants among them, they are, properly, only the
agents
of wealthier merchants who reside in some of the great commercial
cities.
When
the capital of any country is not sufficient for all those three
purposes,
in proportion as a greater share of it is employed in agriculture,
the
greater will be the quantity of productive labour which it puts into
motion
within the country ; as will likewise be the value which its
employment
adds to the annual produce of the land and labour of the society.
After
agriculture, the capital employed in manufactures puts into motion
the
greatest quantity of productive labour, and adds the greatest value to
the
annual produce. That which is employed in the trade of exportation has
the
least effect of any of the three.
The
country, indeed, which has not capital sufficient for all those three
purposes,
has not arrived at that degree of opulence for which it seems
naturally
destined. To attempt, however,
prematurely, and with an
insufficient
capital, to do all the three, is certainly not the shortest way
for a
society, no more than it would be for an individual, to acquire a
sufficient
one. The capital of all the individuals of a nation has its
limits,
in the same manner as that of a single individual, and is capable
of
executing only certain purposes. The capital of all the individuals of a
nation
is increased in the same manner as that of a single individual, by
their
continually accumulating and adding to it whatever they save out of
their
revenue. It is likely to increase the fastest, therefore, when it is
employed
in the way that affords the greatest revenue to all the inhabitants
or the
country, as they will thus be enabled to make the greatest savings.
But the
revenue of all the inhabitants of the country is necessarily in
proportion
to the value of the annual produce of their land and labour.
It has
been the principal cause of the rapid progress of our American
colonies
towards wealth and greatness, that almost their whole capitals have
hitherto
been employed in agriculture. They have no manufactures, those
household
and coarser manufactures excepted, which necessarily accompany the
progress
of agriculture, and which are the work of the women and children in
every
private family. The greater part, both of the exportation and coasting
trade
of America, is carried on by the capitals of merchants who reside in
Great
Britain. Even the stores and warehouses from which goods are retailed
in some
provinces, particularly in Virginia and Maryland, belong many of
them to
merchants who reside in the mother country, and afford one of the
few
instances of the retail trade of a society being carried on by the
capitals
of those who are not resident members of it. Were the Americans,
either
by combination, or by any other sort of violence, to stop the
importation
of European manufactures, and, by thus giving a monopoly to such
of
their own countrymen as could manufacture the like goods, divert any
considerable
part of their capital into this employment, they would retard,
instead
of accelerating, the further increase in the value of their annual
produce,
and would obstruct, instead of promoting, the progress of their
country
towards real wealth and greatness. This would be still more the
case,
were they to attempt, in the same manner, to monopolize to themselves
their
whole exportation trade.
The
course of human prosperity, indeed, seems scarce ever to have been of so
long
continuance as to unable any great country to acquire capital
sufficient
for all those three purposes; unless, perhaps, we give credit to
the
wonderful accounts of the wealth and cultivation of China, of those of
ancient
Egypt, and of the ancient state of Indostan. Even those three
countries,
the wealthiest, according to all accounts, that ever were in the
world,
are chiefly renowned for their superiority in agriculture and
manufactures.
They do not appear to have been eminent for foreign trade. The
ancient
Egyptians had a superstitious antipathy to the sea ; a superstition
nearly
of the same kind prevails among the Indians; and the Chinese have
never
excelled in foreign commerce. The greater part of the surplus produce
of all
those three countries seems to have been always exported by
foreigners,
who gave in exchange for it something else, for which they found
a
demand there, frequently gold and silver.
It is
thus that the same capital will in any country put into motion a
greater
or smaller quantity of productive labour, and add a greater or
smaller
value to the annual produce of its land and labour, according to
the
different proportions in which it is employed in agriculture,
manufactures,
and wholesale trade. The difference, too, is very great,
according
to the different sorts of wholesale trade in which any part of it
is
employed.
All
wholesale trade, all buying in order to sell again by wholesale, maybe
reduced
to three different sorts : the home trade, the foreign trade of
consumption,
and the carrying trade. The home trade is employed in
purchasing
in one part of the same country, and selling in another, the
produce
of the industry of that country. It comprehends both the inland and
the
coasting trade. The foreign trade of consumption is employed in
purchasing
foreign goods for home consumption. The carrying trade is
employed
in transacting the commerce of foreign countries, or in carrying
the
surplus produce of one to another.
The
capital which is employed in purchasing in one part of the country, in
order
to sell in another, the produce of the industry of that country,
generally
replaces, by every such operation, two distinct capitals, that had
both
been employed in the agriculture or manufactures of that country, and
thereby
enables them to continue that employment. When it sends out from the
residence
of the merchant a certain value of commodities, it generally
brings
hack in return at least an equal value of other commodities. When
both
are the produce of domestic industry, it necessarily replaces, by every
such
operation, two distinct capitals, which had both been employed in
Supporting
productive labour, and thereby enables them to continue that
support.
The capital which sends Scotch manufactures to London, and brings
back
English corn and manufactures to Edinburgh, necessarily replaces, by
every
such operation, two British capitals, which had both been employed in
the
agriculture or manufactures of Great Britain.
The
capital employed in purchasing foreign goods for home consumption, when
this
purchase is made with the produce of domestic industry, replaces, too,
by
every such operation, two distinct capitals; but one of them only is
employed
in supporting domestic industry. The capital which sends British
goods
to Portugal, and brings back Portuguese goods to Great Britain,
replaces,
by every such operation, only one British capital. The other is a
Portuguese
one. Though the returns, therefore, of the foreign trade of
consumption,
should be as quick as those of the home trade, the capital
employed
in it will give but one half of the encouragement to the industry
or productive
labour of the country.
But the
returns of the foreign trade of consumption are very seldom so quick
as
those of the home trade. The returns of the home trade generally come in
before
the end of the year, and sometimes three or four times in the year.
The
returns of the foreign trade of consumption seldom come in before the
end of
the year, and sometimes not till after two or three years. A capital,
therefore,
employed in the home trade, will sometimes make twelve
operations,
or be sent out and returned twelve times, before a capital
employed
in the foreign trade of consumption has made one. If the capitals
are
equal, therefore, the one will give four-and-twenty times more
encouragement
and support to the industry of the country than the other.
The
foreign goods for home consumption may sometimes be purchased, not with
the
produce of domestic industry but with some other foreign goods. These
last,
however, must have been purchased, either immediately with the produce
of
domestic industry, or with something else that had been purchased with it;
for,
the case of war and conquest excepted, foreign goods can never be
acquired,
but in exchange for something that had been produced at home,
either
immediately, or after two or more different exchanges. The effects,
therefore,
of a capital employed in such a round-about foreign trade of
consumption,
are, in every respect, the same as those of one employed in the
most
direct trade of the same kind, except that the final returns are likely
to be
still more distant, as they must depend upon the returns of two or
three
distinct foreign trades. If the hemp and flax of Riga are purchased
with
the tobacco of Virginia, which had been purchased with British
manufactures,
the merchant must wait for the returns of two distinct foreign
trades,
before he can employ the same capital in repurchasing a like
quantity
of British manufactures. If the tobacco of Virginia had been
purchased,
not with British manufactures, but with the sugar and rum of
Jamaica,
which had been purchased with those manufactures, he must wait for
the
returns of three. If those two or three distinct foreign trades should
happen
to be carried on by two or three distinct merchants, of whom the
second
buys the goods imported by the first, and the third buys those
imported
by the second, in order to export them again, each merchant,
indeed,
will, in this case, receive the returns of his own capital more
quickly
; but the final returns of the whole capital employed in the trade
will be
just as slow as ever. Whether the whole capital employed in such a
round
about trade belong to one merchant or
to three, can make no
difference
with regard to the country, though it may with regard to the
particular
merchants. Three times a greater capital must in both cases be
employed,
in order to exchange a certain value of British manufactures for a
certain
quantity of flax and hemp, than would have been necessary, had the
manufactures
and the flax and hemp been directly exchanged for one another.
The
whole capital employed, therefore, in such a round-about foreign trade
of
consumption, will generally give less encouragement and support to the
productive
labour of the country, than an equal capital employed in a more
direct
trade of the same kind.
Whatever
be the foreign commodity with which the foreign goods for home
consumption
are purchased, it can occasion no essential difference, either in
the
nature of the trade, or in the encouragement and support which it can
give to
the productive labour of the country from which it is carried on. If
they
are purchased with the gold of Brazil, for example, or with the silver
of
Peru, this gold and silver, like the tobacco of Virginia, must have been
purchased
with something that either was the produce of the industry of the
country,
or that had been purchased with something else that was so. So far,
therefore,
as the productive labour of the country is concerned, the foreign
trade
of consumption, which is carried on by means of gold and silver, has
all the
advantages and all the inconveniencies of any other equally
round-about
foreign trade of consumption; and will replace, just as fast, or
just as
slow, the capital which is immediately employed in supporting that
productive
labour. It seems even to have one advantage over any other
equally
round-about foreign trade. The transportation of those metals from
one
place to another, on account of their small bulk and great value, is
less
expensive than that of almost any other foreign goods of equal value.
Their
freight is much less, and their insurance not greater ; and no goods,
besides,
are less liable to suffer by the carriage. An equal quantity of
foreign
goods, therefore, may frequently be purchased with a smaller
quantity
of the produce of domestic industry, by the intervention of gold
and
silver, than by that of any other foreign goods. The demand of the
country
may frequently, in this manner, be supplied more completely, and at
a
smaller expense, than in any other. Whether, by the continual exportation
of
those metals, a trade of this kind is likely to impoverish the country
from
which it is carried on in any other way, I shall have occasion to
examine
at great length hereafter.
That
part of the capital of any country which is employed in the carrying
trade,
is altogether withdrawn from supporting the productive labour of that
particular
country, to support that of some foreign countries. Though it may
replace,
by every operation, two distinct capitals, yet neither of them
belongs
to that particular country. The capital of the Dutch merchant, which
carries
the corn of Poland to Portugal, and brings back the fruits and wines
of
Portugal to Poland, replaces by every such operation two capitals,
neither
of which had been employed in supporting the productive labour of
Holland;
but one of them in supporting that of Poland, and the other that of
Portugal.
The profits only return regularly to Holland, and constitute the
whole
addition which this trade necessarily makes to the annual produce of
the
land and labour of that country. When, indeed, the carrying trade of any
particular
country is carried on with the ships and sailors of that country,
that
part of the capital employed in it which pays the freight is
distributed
among, and puts into motion, a certain number of productive
labourers
of that country. Almost all nations that have had any considerable
share
of the carrying trade have, in fact, carried it on in this manner. The
trade
itself has probably derived its name from it, the people of such
countries
being the carriers to other countries. It does not, however, seem
essential
to the nature of the trade that it should be so. A Dutch merchant
may,
for example, employ his capital in transacting the commerce of Poland
and
Portugal, by carrying part of the surplus produce of the one to the
other,
not in Dutch, but in British bottoms. It maybe presumed, that he
actually
does so upon some particular occasions. It is upon this account,
however,
that the carrying trade has been supposed peculiarly advantageous
to such
a country as Great Britain, of which the defence and security depend
upon
the number of its sailors and shipping. But the same capital may
employ
as many sailors and shipping, either in the foreign trade of
consumption,
or even in the home trade, when carried on by coasting vessels,
as it
could in the carrying trade. The number of sailors and shipping which
any
particular capital can employ, does not depend upon the nature of the
trade,
but partly upon the bulk of the goods, in proportion to their value,
and
partly upon the distance of the ports between which they are to be
carried;
chiefly upon the former of those two circumstances. The coal trade
from
Newcastle to London, for example, employs more shipping than all the
carrying
trade of England, though the ports are at no great distance. To
force,
therefore, by extraordinary encouragements, a larger share of the
capital
of any country into the carrying trade, than what would naturally go
to it,
will not always necessarily increase the shipping of that country.
The
capital, therefore, employed in the home trade of any country, will
generally
give encouragement and support to a greater quantity of productive
labour
in that country, and increase the value of its annual produce, more
than an
equal capital employed in the foreign trade of consumption; and the
capital
employed in this latter trade has, in both these respects, a still
greater
advantage over an equal capital employed in the carrying trade. The
riches,
and so far as power depends upon riches, the power of every country
must
always be in proportion to the value of its annual produce, the fund
from
which all taxes must ultimately be paid. But the great object of the
political
economy of every country, is to increase the riches and power of
that
country. It ought, therefore, to give no preference nor superior
encouragement
to the foreign trade of consumption above the home trade, nor
to the
carrying trade above either of the other two. It ought neither to
force
nor to allure into either of those two channels a greater share of the
capital
of the country, than what would naturally flow into them of its own
accord.
Each of
those different branches of trade, however, is not only
advantageous,
but necessary and unavoidable, when the course of things,
without
any constraint or violence, naturally introduces it.
When
the produce of any particular branch of industry exceeds what the
demand
of the country requires, the surplus must be sent abroad, and
exchanged
for something for which there is a demand at home. Without
such
exportation, a part of the productive labour of the country must cease,
and the
value of its annual produce diminish. The land and labour of Great
Britain
produce generally more corn, woollens, and hardware, than the demand
of the
home market requires. The surplus part of them, therefore, must be
sent
abroad, and exchanged for something for which there is a demand at
home.
It is only by means of such exportation, that this surplus can
acquired
value sufficient to compensate the labour and expense of producing
it. The
neighbourhood of the sea-coast, and the banks of all navigable
rivers,
are advantageous situations for industry, only because they
facilitate
the exportation and exchange of such surplus produce for
something
else which is more in demand there.
When
the foreign goods which are thus purchased with the surplus produce of
domestic
industry exceed the demand of the home market, the surplus part
of them
must be sent abroad again, and exchanged for something more in
demand
at home. About 96,000 hogsheads of tobacco are annually purchased in
Virginia
and Maryland with a part of the surplus produce of British
industry.
But the demand of Great Britain does not require, perhaps, more
than
14,000. If the remaining 82,000, therefore, could not be sent abroad,
and
exchanged for something more in demand at home, the importation of them
must
cease immediately, and with it the productive labour of all those
inhabitants
of Great Britain who are at present employed in preparing the
goods
with which these 82,000 hogsheads are annually purchased. Those goods,
which
are part of the produce of the land and labour of Great Britain,
having
no market at home, and being deprived of that which they had abroad,
must
cease to be produced. The most round-about foreign trade of
consumption,
therefore, may, upon some occasions, be as necessary for
supporting
the productive labour of the country, and the value of its annual
produce,
as the most direct.
When
the capital stock of any country is increased to such a degree that it
cannot
be all employed in supplying the consumption, and supporting the
productive
labour of that particular country, the surplus part of it
naturally
disgorges itself into the carrying trade, and is employed in
performing
the same offices to other countries. The carrying trade is the
natural
effect and symptom of great national wealth; but it does not seem to
be the
natural cause of it. Those statesmen who have been disposed to favour
it with
particular encouragement, seem to have mistaken the effect and
symptom
for the cause. Holland, in proportion to the extent of the land and
the
number of it's inhabitants, by far the richest country in Europe, has
accordingly
the greatest share of the carrying trade of Europe. England,
perhaps
the second richest country of Europe, is likewise supposed to have a
considerable
share in it; though what commonly passes for the carrying trade
of
England will frequently, perhaps, be found to be no more than a
round-about
foreign trade of consumption. Such are, in a great measure, the
trades
which carry the goods of the East and West Indies and of America to
the different
European markets. Those goods are generally purchased, either
immediately
with the produce of British industry, or with something else
which
had been purchased with that produce, and the final returns of those
trades
are generally used or consumed in Great Britain. The trade which
is
carried on in British bottoms between the different ports of the
Mediterranean,
and some trade of the same kind carried on by British
merchants
between the different ports of India, make, perhaps, the principal
branches
of what is properly the carrying trade of Great Britain.
The
extent of the home trade, and of the capital which can be employed in
it, is
necessarily limited by the value of the surplus produce of all those
distant
places within the country which have occasion to exchange their
respective
productions with one another ; that of the foreign trade of
consumption,
by the value of the surplus produce of the whole country, and
of what
can be purchased with it; that of the carrying trade, by the value
of the
surplus produce of all the different countries in the world. Its
possible
extent, therefore, is in a manner infinite in comparison of that of
the
other two, and is capable of absorbing the greatest capitals.
The
consideration of his own private profit is the sole motive which
determines
the owner of any capital to employ it either in agriculture, in
manufactures,
or in some particular branch of the wholesale or retail trade.
The
different quantities of productive labour which it may put into motion,
and the
different values which it may add to the annual produce of the land
and
labour of the society, according as it is employed in one or other of
those
different ways, never enter into his thoughts. In countries,
therefore,
where agriculture is the most profitable of all employments, and
farming
and improving the most direct roads to a splendid fortune, the
capitals
of individuals will naturally be employed in the manner most
advantageous
to the whole society. The profits of agriculture, however, seem
to have
no superiority over those of other employments in any part of
Europe.
Projectors, indeed, in every corner of it, have, within these few
years,
amused the public with most magnificent accounts of the profits to be
made by
the cultivation and improvement of land. Without entering into any
particular
discussion of their calculations, a very simple observation may
satisfy
us that the result of them must be false. We see, every day, the
most
splendid fortunes, that have been acquired in the course of a single
life,
by trade and manufactures, frequently from a very small capital,
sometimes
from no capital. A single instance of such a fortune, acquired by
agriculture
in the same time, and from such a capital, has not, perhaps,
occurred
in Europe, during the course of the present century. In all the
great
countries of Europe, however, much good land still remains
uncultivated
; and the greater part of what is cultivated, is far from being
improved
to the degree of which it is capable. Agriculture, therefore, is
almost
everywhere capable of absorbing a much greater capital than has ever
yet
been employed in it. What circumstances in the policy of Europe have
given
the trades which are carried on in towns so great an advantage over
that
which is carried on in the country, that private persons frequently
find it
more for their advantage to employ their capitals in the most
distant
carrying trades of Asia and America. than in the improvement and
cultivation
of the most fertile fields in their own neighbourhood, I shall
endeavour
to explain at full length in the two following books.
BOOK III.
OF THE
DIFFERENT PROGRESS OF OPULENCE IN DIFFERENT NATIONS
CHAPTER I.
OF THE
NATURAL PROGRESS OF OPULENCE.
The
great commerce of every civilized society is that carried on between the
inhabitants
of the town and those of the country. It consists in the
exchange
of rude for manufactured produce, either immediately, or by the
intervention
of money, or of some sort of paper which represents money. The
country
supplies the town with the means of subsistence and the materials of
manufacture.
The town repays this supply, by sending back a part of the
manufactured
produce to the inhabitants of the country. The town, in which
there
neither is nor can be any reproduction of substances, may very
properly
be said to gain its whole wealth and subsistence from the country.
We must
not, however, upon this account, imagine that the gain of the town
is the
loss of the country. The gains of both are mutual and reciprocal, and
the
division of labour is in this, as in all other cases, advantageous to all
the
different persons employed in the various occupations into which it is
subdivided.
The inhabitants of the country purchase of the town a greater
quantity
of manufactured goods with the produce of a much smaller quantity
of
their own labour, than they must have employed had they attempted to
prepare
them themselves. The town affords a market for the surplus produce
of the
country, or what is over and above the maintenance of the cultivators
; and
it is there that the inhabitants of the country exchange it for
something
else which is in demand among them. The greater the number and
revenue
of the inhabitants of the town, the more extensive is the market
which
it affords to those of the country ; and the more extensive that
market,
it is always the more advantageous to a great number. The corn which
grows
within a mile of the town, sells there for the same price with that
which
comes from twenty miles distance. But the price of the latter must,
generally,
not only pay the expense of raising it and bringing it to market,
but
afford, too, the ordinary profits of agriculture to the farmer. The
proprietors
and cultivators of the country, therefore, which lies in the
neighbourhood
of the town, over and above the ordinary profits of
agriculture,
gain, in the price of what they sell, the whole value of the
carriage
of the like produce that is brought from more distant parts ; and
they
save, besides, the whole value of this carriage in the price of what
they
buy. Compare the cultivation of the lands in the neighbourhood of any
considerable
town, with that of those which lie at some distance from it,
and you
will easily satisfy yourself bow much the country is benefited by
the
commerce of the town. Among all the absurd speculations that have been
propagated
concerning the balance of trade, it has never been pretended that
either
the country loses by its commerce with the town, or the town by that
with
the country which maintains it.
As
subsistence is, in the nature of things, prior to conveniency and luxury,
so the
industry which procures the former, must necessarily be prior to that
which
ministers to the latter. The cultivation and improvement of the
country,
therefore, which affords subsistence, must, necessarily, be prior
to the
increase of the town, which furnishes only the means of conveniency
and
luxury. It is the surplus produce of the country only, or what is over
and
above the maintenance of the cultivators, that constitutes the
subsistence
of the town, which can therefore increase only with the increase
of the
surplus produce. The town, indeed, may not always derive its whole
subsistence
from the country in its neighbourhood, or even from the
territory
to which it belongs, but from very distant countries; and this,
though
it forms no exception from the general rule, has occasioned
considerable
variations in the progress of opulence in different ages and
nations.
That
order of things which necessity imposes, in general, though not in
every
particular country, is in every particular country promoted by the
natural
inclinations of man. If human institutions had never thwarted those
natural
inclinations, the towns could nowhere have increased beyond what the
improvement
and cultivation of the territory in which they were situated
could
support; till such time, at least, as the whole of that territory was
completely
cultivated and improved. Upon equal, or nearly equal profits,
most
men will choose to employ their capitals, rather in the improvement and
cultivation
of land, than either in manufactures or in foreign trade. The
man who
employs his capital in land, has it more under his view and command
; and
his fortune is much less liable to accidents than that of the trader,
who is
obliged frequently to commit it, not only to the winds and the waves,
but to
the more uncertain elements of human folly and injustice, by giving
great
credits, in distant countries, to men with whose character and
situation
he can seldom be thoroughly acquainted. The capital of the
landlord,
on the contrary, which is fixed in the improvement of his land,
seems
to be as well secured as the nature of human affairs can admit of. The
beauty
of the country, besides, the pleasure of a country life, the
tranquillity
of mind which it promises, and, wherever the injustice of human
laws
does not disturb it, the independency which it really affords, have
charms
that, more or less, attract everybody; and as to cultivate the ground
was the
original destination of man, so, in every stage of his existence, he
seems
to retain a predilection for this primitive employment.
Without
the assistance of some artificers, indeed, the cultivation of land
cannot
be carried on, but with great inconveniency and continual
interruption.
Smiths, carpenters, wheelwrights and ploughwrights, masons and
bricklayers,
tanners, shoemakers, and tailors, are people whose service the
farmer
has frequent occasion for. Such artificers, too, stand occasionally
in need
of the assistance of one another; and as their residence is not,
like
that of the farmer, necessarily tied down to a precise spot, they
naturally
settle in the neighbourhood of one another, and thus form a small
town or
village. The butcher, the brewer, and the baker, soon join them,
together
with many other artificers and retailers, necessary or useful for
supplying
their occasional wants, and who contribute still further to
augment
the town. The inhabitants of the town, and those of the country, are
mutually
the servants of one another. The town is a continual fair or
market,
to which the inhabitants of the country resort, in order to exchange
their
rude for manufactured produce. It is this commerce which supplies the
inhabitants
of the town, both with the materials of their work, and the
means
of their subsistence. The quantity of the finished work which they
sell to
the inhabitants of the country, necessarily regulates the quantity
of the
materials and provisions which they buy. Neither their employment nor
subsistence,
therefore, can augment, but in proportion to the augmentation
of the
demand from the country for finished work ; and this demand can
augment
only in proportion to the extension of improvement and cultivation.
Had
human institutions, therefore, never disturbed the natural course of
things,
the progressive wealth and increase of the towns would, in every
political
society, be consequential, and in proportion to the improvement
and
cultivation of the territory of country.
In our
North American colonies, where uncultivated land is still to be had
upon
easy terms, no manufactures for distant sale have ever yet been
established
in any of their towns. When an artificer has acquired a little
more
stock than is necessary for carrying on his own business in supplying
the
neighbouring country, he does not, in North America, attempt to
establish
with it a manufacture for more distant sale, but employs it in the
purchase
and improvement of uncultivated land. From artificer he becomes
planter
; and neither the large wages nor the easy subsistence which that
country
affords to artificers, can bribe him rather to work for other people
than
for himself. He feels that an artificer is the servant of his
customers,
from whom he derives his subsistence; but that a planter who
cultivates
his own land, and derives his necessary subsistence from the
labour
of his own family, is really a master, and independent of all the
world.
In
countries, on the contrary, where there is either no uncultivated land,
or none
that can be had upon easy terms, every artificer who has acquired
more
stock than he can employ in the occasional jobs of the neighbourhood,
endeavours
to prepare work for more distant sale. The smith erects some sort
of
iron, the weaver some sort of linen or woollen manufactory. Those
different
manufactures come, in process of time, to be gradually subdivided,
and
thereby improved and refined in a great variety of ways, which may
easily
be conceived, and which it is therefore unnecessary to explain any
farther.
In
seeking for employment to a capital, manufactures are, upon equal or
nearly
equal profits, naturally preferred to foreign commerce, for the same
reason
that agriculture is naturally preferred to manufactures. As the
capital
of the landlord or farmer is more secure than that of the
manufacturer,
so the capital of the manufacturer, being at all times more
within
his view and command, is more secure than that of the foreign
merchant.
In every period, indeed, of every society, the surplus part both
of the
rude and manufactured produce, or that for which there is no demand
at
home, must be sent abroad, in order to be exchanged for something for
which
there is some demand at home. But whether the capital which carries
this
surplus produce abroad be a foreign or a domestic one, is of very
little
importance. If the society has not acquired sufficient capital, both
to cultivate
all its lands, and to manufacture in the completest manner the
whole
of its rude produce, there is even a considerable advantage that the
rude
produce should be exported by a foreign capital, in order that the
whole
stock of the society may be employed in more useful purposes. The:
wealth
of ancient Egypt, that of China and Indostan, sufficient1y
demonstrate
that a nation may attain a very high degree of opulence, though
the
greater part of its exportation trade be carried on by foreigners. The
progress
of our North American and West Indian colonies, would have been
much
less rapid, had no capital but what belonged to themselves been
employed
in exporting their surplus produce.
According
to the natural course of things, therefore, the greater part of
the
capital of every growing society is, first, directed to agriculture,
afterwards
to manufactures, and, last of all, to foreign commerce. This
order
of things is so very natural, that in every society that had any
territory,
it has always, I believe, been in some degree observed. Some of
their
lands must have been cultivated before any considerable towns could be
established,
and some sort of coarse industry of the manufacturing kind must
have
been carried on in those towns, before they could well think of
employing
themselves in foreign commerce.
But
though this natural order of things must have taken place in some degree
in
every such society, it has, in all the modern states of Europe, been in
many
respects entirely inverted. The foreign commerce of some of their
cities
has introduced all their finer manufactures, or such as were fit for
distant
sale; and manufactures and foreign commerce together have given
birth
to the principal improvements of agriculture. The manners and customs
which
the nature of their original government introduced, and which remained
after
that government was greatly altered, necessarily forced them into this
unnatural
and retrograde order.
CHAPTER II.
OF THE
DISCOURAGEMENT OF AGRICULTURE IN
THE
ANCIENT STATE OF EUROPE, AFTER THE
FALL OF
THE ROMAN EMPIRE.
When
the German and Scythian nations overran the western provinces of the
Roman
empire, the confusions which followed so great a revolution lasted for
several
centuries. The rapine and violence which the barbarians exercised
against
the ancient inhabitants, interrupted the commerce between the towns
and the
country. The towns were deserted, and the country was left
uncultivated;
and the western provinces of Europe, which had enjoyed a
considerable
degree of opulence under the Roman empire, sunk into the lowest
state
of poverty and barbarism. During the continuance of those confusions,
the
chiefs and principal leaders of those nations acquired, or usurped to
themselves,
the greater part of the lands of those countries. A great part
of them
was uncultivated; but no part of them, whether cultivated or
uncultivated,
was left without a proprietor. All of them were engrossed, and
the
greater part by a few great proprietors.
This
original engrossing of uncultivated lands, though a great, might have
been
but a transitory evil. They might soon have been divided again, and
broke
into small parcels, either by succession or by alienation. The law of
primogeniture
hindered them from being divided by succession; the
introduction
of entails prevented their being broke into small parcels by
alienation.
When
land, like moveables, is considered as the means only of subsistence
and
enjoyment, the natural law of succession divides it, like them, among
all the
children of the family ; of all of whom the subsistence and
enjoyment
may be supposed equally dear to the father. This natural law of
succession,
accordingly, took place among the Romans who made no more
distinction
between elder and younger, between male and female, in the
inheritance
of lands, than we do in the distribution of moveables. But when
land
was considered as the means, not of subsistence merely, but of power
and
protection, it was thought better that it should descend undivided to
one. In
those disorderly times, every great landlord was a sort of petty
prince.
His tenants were his subjects. He was their judge, and in some
respects
their legislator in peace and their leader in war. He made war
according
to his own discretion, frequently against his neighbours, and
sometimes
against his sovereign. The security of a landed estate, therefore,
the
protection which its owner could afford to those who dwelt on it,
depended
upon its greatness. To divide it was to ruin it, and to expose
every
part of it to be oppressed and swallowed up by the incursions of its
neighbours.
The law of primogeniture, therefore, came to take place, not
immediately
indeed, but in process of time, in the succession of landed
estates,
for the same reason that it has generally taken place in that of
monarchies,
though not always at their first institution. That the power,
and
consequently the security of the monarchy, may not be weakened by
division,
it must descend entire to one of the children. To which of them so
important
a preference shall be given, must be determined by some general
rule,
founded not upon the doubtful distinctions of personal merit, but upon
some
plain and evident difference which can admit of no dispute. Among the
children
of the same family there can be no indisputable difference but that
of sex,
and that of age. The male sex is universally preferred to the
female;
and when all other things are equal, the elder everywhere takes
place
of the younger. Hence the origin of the right of primogeniture, and of
what is
called lineal succession.
Laws
frequently continue in force long after the circumstances which first
gave
occasion to them, and which could alone render them reasonable, are no
more.
In the present state of Europe, the proprietor of a single acre of
land is
as perfectly secure in his possession as the proprietor of 100,000.
The
right of primogeniture, however, still continues to be respected ; and
as of
all institutions it is the fittest to support the pride of family
distinctions,
it is still likely to endure for many centuries. In every
other
respect, nothing can be more contrary to the real interest of a
numerous
family, than a right which, in order to enrich one, beggars all the
rest of
the children.
Entails
are the natural consequences of the law of primogeniture. They were
introduced
to preserve a certain lineal succession, of which the law of
primogeniture
first gave the idea, and to hinder any part of the original
estate
from being carried out of the proposed line, either by gift, or
device,
or alienation; either by the folly, or by the misfortune of any of
its
successive owners. They were altogether unknown to the Romans. Neither
their
substitutions, nor fidei commisses, bear any resemblance to entails,
though
some French lawyers have thought proper to dress the modern
institution
in the language and garb of those ancient ones.
When
great landed estates were a sort of principalities, entails might not
be
unreasonable. Like what are called the fundamental laws of some
monarchies,
they might frequently hinder the security of thousands from
being
endangered by the caprice or extravagance of one man. But in the
present
state of Europe, when small as well as great estates derive their
security
from the laws of their country, nothing can be more completely
absurd.
They are founded upon the most absurd of all suppositions, the
supposition
that every successive generation of men have not an equal right
to the
earth, and to all that it possesses ; but that the property of the
present
generation should be restrained and regulated according to the fancy
of
those who died, perhaps five hundred years ago. Entails, however,
are
still respected, through the greater part of Europe ; In those
countries,
particularly, in which noble birth is a necessary qualification
for the
enjoyment either of civil or military honours. Entails are thought
necessary
for maintaining this exclusive privilege of the nobility to the
great offices
and honours of their country; and that order having usurped
one
unjust advantage over the rest of their fellow-citizens, lest their
poverty
should render it ridiculous, it is thought reasonable that they
should
have another. The common law of England, indeed, is said to abhor
perpetuities,
and they are accordingly more restricted there than in any
other
European monarchy ; though even England is not altogether without
them.
In Scotland, more than one fifth, perhaps more than one third part of
the
whole lands in the country, are at present supposed to be under strict
entail.
Great
tracts of uncultivated land were in this manner not only engrossed by
particular
families, but the possibility of their being divided again was as
much as
possible precluded for ever. It seldom happens, however, that a
great
proprietor is a great improver. In the disorderly times which gave
birth
to those barbarous institutions, the great proprietor was sufficiently
employed
in defending his own territories, or in extending his jurisdiction
and
authority over those of his neighbours. He had no leisure to attend to
the
cultivation and improvement of land. When the establishment of law and
order
afforded him this leisure, he often wanted the inclination, and almost
always
the requisite abilities. If the expense of his house and person
either
equalled or exceeded his revenue, as it did very frequently, he had
no
stock to employ in this manner. If he was an economist, he generally
found
it more profitable to employ his annual savings in new purchases than
in the
improvement of his old estate. To improve land with profit, like all
other
commercial projects, requires an exact attention to small savings and
small
gains, of which a man born to a great fortune, even though naturally
frugal,
is very seldom capable. The situation of such a person naturally
disposes
him to attend rather to ornament, which pleases his fancy, than to
profit,
for which he has so little occasion. The elegance of his dress, of
his equipage,
of his house and household furniture, are objects which, from
his
infancy, he has been accustomed to have some anxiety about. The turn of
mind
which this habit naturally forms, follows him when he comes to think of
the
improvement of land. He embellishes, perhaps, four or five hundred acres
in the
neighbourhood of his house, at ten times the expense which the land
is
worth after all his improvements; and finds, that if he was to improve
his
whole estate in the same manner, and he has little taste for any other,
he
would be a bankrupt before he had finished the tenth part of it. There
still
remain, in both parts of the united kingdom, some great estates which
have
continued, without interruption, in the hands of the same family since
the times
of feudal anarchy. Compare the present condition of those estates
with
the possessions of the small proprietors in their neighbourhood, and
you
will require no other argument to convince you how unfavourable such
extensive
property is to improvement.
If
little improvement was to be expected from such great proprietors, still
less
was to be hoped for from those who occupied the land under them. In the
ancient
state of Europe, the occupiers of land were all tenants at will.
They
were all, or almost all, slaves, but their slavery was of a milder kind
than
that known among the ancient Greeks and Romans, or even in our West
Indian
colonies. They were supposed to belong more directly to the land than
to
their master. They could, therefore, be sold with it, but not separately.
They
could marry, provided it was with the consent of their master; and he
could
not afterwards dissolve the marriage by selling the man and wife to
different
persons. If he maimed or murdered any of them, he was liable to
some
penalty, though generally but to a small one. They were not, however,
capable
of acquiring property. Whatever they acquired was acquired to their
master,
and he could take it from them at pleasure. Whatever cultivation and
improvement
could be carried on by means of such slaves, was properly
carried
on by their master. It was at his expense. The seed, the cattle, and
the
instruments of husbandry, were all his. It was for his benefit. Such
slaves
could acquire nothing but their daily maintenance. It was properly
the
proprietor himself, therefore, that in this case occupied his own lands,
and
cultivated them by his own bondmen. This species of slavery still
subsists
in Russia, Poland, Hungary, Bohemia, Moravia, and other parts of
Germany.
It is only in the western and south-western provinces of Europe
that it
has gradually been abolished altogether.
But if
great improvements are seldom to be expected from great proprietors,
they
are least of all to be expected when they employ slaves for their
workmen.
The experience of all ages and nations, I believe, demonstrates
that
the work done by slaves, though it appears to cost only their
maintenance,
is in the end the dearest of any. A person who can acquire no
property
can have no other interest but to eat as much and to labour as
little
as possible. Whatever work he does beyond what is sufficient to
purchase
his own maintenance, can be squeezed out of him by violence only,
and not
by any interest of his own. In ancient Italy, how much the
cultivation
of corn degenerated, how unprofitable it became to the master,
when it
fell under the management of slaves, is remarked both by Pliny and
Columella.
In the time of Aristotle, it had not been much better in ancient
Greece.
Speaking of the ideal republic described in the laws of Plato, to
maintain
5000 idle men (the number of warriors supposed necessary for its
defence),
together with their women and servants, would require, he says, a
territory
of boundless extent and fertility, like the plains of Babylon.
The
pride of man makes him love to domineer, and nothing mortifies him so
much as
to be obliged to condescend to persuade his inferiors. Wherever the
law
allows it, and the nature of the work can afford it, therefore, he will
generally
prefer the service of slaves to that of freemen. The planting of
sugar
and tobacco can afford the expense of slave cultivation. The raising
of
corn, it seems, in the present times, cannot. In the English colonies, of
which
the principal produce is corn, the far greater part of the work is
done by
freemen. The late resolution of the Quakers in Pennsylvania, to set
at
liberty all their negro slaves, may satisfy us that their number cannot
be very
great. Had they made any considerable part of their property, such a
resolution
could never have been agreed to. In our sugar colonies., on the
contrary,
the whole work is done by slaves, and in our tobacco colonies a
very
great part of it. The profits of a sugar plantation in any of our West
Indian
colonies, are generally much greater than those of any other
cultivation
that is known either in Europe or America ; and the profits of a
tobacco
plantation, though inferior to those of sugar, are superior to
those
of corn, as has already been observed. Both can afford the expense of
slave
cultivation but sugar can afford it still better than tobacco. The
number
of negroes, accordingly, is much greater, in proportion to that of
whites,
in our sugar than in our tobacco colonies.
To the
slave cultivators of ancient times. gradually succeeded a species of
farmers,
known at present in France by the name of metayers. They are called
in
Latin Coloni Partiarii. They have been so long in disuse in England, that
at
present I know no English name for them. The proprietor furnished them
with
the seed, cattle, and instruments of husbandry, the whole stock, in
short,
necessary for cultivating the farm. The produce was divided equally
between
the proprietor and the farmer, after setting aside what was judged
necessary
for keeping up the stock, which was restored to the proprietor,
when
the farmer either quitted or was turned out of the farm.
Land
occupied by such tenants is properly cultivated at the expense of the
proprietors,
as much as that occupied by slaves. There is, however, one very
essential
difference between them. Such tenants, being freemen, are capable
of
acquiring property; and having a certain proportion of the produce of the
land,
they have a plain interest that the whole produce should be as great
as
possible, in order that their own proportion may be so. A slave, on the
contrary,
who can acquire nothing but his maintenance, consults his own
ease,
by making the land produce as little as possible over and above that
maintenance.
It is probable that it was partly upon account of this
advantage,
and partly upon account of the encroachments which the
sovereigns,
always jealous of the great lords, gradually encouraged their
villains
to make upon their authority, and which seem, at least, to have
been
such as rendered this species of servitude altogether inconvenient,
that
tenure in villanage gradually wore out through the greater part of
Europe.
The time and manner, however, in which so important a revolution was
brought
about, is one of the most obscure points in modern history. The
church
of Rome claims great merit in it ; and it is certain, that so early
as the
twelfth century, Alexander III. published a bull for the general
emancipation
of slaves. It seems, however, to have been rather a pious
exhortation,
than a law to which exact obedience was required from the
faithful.
Slavery continued to take place almost universally for several
centuries
afterwards, till it was gradually abolished by the joint operation
of the
two interests above mentioned ; that of the proprietor on the one
hand,
and that of the sovereign on the other. A villain, enfranchised, and
at the
same time allowed to continue in possession of the land, having no
stock
of his own, could cultivate it only by means of what the landlord
advanced
to him, and must therefore have been what the French call a
metayer.
It
could never, however, be the interest even of this last species of
cultivators,
to lay out, in the further improvement of the land, any part of
the
little stock which they might save from their own share of the produce ;
because
the landlord, who laid out nothing, was to get one half of whatever
it
produced. The tithe, which is but a tenth of the produce, is found to be
a very
great hindrance to improvement. A tax, therefore, which amounted to
one
half, must have been an effectual bar to it. It might be the interest of
a
metayer to make the land produce as much as could be brought out of it by
means
of the stock furnished by the proprietor ; but it could never be his
interest
to mix any part of his own with it. In France, where five parts out
of six
of the whole kingdom are said to be still occupied by this species of
cultivators,
the proprietors complain, that their metayers take every
opportunity
of employing their master's cattle rather in carriage than in
cultivation
; because, in the one case, they get the whole profits to
themselves,
in the other they share them with their landlord. This species
of
tenants still subsists in some parts of Scotland. They are called
steel-bow
tenants. Those ancient English tenants, who are said by
Chief-Baron
Gilbert and Dr Blackstone to have been rather bailiffs of the
landlord
than farmers, properly so called, were probably of the same kind.
To this
species of tenantry succeeded, though by very slow degrees, farmers,
properly
so called, who cultivated the land with their own stock, paying a
rent
certain to the landlord. When such farmers have a lease for a term of
years,
they may sometimes find it for their interest to lay out part of
their
capital in the further improvement of the farm; because they may
sometimes
expect to recover it, with a large profit, before the expiration
of the
lease. The possession, even of such farmers, however, was long
extremely
precarious, and still is so in many parts of Europe. They could,
before
the expiration of their term, be legally ousted of their leases by a
new
purchaser; in England, even, by the fictitious action of a common
recovery.
If they were turned out illegally by the violence of their master,
the
action by which they obtained redress was extremely imperfect. It did
not
always reinstate them in the possession of the land, but gave them
damages,
which never amounted to a real loss. Even in England, the country,
perhaps
of Europe, where the yeomanry has always been most respected, it was
not
till about the 14th of Henry VII. that the action of ejectment was
invented,
by which the tenant recovers, not damages only, but possession,
and in
which his claim is not necessarily concluded by the uncertain
decision
of a single assize. This action has been found so effectual a
remedy,
that, in the modern practice, when the landlord has occasion to sue
for the
possession of the land, he seldom makes use of the actions which
properly
belong to him as a landlord, the writ of right or the writ of
entry,
but sues in the name of his tenant, by the writ of ejectment. In
England,
therefore the security of the tenant is equal to that of the
proprietor.
In England, besides, a lease for life of forty shillings a-year
value
is a freehold, and entitles the lessee to a vote for a member of
parliament
; and as a great part of the yeomanry have freeholds of this
kind,
the whole order becomes respectable to their landlords, on account of
the
political consideration which this gives them. There is, I believe,
nowhere
in Europe, except in England, any instance of the tenant building
upon
the land of which he had no lease, and trusting that the honour of his
landlord
would take no advantage of so important an improvement. Those laws
and
customs, so favourable to the yeomanry, have perhaps contributed more to
the
present grandeur of England, than all their boasted regulations of
commerce
taken together.
The law
which secures the longest leases against successors of every kind,
is, so
far as I know, peculiar to Great Britain. It was introduced into
Scotland
so early as 1449, by a law of James II. Its beneficial influence,
however,
has been much obstructed by entails ; the heirs of entail being
generally
restrained from letting leases for any long term of years,
frequently
for more than one year. A late act of parliament has, in this
respect,
somewhat slackened their fetters, though they are still by much too
strait.
In Scotland, besides, as no leasehold gives a vote for a member of
parliament,
the yeomanry are upon this account less respectable to their
landlords
than in England.
In
other parts of Europe, after it was found convenient to secure tenants
both
against heirs and purchasers, the term of their security was still
limited
to a very short period ; in France, for example, to nine years from
the
commencement of the lease. It has in that country, indeed, been lately
extended
to twentyseven, a period still too short to encourage the tenant to
make
the most important improvements. The proprietors of land were
anciently
the legislators of every part of Europe. The laws relating to
land,
therefore, were all calculated for what they supposed the interest of
the
proprietor. It was for his interest, they had imagined, that no lease
granted
by any of his predecessors should hinder him from enjoying, during a
long
term of years, the full value of his land. Avarice and injustice are
always
short-sighted, and they did not foresee how much this regulation must
obstruct
improvement, and thereby hurt, in the long-run, the real interest
of the
landlord.
The
farmers, too, besides paying the rent, were anciently, it was supposed,
bound
to perform a great number of services to the landlord, which were
seldom
either specified in the lease, or regulated by any precise rule, but
by the
use and wont of the manor or barony. These services, therefore. being
almost
entirely arbitrary, subjected the tenant to many vexations. In
Scotland
the abolition of all services not precisely stipulated in the
lease,
has, in the course of a few years, very much altered for the better
the
condition of the yeomanry of that country.
The
public services to which the yeomanry were bound, were not less
arbitrary
than the private ones. To make and maintain the high roads, a
servitude
which still subsists, I believe, everywhere, though with different
degrees
of oppression in different countries, was not the only one. When the
king's
troops, when his household, or his officers of any kind, passed
through
any part of the country, the yeomanry were bound to provide them
with
horses, carriages, and provisions, at a price regulated by the
purveyor.
Great Britain is, I believe, the only monarchy in Europe where the
oppression
of purveyance has been entirely abolished. It still subsists in
France
and Germany.
The
public taxes, to which they were subject, were as irregular and
oppressive
as the services The ancient lords, though extremely unwilling to
grant,
themselves, any pecuniary aid to their sovereign, easily allowed him
to
tallage, as they called it, their tenants, and had not knowledge enough
to
foresee how much this must, in the end, affect their own revenue. The
taille,
as it still subsists in France. may serve as an example of those
ancient
tallages. It is a tax upon the supposed profits of the farmer, which
they
estimate by the stock that he has upon the farm. It is his interest,
therefore,
to appear to have as little as possible, and consequently to
employ
as little as possible in its cultivation, and none in its
improvement.
Should any stock happen to accumulate in the hands of a
French
farmer, the taille is almost equal to a prohibition of its ever being
employed
upon the land. This tax, besides, is supposed to dishonour whoever
is
subject to it, and to degrade him below, not only the rank of a
gentleman,
but that of a burgher ; and whoever rents the lands of another
becomes
subject to it. No gentleman, nor even any burgher, who has stock,
will
submit to this degradation. This tax, therefore, not only hinders the
stock
which accumulates upon the land from being employed in its
improvement,
but drives away all other stock from it. The ancient tenths and
fifteenths,
so usual in England in former times, seem, so far as they
affected
the land, to have been taxes of the same nature with the taille.
Under
all these discouragements, little improvement could he expected from
the
occupiers of land. That order of people, with all the liberty and
security
which law can give, must always improve under great disadvantage.
The
farmer, compared with the proprietor, is as a merchant who trades with
burrowed
money, compared with one who trades with his own. The stock of both
may
improve; but that of the one, with only equal good conduct, must always
improve
more slowly than that of the other, on account of the large share
of the
profits which is consumed by the interest of the loan. The lands
cultivated
by the farmer must, in the same manner, with only equal good
conduct,
be improved more slowly than those cultivated by the proprietor,
on
account of the large share of the produce which is consumed in the rent,
and
which, had the farmer been proprietor, he might have employed in the
further
improvement of the land. The station of a farmer, besides, is, from
the
nature of things, inferior to that of a proprietor. Through the greater
part of
Europe, the yeomanry are regarded as an inferior rank of people,
even to
the better sort of tradesmen and mechanics, and in all parts of
Europe
to the great merchants and master manufacturers. It can seldom
happen,
therefore, that a man of any considerable stock should quit the
superior,
in order to place himself in an inferior station. Even in the
present
state of Europe, therefore, little stock is likely to go from any
other
profession to the improvement of land in the way of farming. More
does,
perhaps, in Great Britain than in any other country, though even there
the
great stocks which are in some places employed in farming, have
generally
been acquired by fanning, the trade, perhaps, in which, of all
others,
stock is commonly acquired most slowly.
After small proprietors,
however,
rich and great farmers are in every country the principal
improvers.
There are more such, perhaps, in England than in any other
European
monarchy. In the republican governments of Holland, and of Berne
in
Switzerland, the farmers are said to be not inferior to those of England.
The
ancient policy of Europe was, over and above all this, unfavourable to
the
improvement and cultivation of land, whether carried on by the
proprietor
or by the farmer ; first, by the general prohibition of the
exportation
of corn, without a special licence, which seems to have been a
very
universal regulation ; and, secondly, by the restraints which were laid
upon
the inland commerce, not only of corn, but of almost every other part
of the
produce of the farm, by the absurd laws against engrossers,
regraters,
and forestallers, and by the privileges of fairs and markets. It
has
already been observed in what manner the prohibition of the exportation
of
corn, together with some encouragement given to the importation of
foreign
corn, obstructed the cultivation of ancient Italy, naturally the most
fertile
country in Europe, and at that time the seat of the greatest empire
in the
world. To what degree such restraints upon the inland commerce of
this
commodity, joined to the general prohibition of exportation, must have
discouraged
the cultivation of countries less fertile, and less favourably
circumstanced,
it is not, perhaps, very easy to imagine.
CHAPTER III.
OF THE
RISE AND PROGRESS OF CITIES AND TOWNS, AFTER THE FALL OF THE ROMAN
EMPIRE.
The
inhabitants of cities and towns were, after the fall of the Roman
empire,
not more favoured than those of the country. They consisted, indeed,
of a
very different order of people from the first inhabitants of the
ancient
republics of Greece and Italy. These last were composed chiefly of
the
proprietors of lands, among whom the public territory was originally
divided,
and who found it convenient to build their houses in the
neighbourhood
of one another, and to surround them with a wall, for the sake
of
common defence. After the fall of the Roman empire, on the contrary, the
proprietors
of land seem generally to have lived in fortified castles on
their
own estates, and in the midst of their own tenants and dependants. The
towns
were chiefly inhabited by tradesmen and mechanics, who seem, in those
days,
to have been of servile, or very nearly of servile condition. The
privileges
which we find granted by ancient charters to the inhabitants of
some of
the principal towns in Europe, sufficiently show what they were
before
those grants. The people to whom it is granted as a privilege, that
they
might give away their own daughters in marriage without the consent of
their
lord, that upon their death their own children, and not their lord,
should
succeed to their goods, and that they might dispose of their own
effects
by will, must, before those grants, have been either altogether, or
very
nearly, in the same state of villanage with the occupiers of land in
the
country.
They
seem, indeed, to have been a very poor, mean set of people, who seemed
to
travel about with their goods from place to place, and from fair to fair,
like
the hawkers and pedlars of the present times. In all the different
countries
of Europe then, in the same manner as in several of the Tartar
governments
of Asia at present, taxes used to be levied upon the persons and
goods
of travellers, when they passed through certain manors, when they went
over
certain bridges, when they carried about their goods from place to
place
in a fair, when they erected in it a booth or stall to sell them in.
These
different taxes were known in England by the names of passage,
pontage,
lastage, and stallage. Sometimes the king, sometimes a great lord,
who
had, it seems, upon some occasions, authority to do this, would grant to
particular
traders, to such particularly as lived in their own demesnes, a
general
exemption from such taxes. Such traders, though in other respects of
servile,
or very nearly of servile condition, were upon this account called
free
traders. They, in return, usually paid to their protector a sort of
annual
poll-tax. In those days protection was seldom granted without a
valuable
consideration, and this tax might perhaps be considered as
compensation
for what their patrons might lose by their exemption from other
taxes.
At first, both those poll-taxes and those exemptions seem to have
been
altogether personal, and to have affected only particular individuals,
during
either their lives, or the pleasure of their protectors. In the very
imperfect
accounts which have been published from Doomsday-book, of several
of the
towns of England, mention is frequently made, sometimes of the tax
which
particular burghers paid, each of them, either to the king, or to some
other
great lord, for this sort of protection, and sometimes of the general
amount
only of all those taxes. {see Brady's Historical Treatise of Cities
and
Boroughs, p. 3. etc.}
But how
servile soever may have been originally the condition of the
inhabitants
of the towns, it appears evidently, that they arrived at liberty
and
independency much earlier than the occupiers of land in the country.
That
part of the king's revenue which arose from such poll-taxes in any
particular
town, used commonly to be let in farm, during a term of years,
for a
rent certain, sometimes to the sheriff of the county, and sometimes to
other
persons. The burghers themselves frequently got credit enough to be
admitted
to farm the revenues of this sort winch arose out of their own
town,
they becoming jointly and severally answerable for the whole rent.
{See
Madox, Firma Burgi, p. 18; also History of the Exchequer, chap. 10,
sect.
v, p. 223, first edition.} To let a
farm in this manner, was quite
agreeable
to the usual economy of, I believe, the sovereigns of all the
different
countries of Europe, who used frequently to let whole manors to
all the
tenants of those manors, they becoming jointly and severally
answerable
for the whole rent ; but in return being allowed to collect it in
their
own way, and to pay it into the king's exchequer by the hands of their
own
bailiff, and being thus altogether freed from the insolence of the
king's
officers; a circumstance in those days regarded as of the greatest
importance.
At
first, the farm of the town was probably let to the burghers, in the same
manner
as it had been to other farmers, for a term of years only. In process
of
time, however, it seems to have become the general practice to grant it
to them
in fee, that is for ever, reserving a rent certain, never afterwards
to be
augmented. The payment having thus become perpetual, the exemptions,
in
return, for which it was made, naturally became perpetual too. Those
exemptions,
therefore, ceased to be personal, and could not afterwards be
considered
as belonging to individuals, as individuals, but as burghers of a
particular
burgh, which, upon this account, was called a free burgh, for the
same
reason that they had been called free burghers or free traders.
Along
with this grant, the important privileges, above mentioned, that they
might
give away their own daughters in marriage, that their children should
succeed
to them, and that they might dispose of their own effects by will,
were generally
bestowed upon the burghers of the town to whom it was given.
Whether
such privileges had before been usually granted, along with the
freedom
of trade, to particular burghers, as individuals, I know not. I
reckon
it not improbable that they were, though I cannot produce any direct
evidence
of it. But however this may have been, the principal attributes of
villanage
and slavery being thus taken away from them, they now at least
became
really free, in our present sense of the word freedom.
Nor was
this all. They were generally at the same time erected into a
commonalty
or corporation, with the privilege of having magistrates and a
town-council
of their own, of making bye-laws for their own government, of
building
walls for their own defence, and of reducing all their inhabitants
under a
sort of military discipline, by obliging them to watch and ward;
that
is, as anciently understood, to guard and defend those walls against
all
attacks and surprises, by night as well as by day. In England they were
generally
exempted from suit to the hundred and county courts : and all such
pleas
as should arise among them, the pleas of the crown excepted, were left
to the
decision of their own magistrates. In other countries, much greater
and
more extensive jurisdictions were frequently granted to them. {See
Madox,
Firma Burgi. See also Pfeffel in the Remarkable events under Frederick
II. and
his Successors of the House of Suabia.}
It
might, probably, be necessary to grant to such towns as were admitted to
farm
their own revenues, some sort of compulsive jurisdiction to oblige
their
own citizens to make payment. In those disorderly times, it might have
been
extremely inconvenient to have left them to seek this sort of justice
from
any other tribunal. But it must seem extraordinary, that the sovereigns
of all
the different countries of Europe should have exchanged in this
manner
for a rent certain, never more to be augmented, that branch of their
revenue,
which was, perhaps, of all others, the most likely to be improved
by the
natural course of things, without either expense or attention of
their
own ; and that they should, besides, have in this manner voluntarily
erected
a sort of independent republics in the heart of their own dominions.
In
order to understand this, it must be remembered, that, in those days, the
sovereign
of perhaps no country in Europe was able to protect, through the
whole
extent of his dominions, the weaker part of his subjects from the
oppression
of the great lords. Those whom the law could not protect, and who
were
not strong enough to defend themselves, were obliged either to have
recourse
to the protection of some great lord, and in order to obtain it, to
become
either his slaves or vassals; or to enter into a league of mutual
defence
for the common protection of one another. The inhabitants of cities
and
burghs, considered as single individuals, had no power to defend
themselves;
but by entering into a league of mutual defence with their
neighbours,
they were capable of making no contemptible resistance. The
lords
despised the burghers, whom they considered not only as a different
order,
but as a parcel of emancipated slaves, almost of a different species
from
themselves. The wealth of the burghers never failed to provoke their
envy
and indignation, and they plundered them upon every occasion without
mercy
or remorse. The burghers naturally hated and feared the lords. The
king
hated and feared them too ; but though, perhaps, he might despise, he
had no
reason either to hate or fear the burghers. Mutual interest,
therefore,
disposed them to support the king, and the king to support them
against
the lords. They were the enemies of his enemies, and it was his
interest
to render them as secure and independent of those. enemies as he
could.
By granting them magistrates of their own, the privilege of making
bye-laws
for their own government, that of building walls for their own
defence,
and that of reducing all their inhabitants under a sort of military
discipline,
he gave them all the means of security and independency of the
barons
which it was in his power to bestow. Without the establishment of
some
regular government of this kind, without some authority to compel their
inhabitants
to act according to some certain plan or system, no voluntary
league
of mutual defence could either have afforded them any permanent
security,
or have enabled them to give the king any considerable support. By
granting
them the farm of their own town in fee, he took away from those
whom he
wished to have for his friends, and, if one may say so, for his
allies,
all ground of jealousy and suspicion, that he was ever afterwards to
oppress
them, either by raising the farm-rent of their town, or by granting
it to
some other farmer.
The
princes who lived upon the worst terms with their barons, seem
accordingly
to have been the most liberal in grants of this kind to their
burghs.
King John of England, for example, appears to have been a most
munificent
benefactor to his towns. {See Madox.}
Philip I. of France lost
all
authority over his barons. Towards the end of his reign, his son Lewis,
known
afterwards by the name of Lewis the Fat, consulted, according to
Father
Daniel, with the bishops of the royal demesnes, concerning the most
proper
means of restraining the violence of the great lords. Their advice
consisted
of two different proposals. One was to erect a new order of
jurisdiction,
by establishing magistrates and a town-council in every
considerable
town of his demesnes. The other was to form a new militia, by
making
the inhabitants of those towns, under the command of their own
magistrates,
march out upon proper occasions to the assistance of the king.
It is
from this period, according to the French antiquarians, that we are to
date
the institution of the magistrates and councils of cities in France. It
was
during the unprosperous reigns of the princes of the house of Suabia,
that
the greater part of the free towns of Germany received the first grants
of
their privileges, and that the famous Hanseatic league first became
formidable.
{See Pfeffel.}
The
militia of the cities seems, in those times, not to have been inferior
to that
of the country ; and as they could be more readily assembled upon
any
sudden occasion, they frequently had the advantage in their disputes
with
the neighbouring lords. In countries such as Italy or Switzerland, in
which,
on account either of their distance from the principal seat of
government,
of the natural strength of the country itself, or of some other
reason,
the sovereign came to lose the whole of his authority; the cities
generally
became independent republics, and conquered all the nobility in
their
neighbourhood; obliging them to pull down their castles in the
country,
and to live, like other peaceable inhabitants, in the city. This is
the
short history of the republic of Berne, as well as of several other
cities
in Switzerland. If you except Venice, for of that city the history is
somewhat
different, it is the history of all the considerable Italian
republics,
of which so great a number arose and perished between the end of
the
twelfth and the beginning of the sixteenth century.
In
countries such as France and England, where the authority of the
sovereign,
though frequently very low, never was destroyed altogether, the
cities
had no opportunity of becoming entirely independent. They became,
however,
so considerable, that the sovereign could impose no tax upon them,
besides
the stated farm-rent of the town, without their own consent. They
were,
therefore, called upon to send deputies to the general assembly of the
states
of the kingdom, where they might join with the clergy and the barons
in
granting, upon urgent occasions, some extraordinary aid to the king.
Being
generally, too, more favourable to his power, their deputies seem
sometimes
to have been employed by him as a counterbalance in those
assemblies
to the authority of the great lords. Hence the origin of the
representation
of burghs in the states-general of all great monarchies in
Europe.
Order
and good government, and along with them the liberty and security of
individuals,
were in this manner established in cities, at a time when the
occupiers
of land in the country, were exposed to every sort of violence.
But men
in this defenceless state naturally content themselves with their
necessary
subsistence ; because, to acquire more, might only tempt the
injustice
of their oppressors. On the contrary, when they are secure of
enjoying
the fruits of their industry, they naturally exert it to better
their
condition, and to acquire not only the necessaries, but the
conveniencies
and elegancies of life. That industry, therefore, which aims
at
something more than necessary subsistence, was established in cities long
before
it was commonly practised by the occupiers of land in the country.
If, in
the hands of a poor cultivator, oppressed with the servitude of
villanage,
some little stock should accumulate, he would naturally conceal
it with
great care from his master, to whom it would otherwise have
belonged,
and take the first opportunity of running away to a town. The law
was at
that time so indulgent to the inhabitants of towns, and so desirous
of
diminishing the authority of the lords over those of the country, that if
he
could conceal himself there from the pursuit of his lord for a year, he
was
free for ever. Whatever stock, therefore, accumulated in the hands of
the
industrious part of the inhabitants of the country, naturally took
refuge
in cities, as the only sanctuaries in which it could be secure to the
person
that acquired it.
The
inhabitants of a city, it is true, must always ultimately derive their
subsistence,
and the whole materials and means of their industry, from the
country.
But those of a city, situated near either the sea-coast or the
banks
of a navigable river, are not necessarily confined to derive them from
the
country in their neighbourhood.
They have a much wider range, and
may
draw them from the most remote corners of the world, either in exchange
for the
manufactured produce of their own industry, or by performing the
office
of carriers between distant countries, and exchanging the produce of
one for
that of another. A city might, in this manner, grow up to great
wealth
and splendour, while not only the country in its neighbourhood, but
all
those to which it traded, were in poverty and wretchedness. Each of
those
countries, perhaps, taken singly, could afford it but a small part,
either
of its subsistence or of its employment ; but all of them taken
together,
could afford it both a great subsistence and a great employment.
There
were, however, within the narrow circle of the commerce of those
times,
some countries that were opulent and industrious. Such was the Greek
empire
as long as it subsisted, and that of the Saracens during the reigns
of the
Abassides. Such, too, was Egypt till it was conquered by the Turks,
some
part of the coast of Barbary, and all those provinces of Spain which
were
under the government of the Moors.
The
cities of Italy seem to have been the first in Europe which were raised
by
commerce to any considerable degree of opulence. Italy lay in the centre
of what
was at that time the improved and civilized part of the world. The
crusades,
too, though, by the great waste of stock and destruction of
inhabitants
which they occasioned, they must necessarily have retarded the
progress
of the greater part of Europe, were extremely favourable to that of
some
Italian cities. The great armies which marched from all parts to the
conquest
of the Holy Land, gave extraordinary encouragement to the shipping
of
Venice, Genoa, and Pisa, sometimes in transporting them thither, and
always
in supplying them with provisions. They were the commissaries, if one
may say
so, of those armies ; and the most destructive frenzy that ever
befel
the European nations, was a source of opulence to those republics.
The
inhabitants of trading cities, by importing the improved manufactures
and
expensive luxuries of richer countries, afforded some food to the vanity
of the
great proprietors, who eagerly purchased them with great quantities
of the
rude produce of their own lands. The commerce of a great part of
Europe
in those times, accordingly, consisted chiefly in the exchange of
their
own rude, for the manufactured produce of more civilized nations. Thus
the
wool of England used to be exchanged for the wines of France, and the
fine
cloths of Flanders, in the same manner as the corn in Poland is at this
day,
exchanged for the wines and brandies of France, and for the silks and
velvets
of France and Italy.
A taste
for the finer and more improved manufactures was, in this manner,
introduced
by foreign commerce into countries where no such works were
carried
on. But when this taste became so general as to occasion a
considerable
demand, the merchants, in order to save the expense of carriage,
naturally
endeavoured to establish some manufactures of the same kind in
their
own country. Hence the origin of the first manufactures for distant
sale,
that seem to have been established in the western provinces of Europe,
after
the fall of the Roman empire.
No
large country, it must be observed, ever did or could subsist without
some
sort of manufactures being carried on in it ; and when it is said of
any
such country that it has no manufactures, it must always be understood
of the
finer and more improved, or of such as are fit for distant sale. In
every
large country both the clothing and household furniture or the far
greater
part of the people, are the produce of their own industry. This is
even
more universally the case in those poor countries which are commonly
said to
have no manufactures, than in those rich ones that are said to
abound
in them. In the latter you will generally find, both in the clothes
and
household furniture of the lowest rank of people, a much greater
proportion
of foreign productions than in the former.
Those
manufactures which are fit for distant sale, seem to have been
introduced
into different countries in two different ways.
Sometimes
they have been introduced in the manner above mentioned, by the
violent
operation, if one may say so, of the stocks of particular merchants
and undertakers,
who established them in imitation of some foreign
manufactures
of the same kind. Such manufactures, therefore, are the offspring
of
foreign commerce; and such seem to have been the ancient manufactures of
silks,
velvets, and brocades, which flourished in Lucca during the
thirteenth
century. They were banished from thence by the tyranny of one of
Machiavel's
heroes, Castruccio Castracani. In 1310, nine hundred families
were
driven out of Lucca, of whom thirty-one retired to Venice, and offered
to
introduce there the silk manufacture. {See Sandi Istoria civile de
Vinezia,
part 2 vol. i, page 247 and 256.} Their offer was accepted, many
privileges
were conferred upon them, and they began the manufacture with
three
hundred workmen. Such, too, seem to have been the manufactures of fine
cloths
that anciently flourished in Flanders, and which were introduced into
England
in the beginning of the reign of Elizabeth, and such are the present
silk
manufactures of Lyons and Spitalfields. Manufactures introduced in this
manner
are generally employed upon foreign materials, being imitations of
foreign
manufactures. When the Venetian manufacture was first established,
the
materials were all brought from Sicily and the Levant. The more ancient
manufacture
of Lucca was likewise carried on with foreign materials. The
cultivation
of mulberry trees, and the breeding of silk-woms, seem not to
have
been common in the northern parts of Italy before the sixteenth
century.
Those arts were not introduced into France till the reign of
Charles
IX. The manufactures of Flanders were carried on chiefly with
Spanish
and English wool. Spanish wool was the material, not of the first
woollen
manufacture of England, but of the first that was fit for distant
sale.
More than one half the materials of the Lyons manufacture is at this
day
foreign silk; when it was first established, the whole, or very nearly
the
whole, was so. No part of the materials of the Spitalfields manufacture
is ever
likely to be the produce of England. The seat of such manufactures,
as they
are generally introduced by the scheme and project of a few
individuals,
is sometimes established in a maritime city, and sometimes in
an
inland town, according as their interest, judgment, or caprice, happen to
determine.
At
other times, manufactures for distant sale grow up naturally, and as it
were of
their own accord, by the gradual refinement of those household and
coarser
manufactures which must at all times be carried on even in the
poorest
and rudest countries. Such manufactures are generally employed upon
the
materials which the country produces, and they seem frequently to have
been
first refined and improved In such inland countries as were not,
indeed,
at a very great, but at a considerable distance from the sea-coast,
and
sometimes even from all water carriage. An inland country, naturally
fertile
and easily cultivated, produces a great surplus of provisions beyond
what is
necessary for maintaining the cultivators; and on account of the
expense
of land carriage, and inconveniency of river navigation, it may
frequently
be difficult to send this surplus abroad. Abundance, therefore,
renders
provisions cheap, and encourages a great number of workmen to settle
in the
neighbourhood, who find that their industry can there procure them
more of
the necessaries and conveniencies of life than in other places. They
work up
the materials of manufacture which the land produces, and exchange
their
finished work, or, what is the same thing, the price of it, for more
materials
and provisions. They give a new value to the surplus part of the
rude
produce, by saving the expense of carrying it to the water-side, or to
some
distant market ; and they furnish the cultivators with something in
exchange
for it that is either useful or agreeable to them, upon easier
terms
than they could have obtained it before. The cultivators get a better
price
for their surplus produce, and can purchase cheaper other
conveniencies
which they have occasion for. They are thus both encouraged
and
enabled to increase this surplus produce by a further improvement and
better
cultivation of the land; and as the fertility of she land had given
birth
to the manufacture, so the progress of the manufacture reacts upon the
land,
and increases still further it's fertility. The manufacturers first
supply
the neighbourhood, and afterwards, as their work improves and
refines,
more distant markets. For though neither the rude produce, nor even
the
coarse manufacture, could, without the greatest difficulty, support the
expense
of a considerable land-carriage, the refined and improved
manufacture
easily may. In a small bulk it frequently contains the price of
a great
quantity of rude produce. A piece of fine cloth, for example which
weighs
only eighty pounds, contains in it the price, not only of eighty
pounds
weight of wool, but sometimes of several thousand weight of corn, the
maintenance
of the different working people, and of their immediate
employers.
The corn which could with difficulty have been carried abroad in
its own
shape, is in this manner virtually exported in that of the complete
manufacture,
and may easily be sent to the remotest corners of the world. In
this
manner have grown up naturally, and, as it were, of their own accord,
the
manufactures of Leeds, Halifax, Sheffield, Birmingham, and
Wolverhampton.
Such manufactures are the offspring of agriculture. In the
modern
history of Europe, their extension and improvement have generally
been
posterior to those which were the offspring of foreign commerce.
England
was noted for the manufacture of fine cloths made of Spanish wool,
more
than a century before any of those which now flourish in the places
above
mentioned were fit for foreign sale. The extension and improvement of
these
last could not take place but in consequence of the extension and
improvement
of agriculture, the last and greatest effect of foreign
commerce,
and of the manufactures immediately introduced by it, and which I
shall
now proceed to explain.
CHAPTER IV.
HOW THE
COMMERCE OF TOWNS CONTRIBUTED TO THE IMPROVEMENT OF THE COUNTRY.
The
increase and riches of commercial and manufacturing towns contributed to
the
improvement and cultivation of the countries to which they belonged, in
three
different ways :
First,
by affording a great and ready market for the rude produce of the
country,
they gave encouragement to its cultivation and further improvement.
This
benefit was not even confined to the countries in which they were
situated,
but extended more or less to all those with which they had any
dealings.
To all of them they afforded a market for some part either of
their
rude or manufactured produce, and, consequently, gave some
encouragement
to the industry and improvement of all. Their own country,
however,
on account of its neighbourhood, necessarily derived the greatest
benefit
from this market. Its rude produce being charged with less carriage,
the
traders could pay the growers a better price for it, and yet afford it
as
cheap to the consumers as that of more distant countries.
Secondly,
the wealth acquired by the inhabitants of cities was frequently
employed
in purchasing such lands as were to be sold, of which a great part
would
frequently be uncultivated. Merchants are commonly ambitious of
becoming
country gentlemen, and, when they do, they are generally the best
of all
improvers. A merchant is accustomed to employ his money chiefly in
profitable
projects ; whereas a mere country gentleman is accustomed to
employ
it chiefly in expense. The one often sees his money go from him, and
return
to him again with a profit; the other, when once he parts with it,
very
seldom expects to see any more of it. Those different habits naturally
affect
their temper and disposition in every sort of business. The merchant
is
commonly a bold, a country gentleman a timid undertaker. The one is not
afraid
to lay out at once a large capital upon the improvement of his land,
when he
has a probable prospect of raising the value of it in proportion to
the
expense ; the other, if he has any capital, which is not always the
case,
seldom ventures to employ it in this manner. If he improves at all, it
is
commonly not with a capital, but with what he can save out or his annual
revenue.
Whoever has had the fortune to live in a mercantile town, situated
in an
unimproved country, must have frequently observed how much more
spirited
the operations of merchants were in this way, than those of mere
country
gentlemen. The habits, besides, of order, economy, and attention, to
which
mercantile business naturally forms a merchant, render him much fitter
to
execute, with profit and success, any project of improvement.
Thirdly,
and lastly, commerce and manufactures gradually introduced order
and
good government, and with them the liberty and security of individuals,
among
the inhabitants of the country, who had before lived almost in a
continual
state of war with their neighbours, and of servile dependency upon
their
superiors. This, though it has been the least observed, is by far the
most
important of all their effects. Mr Hume is the only writer who, so far
as I
know, has hitherto taken notice of it.
In a
country which has neither foreign commerce nor any of the finer
manufactures,
a great proprietor, having nothing for which he can exchange
the
greater part of the produce of his lands which is over and above the
maintenance
of the cultivators, consumes the whole in rustic hospitality at
home.
If this surplus produce is sufficient to maintain a hundred or a
thousand
men, he can make use of it in no other way than by maintaining a
hundred
or a thousand men. He is at all times, therefore, surrounded with a
multitude
of retainers and dependants, who, having no equivalent to give in
return
for their maintenance, but being fed entirely by his bounty, must
obey
him, for the same reason that soldiers must obey the prince who pays
them.
Before the extension of commerce and manufactures in Europe, the
hospitality
of the rich and the great, from the sovereign down to the
smallest
baron, exceeded every thing which, in the present times, we can
easily
form a notion of Westminster-hall was the dining-room of William
Rufus,
and might frequently, perhaps, not be too large for his company. It
was
reckoned a piece of magnificence in Thomas Becket, that he strewed the
floor
of his hall with clean hay or rushes in the season, in order that the
knights
and squires, who could not get seats, might not spoil their fine
clothes
when they sat down on the floor to eat their dinner. The great Earl
of
Warwick is said to have entertained every day, at his different manors,
30,000
people ; and though the number here may have been exaggerated, it
must,
however, have been very great to admit of such exaggeration. A
hospitality
nearly of the same kind was exercised not many years ago in many
different
parts of the Highlands of Scotland. It seems to be common in all
nations
to whom commerce and manufactures are little known. I have seen,
says
Doctor Pocock, an Arabian chief dine in the streets of a town where he
had
come to sell his cattle, and invite all passengers, even common
beggars,
to sit down with him and partake of his banquet.
The
occupiers of land were in every respect as dependent upon the great
proprietor
as his retainers. Even such of them as were not in a state of
villanage,
were tenants at will, who paid a rent in no respect equivalent to
the
subsistence which the land afforded them. A crown, half a crown, a
sheep,
a lamb, was some years ago, in the Highlands of Scotland, a common
rent
for lands which maintained a family. In some places it is so at this
day;
nor will money at present purchase a greater quantity of commodities
there
than in other places. In a country where the surplus produce of a
large
estate must be consumed upon the estate itself, it will frequently be
more
convenient for the proprietor, that part of it be consumed at a
distance
from his own house, provided they who consume it are as dependent
upon
him as either his retainers or his menial servants. He is thereby saved
from
the embarrassment of either too large a company, or too large a family.
A
tenant at will, who possesses land sufficient to maintain his family for
little
more than a quit-rent, is as dependent upon the proprietor as any
servant
or retainer whatever, and must obey him with as little reserve. Such
a
proprietor, as he feeds his servants and retainers at his own house, so he
feeds
his tenants at their houses. The subsistence of both is derived from
his
bounty, and its continuance depends upon his good pleasure.
Upon
the authority which the great proprietors necessarily had, in such a
state
of things, over their tenants and retainers, was founded the power of
the
ancient barons. They necessarily became the judges in peace, and the
leaders
in war, of all who dwelt upon their estates. They could maintain
order,
and execute the law, within their respective demesnes, because each
of them
could there turn the whole force of all the inhabitants against the
injustice
of anyone. No other person had sufficient authority to do this.
The
king, in particular, had not. In those ancient times, he was little more
than
the greatest proprietor in his dominions, to whom, for the sake of
common
defence against their common enemies, the other great proprietors
paid
certain respects. To have enforced payment of a small debt within the
lands
of a great proprietor, where all the inhabitants were armed, and
accustomed
to stand by one another, would have cost the king, had he
attempted
it by his own authority, almost the same effort as to extinguish a
civil
war. He was, therefore, obliged to abandon the administration of
justice,
through the greater part of the country, to those who were capable
of
administering it; and, for the same reason, to leave the command of the
country
militia to those whom that militia would obey.
It is a
mistake to imagine that those territorial jurisdictions took their
origin
from the feudal law. Not only the highest jurisdictions, both civil
and
criminal, but the power of levying troops, of coining money, and even
that of
making bye-laws for the government of their own people, were all
rights
possessed allodially by the great proprietors of land, several
centuries
before even the name of the feudal law was known in Europe. The
authority
and jurisdiction of the Saxon lords in England appear to have been
as
great before the Conquest as that of any of the Norman lords after it.
But the
feudal law is not supposed to have become the common law of England
till
after the Conquest. That the most extensive authority and jurisdictions
were
possessed by the great lords in France allodially, long before the
feudal
law was introduced into that country, is a matter of fact that admits
of no
doubt. That authority, and those jurisdictions, all necessarily flowed
from
the state of property and manners just now described. Without
remounting
to the remote antiquities of either the French or English
monarchies,
we may find, in much later times, many proofs that such effects
must
always flow from such causes. It is not thirty years ago since Mr
Cameron
of Lochiel, a gentleman of Lochaber in Scotland, without any legal
warrant
whatever, not being what was then called a lord of regality, nor
even a
tenant in chief, but a vassal of the Duke of Argyll, and with out
being
so much as a justice of peace, used, notwithstanding, to exercise the
highest
criminal jurisdictions over his own people. He is said to have done
so with
great equity, though without any of the formalities of justice; and
it is
not improbable that the state of that part of the country at that time
made it
necessary for him to assume this authority, in order to maintain the
public
peace. That gentleman, whose rent never exceeded £500 a-year,
carried,
in 1745, 800 of his own people into the rebellion with him.
The
introduction of the feudal law, so far from extending, may be regarded
as an
attempt to moderate, the authority of the great allodial lords. It
established
a regular subordination, accompanied with a long train of
services
and duties, from the king down to the smallest proprietor. During
the
minority of the proprietor, the rent, together with the management of
his
lands, fell into the hands of his immediate superior ; and,
consequently,
those of all great proprietors into the hands of the king, who
was
charged with the maintenance and education of the pupil, and who, from
his
authority as guardian, was supposed to have a right of disposing of him
in
marriage, provided it was in a manner not unsuitable to his rank. But
though
this institution necessarily tended to strengthen the authority of
the
king, and to weaken that of the great proprietors, it could not do
either
sufficiently for establishing order and good government among the
inhabitants
of the country; because it could not alter sufficiently that
state
of property and manners from which the disorders arose. The authority
of
government still continued to be, as before, too weak in the head, and
too
strong in the inferior members; and the excessive strength of the
inferior
members was the cause of the weakness of the head. After the
institution
of feudal subordination, the king was as incapable of
restraining
the violence of the great lords as before. They still continued
to make
war according to their own discretion, almost continually upon one
another,
and very frequently upon the king; and the open country still
continued
to be a scene of violence, rapine, and disorder.
But
what all the violence of the feudal institutions could never have
effected,
the silent and insensible operation of foreign commerce and
manufactures
gradually brought about. These gradually furnished the great
proprietors
with something for which they could exchange the whole surplus
produce
of their lands, and which they could consume themselves. without
sharing
it either with tenants or retainers. All for ourselves, and nothing
for
other people, seems, in every age of the world, to have been the vile
maxim
of the masters of mankind. As soon, therefore, as they could find a
method
of consuming the whole value of their rents themselves, they had no
disposition
to share them with any other persons. For a pair of diamond
buckles,
perhaps, or for something as frivolous and useless, they exchanged
the
maintenance, or, what is the same thing, the price of the maintenance of
1000
men for a year, and with it the whole weight and authority which it
could
give them. The buckles, however, were to be all their own, and no
other
human creature was to have any share of them; whereas, in the more
ancient
method of expense, they must have shared with at least 1000 people.
With
the judges that were to determine the preference, this difference was
perfectly
decisive; and thus, for the gratification of the most childish,
the
meanest, and the most sordid of all vanities they gradually bartered
their
whole power and authority.
In a
country where there is no foreign commerce, nor any of the finer
manufactures,
a man of £10,000 a-year cannot well employ his revenue in any
other
way than in maintaining, perhaps, 1000 families, who are all of them
necessarily
at his command. In the present state of Europe, a man of £10,000
a-year
can spend his whole revenue, and he generally does so, without
directly
maintaining twenty people, or being able to command more than ten
footmen,
not worth the commanding. Indirectly, perhaps, he maintains as
great,
or even a greater number of people, than he could have done by the
ancient
method of expense. For though the quantity of precious productions
for
which he exchanges his whole revenue be very small, the number of
workmen
employed in collecting and preparing it must necessarily have been
very
great. Its great price generally arises from the wages of their labour,
and the
profits of all their immediate employers. By paying that price, he
indirectly
pays all those wages and profits, and thus indirectly contributes
to the
maintenance of all the workmen and their employers. He generally
contributes,
however, but a very small proportion to that of each; to a very
few,
perhaps, not a tenth, to many not a hundredth, and to some not a
thousandth,
or even a ten thousandth part of their whole annual maintenance.
Though
he contributes, therefore, to the maintenance of them all, they are
all
more or less independent of him, because generally they can all be
maintained
without him.
When
the great proprietors of land spend their rents in maintaining their
tenants
and retainers, each of them maintains entirely all his own tenants
and all
his own retainers. But when they spend them in maintaining tradesmen
and
artificers, they may, all of them taken together, perhaps maintain as
great,
or, on account of the waste which attends rustic hospitality, a
greater
number of people than before. Each of them, however, taken singly,
contributes
often but a very small share to the maintenance of any
individual
of this greater number. Each tradesman or artificer derives his
subsistence
from the employment, not of one, but of a hundred or a thousand
different
customers. Though in some measure obliged to them all, therefore,
he is
not absolutely dependent upon any one of them.
The
personal expense of the great proprietors having in this manner
gradually
increased, it was impossible that the number of their retainers
should
not as gradually diminish, till they were at last dismissed
altogether.
The same cause gradually led them to dismiss the unnecessary
part of
their tenants. Farms were enlarged, and the occupiers of land, not.
withstanding
the complaints of depopulation, reduced to the number necessary
for
cultivating it, according to the imperfect state of cultivation and
improvement
in those times. By the removal of the unnecessary mouths, and by
exacting
from the farmer the full value of the farm, a greater surplus, or,
what is
the same thing, the price of a greater surplus, was obtained for the
proprietor,
which the merchants and manufacturers soon furnished him with a
method
of spending upon his own person, in the same manner as he had done
the
rest. The cause continuing to operate, he was desirous to raise his
rents
above what his lands, in the actual state of their improvement, could
afford.
His tenants could agree to this upon one condition only, that they
should
be secured in their possession for such a term of years as might give
them
time to recover, with profit, whatever they should lay not in the
further
improvement of the land. The expensive vanity of the landlord made
him
willing to accept of this condition ; and hence the origin of long
leases.
Even a
tenant at will, who pays the full value of the land, is not
altogether
dependent upon the landlord. The pecuniary advantages which they
receive
from one another are mutual and equal, and such a tenant will expose
neither
his life nor his fortune in the service of the proprietor. But if he
has a
lease for along term of years, he is altogether independent; and his
landlord
must not expect from him even the most trifling service, beyond
what is
either expressly stipulated in the lease, or imposed upon him by the
common
and known law of the country.
The
tenants having in this manner become independent, and the retainers
being
dismissed, the great proprietors were no longer capable of
interrupting
the regular execution of justice, or of disturbing the peace of
the
country. Having sold their birth-right, not like Esau, for a mess of
pottage
in time of hunger and necessity, but, in the wantonness of plenty,
for
trinkets and baubles, fitter to be the playthings of children than the
serious
pursuits of men, they became as insignificant as any substantial
burgher
or tradesmen in a city. A regular government was established in the
country
as well as in the city, nobody having sufficient power to disturb
its
operations in the one, any more than in the other.
It does
not, perhaps, relate to the present subject, but I cannot help
remarking
it, that very old families, such as have possessed some
considerable
estate from father to son for many successive generations, are
very
rare in commercial countries. In countries which have little commerce,
on the
contrary, such as Wales, or the Highlands of Scotland, they are very
common.
The Arabian histories seem to be all full of genealogies; and there
is a
history written by a Tartar Khan, which has been translated into
several
European languages, and which contains scarce any thing else; a
proof
that ancient families are very common among those nations. In
countries
where a rich man can spend his revenue in no other way than by
maintaining
as many people as it can maintain, he is apt to run out, and his
benevolence,
it seems, is seldom so violent as to attempt to maintain more
than he
can afford. But where he can spend the greatest revenue upon his own
person,
he frequently has no bounds to his expense, because he frequently
has no
bounds to his vanity, or to his affection for his own person. In
commercial
countries, therefore, riches, in spite of the most violent
regulations
of law to prevent their dissipation, very seldom remain long in
the
same family. Among simple nations, on the contrary, they frequently do,
without
any regulations of law ; for among nations of shepherds, such as the
Tartars
and Arabs, the consumable nature of their property necessarily
renders
all such regulations impossible.
A
revolution of the greatest importance to the public happiness, was in this
manner
brought about by two different orders of people, who had not the
least
intention to serve the public. To gratify the most childish vanity was
the
sole motive of the great proprietors. The merchants and artificers, much
less
ridiculous, acted merely from a view to their own interest, and in
pursuit
of their own pedlar principle of turning a penny wherever a penny
was to
be got. Neither of them had either knowledge or foresight of that
great
revolution which the folly of the one, and the industry of the other,
was
gradually bringing about.
It was
thus, that, through the greater part of Europe, the commerce and
manufactures
of cities, instead of being the effect, have been the cause and
occasion
of the improvement and cultivation of the country.
This
order, however, being contrary to the natural course of things, is
necessarily
both slow and uncertain. Compare the slow progress of those
European
countries of which the wealth depends very much upon their commerce
and
manufactures, with the rapid advances of our North American colonies, of
which
the wealth is founded altogether in agriculture. Through the greater
part of
Europe, the number of inhabitants is not supposed to double in less
than
five hundred years. In several of our North American colonies, it is
found
to double in twenty or five-and-twenty years. In Europe, the law of
primogeniture,
and perpetuities of different kinds, prevent the division of
great
estates, and thereby hinder the multiplication of small proprietors. A
small
proprietor, however, who knows every part of his little territory,
views
it with all the affection which property, especially small property,
naturally
inspires, and who upon that account takes pleasure, not only in
cultivating,
but in adorning it, is generally of all improvers the most
industrious,
the most intelligent, and the most successful. The same
regulations,
besides, keep so much land out of the market, that there are
always
more capitals to buy than there is land to sell, so that what is sold
always
sells at a monopoly price. The rent never pays the interest of the
purchase-money,
and is, besides, burdened with repairs and other occasional
charges,
to which the interest of money is not liable. To purchase land, is,
everywhere
in Europe, a most unprofitable employment of a small capital. For
the
sake of the superior security, indeed, a man of moderate circumstances,
when he
retires from business, will sometimes choose to lay out his little
capital
in land. A man of profession, too whose revenue is derived from
another
source often loves to secure his savings in the same way. But a
young
man, who, instead of applying to trade or to some profession, should
employ
a capital of two or three thousand pounds in the purchase and
cultivation
of a small piece of land, might indeed expect to live very
happily
and very independently, but must bid adieu for ever to all hope of
either
great fortune or great illustration, which, by a different employment
of his
stock, he might have had the same chance of acquiring with other
people.
Such a person, too, though he cannot aspire at being a proprietor,
will
often disdain to be a farmer. The small quantity of land, therefore,
which
is brought to market, and the high price of what is brought thither,
prevents
a great number of capitals from being employed in its cultivation
and
improvement, which would otherwise have taken that direction. In North
America,
on the contrary, fifty or sixty pounds is often found a sufficient
stock
to begin a plantation with. The purchase and improvement of
uncultivated
land is there the most profitable employment of the smallest as
well as
of the greatest capitals, and the most direct road to all the
fortune
and illustration which can be required in that country. Such land,
indeed,
is in North America to be had almost for nothing, or at a price much
below
the value of the natural produce; a thing impossible in Europe, or
indeed
in any country where all lands have long been private property. If
landed
estates, however, were divided equally among all the children, upon
the
death of any proprietor who left a numerous family, the estate would
generally
be sold. So much land would come to market, that it could no
longer
sell at a monopoly price. The free rent of the land would go no
nearer
to pay the interest of the purchase-money, and a small capital might
be
employed in purchasing land as profitable as in any other way.
England,
on account of the natural fertility of the soil, of the great
extent
of the sea-coast in proportion to that of the whole country, and of
the
many navigable rivers which run through it, and afford the conveniency
of
water carriage to some of the most inland parts of it, is perhaps as well
fitted
by nature as any large country in Europe to be the seat of foreign
commerce,
of manufactures for distant sale, and of all the improvements
which
these can occasion. From the beginning of the reign of Elizabeth, too,
the
English legislature has been peculiarly attentive to the interest of
commerce
and manufactures, and in reality there is no country in Europe,
Holland
itself not excepted, of which the law is, upon the whole, more
favourable
to this sort of industry. Commerce and manufactures have
accordingly
been continually advancing during all this period. The
cultivation
and improvement of the country has, no doubt, been gradually
advancing
too; but it seems to have followed slowly, and at a distance, the
more
rapid progress of commerce and manufactures. The greater part of the
country
must probably have been cultivated before the reign of Elizabeth;
and a
very great part of it still remains uncultivated, and the
cultivation
of the far greater part much inferior to what it might be, The
law of
England, however, favours agriculture, not only indirectly, by the
protection
of commerce, but by several direct encouragements. Except in
times
of scarcity, the exportation of corn is not only free, but encouraged
by a
bounty. In times of moderate plenty, the importation of foreign corn is
loaded
with duties that amount to a prohibition. The importation of live
cattle,
except from Ireland, is prohibited at all times ; and it is but of
late
that it was permitted from thence. Those who cultivate the land,
therefore,
have a monopoly against their countrymen for the two greatest and
most
important articles of land produce, bread and butcher's meat. These
encouragements,
although at bottom, perhaps, as I shall endeavour to show
hereafter,
altogether illusory, sufficiently demonstrate at least the good
intention
of the legislature to favour agriculture. But what is of much more
importance
than all of them, the yeomanry of England are rendered as secure
, as
independent, and as respectable, as law can make them. No country,
therefore,
which the right of primogeniture takes place, which pays tithes,
and
where perpetuities, though contrary to the spirit of the law, are
admitted
in some cases, can give more encouragement to agriculture than
England.
Such, however, notwithstanding, is the state of its cultivation.
What
would it have been, had the law given no direct encouragement to
agriculture
besides what arises indirectly from the progress of commerce,
and had
left the yeomanry in the same condition as in most other countries
of
Europe ? It is now more than two hundred years since the beginning of the
reign
of Elizabeth, a period as long as the course of human prosperity
usually
endures.
France
seems to have had a considerable share of foreign commerce, near a
century
before England was distinguished as a commercial country. The marine
of
France was considerable, according to the notions of the times, before
the
expedition of Charles VIII. to Naples. The cultivation and improvement
of
France, however, is, upon the whole, inferior to that of England. The law
of the
country has never given the same direct encouragement to agriculture.
The
foreign commerce of Spain and Portual to the other parts of Europe,
though
chiefly carried on in foreign ships, is very considerable. That to
their
colonies is carried on in their own, and is much greater, on account
of the
great riches and extent of those colonies. But it has never
introduced
any considerable manufactures for distant sale into either of
those
countries, and the greater part of both still remains uncultivated.
The
foreign commerce of Portugal is of older standing than that of any great
country
in Europe, except Italy.
Italy
is the only great country of Europe which seems to have been
cultivated
and improved in every part, by means of foreign commerce and
manufactures
for distant sale. Before the invasion of Charles VIII., Italy,
according
to Guicciardini, was cultivated not less in the most mountainous
and
barren parts of the country, than in the plainest and most fertile. The
advantageous
situation of the country, and the great number of independent
status
which at that time subsisted in it, probably contributed not a little
to this
general cultivation. It is not impossible, too, notwithstanding this
general
expression of one of the most judicious and reserved of modern
historians,
that Italy was not at that time better cultivated than England
is at
present.
The
capital, however, that is acquired to any country by commerce and
manufactures,
is always a very precarious and uncertain possession, till
some
part of it has been secured and realized in the cultivation and
improvement
of its lands. A merchant, it has been said very properly, is not
necessarily
the citizen of any particular country. It is in a great measure
indifferent
to him from what place he carries on his trade ; and a very
trifling
disgust will make him remove his capital, and, together with it,
all the
industry which it supports, from one
country to another. No part of
it can
be said to belong to any particular country, till it has been spread,
as it
were, over the face of that country, either in buildings, or in the
lasting
improvement of lands. No vestige now remains of the great wealth
said to
have been possessed by the greater part of the Hanse Towns, except
in the
obscure histories of the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries. It is
even
uncertain where some of them were situated, or to what towns in Europe
the
Latin names given to some of them belong. But though the misfortunes of
Italy,
in the end of the fifteenth and beginning of the sixteenth centuries,
greatly
diminished the commerce and manufactures of the cities of Lombardy
and
Tuscany, those countries still continue to be among the most populous
and
best cultivated in Europe. The civil wars of Flanders, and the Spanish
government
which succeeded them, chased away the great commerce of Antwerp,
Ghent,
and Bruges. But Flanders still continues to be one of the richest,
best
cultivated, and most populous provinces of Europe. The ordinary
revolutions
of war and government easily dry up the sources of that wealth
which
arises from commerce only. That which arises from the more solid
improvements
of agriculture is much more durable, and cannot be destroyed
but by
those more violent convulsions occasioned by the depredations of
hostile
and barbarous nations continued for a century or two together ; such
as
those that happened for some time before and after the fall of the Roman
empire
in the western provinces of Europe.
BOOK
IV.
OF
SYSTEMS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY.
Political
economy, considered as a branch of the science of a
statesman
or legislator, proposes two distinct objects; first, to
provide
a plentiful revenue or subsistence for the people, or,
more
properly, to enable them to provide such a revenue or
subsistence
for themselves; and, secondly, to supply the state or
commonwealth
with a revenue sufficient for the public services.
It
proposes to enrich both the people and the sovereign.
The
different progress of opulence in different ages and nations,
has
given occasion to two different systems of political economy,
with
regard to enrichiug the people. The one may be called the
system
of commerce, the other that of agriculture. I shall
endeavour
to explain both as fully and distinctly as I can, and
shall
begin with the system of commerce. It is the modern system,
and is
best understood in our own country and in our own times.
CHAPTER I.
OF THE
PRINCIPLE OF THE COMMERCIAL OR MERCANTILE SYSTEM.
That
wealth consists in money, or in gold and silver, is a
popular
notion which naturally arises from the double function of
money,
as the instrument of commerce, and as the measure of
value.
In consequence of its being the instrument of commerce,
when we
have money we can more readily obtain whatever else we
have
occasion for, than by means of any other commodity. The
great
affair, we always find, is to get money. When that is
obtained,
there is no difficulty in making any subsequent
purchase.
In consequence of its being the measure of value, we
estimate
that of all other commodities by the quantity of money
which
they will exchange for. We say of a rich man, that he is
worth a
great deal, and of a poor man, that he is worth very
little
money. A frugal man, or a man eager to be rich, is said to
love
money ; and a careless, a generous, or a profuse man, is
said to
be indifferent about it. To grow rich is to get money ;
and
wealth and money, in short, are, in common language,
considered
as in every respect synonymous.
A rich
country, in the same manner as a rich man, is supposed to
be a
country abounding in money ; and to heap up gold and silver
in any
country is supposed to be the readiest way to enrich it.
For
some time after the discovery of America, the first inquiry
of the
Spaniards, when they arrived upon any unknown coast, used
to be,
if there was any gold or silver to be
found in the
neighbourhood?
By the information which they received, they
judged
whether it was worth while to make a settlement there, or
if the
country was worth the conquering. Plano Carpino, a monk
sent
ambassador from the king of France to one of the sons of the
famous
Gengis Khan, says, that the Tartars used frequently to ask
him, if
there was plenty of sheep and oxen in the kingdom of
France
? Their inquiry had the same object with that of the
Spaniards.
They wanted to know if the country was rich enough to
be
worth the conquering. Among the Tartars, as among all other
nations
of shepherds, who are generally ignorant of the use of
money,
cattle are the instruments of commerce and the measures of
value.
Wealth, therefore, according to them, consisted in cattle,
as,
according to the Spaniards, it consisted in gold and silver.
Of the
two, the Tartar notion, perhaps, was the nearest to the
truth.
Mr
Locke remarks a distinction between money and other moveable
goods.
All other moveable goods, he says, are of so consumable a
nature,
that the wealth which consists in them cannot be much
depended
on; and a nation which abounds in them one year may,
without
any exportation, but merely by their own waste and
extravagance,
be in great want of them the next. Money, on the
contrary,
is a steady friend, which, though it may travel about
from
hand to hand, yet if it can be kept from going out of the
country,
is not very liable to be wasted and consumed. Gold and
silver,
therefore, are, according to him, the must solid and
substantial
part of the moveable wealth of a nation ; and to
multiply
those metals ought, he thinks, upon that account, to be
the
great object of its political economy.
Others
admit, that if a nation could be separated from all the
world,
it would be of no consequence how much or how little money
circulated
in it. The consumable goods, which were circulated by
means
of this money, would only be exchanged for a greater or a
smaller
number of pieces; but the real wealth or poverty of the
country,
they allow, would depend altogether upon the abundance
or
scarcity of those consumable goods. But it is otherwise, they
think,
with countries which have connections with foreign
nations,
and which are obliged to carry on foreign wars, and to
maintain
fleets and armies in distant countries. This, they say,
cannot
be done, but by sending abroad money to pay them with ;
and a
nation cannot send much money abroad, unless it has a good
deal at
home. Every such nation, therefore, must endeavour, in
time of
peace, to accumulate gold and silver, that when occasion
requires,
it may have wherewithal to carry on foreign wars.
In
consequence of those popular notions, all the different
nations
of Europe have studied, though to little purpose, every
possible
means of accumulating gold and silver in their
respective
countries. Spain and Portugal, the proprietors of the
principal
mines which supply Europe with those metals, have
either
prohibited their exportation under the severest penalties,
or
subjected it to a considerable duty. The like prohibition
seems
anciently to have made a part of the policy of most other
European
nations. It is even to be found, where we should least
of all
expect to find it, in some old Scotch acts of Parliament,
which
forbid, under heavy penalties, the carrying gold or silver
forth
of the kingdom. The like policy anciently took place both
in
France and England.
When
those countries became commercial, the merchants found this
prohibition,
upon many occasions, extremely inconvenient. They
could
frequently buy more advantageously with gold and silver,
than
with any other commodity, the foreign goods which they
wanted,
either to import into their own, or to carry to some
other
foreign country. They remonstrated, therefore, against this
prohibition
as hurtful to trade.
They
represented, first, that the exportation of gold and silver,
in
order to purchase foreign goods, did not always diminish the
quantity
of those metals in the kingdom ; that, on the contrary,
it
might frequently increase the quantity ; because, if the
consumption
of foreign goods was not thereby increased in the
country,
those goods might be re-exported to foreign countries,
and
being there sold for a large profit, might bring back much
more
treasure than was originally sent out to purchase them. Mr
Mun
compares this operation of foreign trade to the seed-time and
harvest
of agriculture. "If we only behold," says he, "the
actions
of the husbandman in the seed. time, when he casteth away
much
good corn into the ground, we shall account him rather a
madman
than a husbandman. But when we consider his labours in the
harvest,
which is the end of his endeavours, we shall find the
worth
and plentiful increase of his actions."
They
represented, secondly, that this prohibition could not
hinder
the exportation of gold and silver, which, on account of
the
smallness of their bulk in proportion to their value, could
easily
be smuggled abroad. That this exportation could only be
prevented
by a proper attention to what they called the balance
of
trade. That when the country exported to a greater value than
it
imported, a balance became due to it from foreign nations,
which
was necessarily paid to it in gold and silver, and thereby
increased
the quantity of those metals in the kingdom. But that
when it
imported to a greater value than it exported, a contrary
balance
became due to foreign nations, which was necessarily paid
to them
in the same manner, and thereby diminished that quantity
: that
in this case, to prohibit the exportation of those metals,
could
not prevent it, but only, by making it more dangerous,
render
it more expensive: that the exchange was thereby turned
more
against the country which owed the balance, than it
otherwise
might have been; the merchant who purchased a bill upon
the
foreign country being obliged to pay the banker who sold it,
not
only for the natural risk, trouble, and expense of sending
the
money thither, but for the extraordinary risk arising from
the
prohibition; but that the more the exchange was against any
country,
the more the balance of trade became necessarily against
it; the
money of that country becoming necessarily of so much
less
value, in comparison with that of the country to which the
balance
was due. That if the exchange between England and
Holland,
for example, was five per cent. against England, it
would
require 105 ounces of silver in England to purchase a bill
for 100
ounces of silver in Holland: that 105 ounces of silver in
England,
therefore, would be worth only 100 ounces of silver in
Holland,
and would purchase only a proportionable quantity of
Dutch
goods ; but that 100 ounces of silver in Holland, on the
contrary,
would be worth 105 ounces in England, and would
purchase
a proportionable quantity of English goods;
that the
English
goods which were sold to Holland would be sold so much
cheaper,
and the Dutch goods which were sold to England so much
dearer,
by the difference of the exchange : that the one would
draw so
much less Dutch money to England, and the other so much
more
English money to Holland, as this difference amounted to:
and
that the balance of trade, therefore, would necessarily be so
much
more against England, and would require a greater balance of
gold
and silver to be exported to Holland.
Those
arguments were partly solid and partly sophistical. They
were
solid, so far as they asserted that the exportation of gold
and
silver in trade might frequently be advantageous to the
country.
They were solid, too, in asserting that no prohibition
could
prevent their exportation, when private people found any
advantage
in exporting them. But they were sophistical, in
supposing,
that either to preserve or to augment the quantity of
those
metals required more the attention of government, than to
preserve
or to augment the quantity of any other useful
commodities,
which the freedom of trade, without any such
attention,
never fails to supply in the proper quantity. They
were
sophistical, too, perhaps, in asserting that the high price
of
exchange necessarily increased what they called the
unfavourable
balance of trade, or occasioned the exportation of a
greater
quantity of gold and silver. That high price, indeed, was
extremely
disadvantageous to the merchants who had any money to
pay in
foreign countries. They paid so much dearer for the bills
which
their bankers granted them upon those countries. But though
the
risk arising from the prohibition might occasion some
extraordinary
expense to the bankers, it would not necessarily
carry
any more money out of the country. This expense would
generally
be all laid out in the country, in smuggling the money
out of
it, and could seldom occasion the exportation of a single
sixpence
beyond the precise sum drawn for. The high price of
exchange,
too, would naturally dispose the merchants to endeavour
to make
their exports nearly balance their imports, in order that
they
might have this high exchange to pay upon as small a sum as
possible.
The high price of exchange, besides, must necessarily
have
operated as a tax, in raising the price of foreign goods,
and
thereby diminishing their consumption. It would tend,
therefore,
not to increase, but to diminish, what they called the
unfavourable
balance of trade, and consequently the exportation
of gold
and silver.
Such as
they were, however, those arguments convinced the people
to whom
they were addressed. They were addressed by merchants to
parliaments
and to the councils of princes, to nobles, and to
country
gentlemen; by those who were supposed to understand
trade,
to those who were conscious to them selves that they knew
nothing
about the matter. That foreign trade enriched the
country,
experience demonstrated to the nobles and country
gentlemen,
as well as to the merchants ; but how, or in what
manner,
none of them well knew. The merchants knew perfectly in
what
manner it enriched themselves, it was their business to know
it. But
to know in what manner it enriched the country, was no
part of
their business. The subject never came into their
consideration,
but when they had occasion to apply to their
country
for some change in the laws relating to foreign trade. It
then
became necessary to say something about the beneficial
effects
of foreign trade, and the manner in which those effects
were
obstructed by the laws as they then stood. To the judges who
were to
decide the business, it appeared a most satisfactory
account
of the matter, when they were told that foreign trade
brought
money into the country, but that the laws in question
hindered
it from bringing so much as it otherwise would do. Those
arguments,
therefore, produced the wished-for effect. The
prohibition
of exporting gold and silver was, in France and
England,
confined to the coin of those respective countries. The
exportation
of foreign coin and of bullion was made free. In
Holland,
and in some other places, this liberty was extended even
to the
coin of the country. The attention of government was
turned
away from guarding against the
exportation of gold and
silver,
to watch over the balance of trade, as the only cause
which
could occasion any augmentation or diminution of those
metals.
From one fruitless care, it was turned away to another
care
much more intricate, much more embarrassing, and just
equally
fruitless. The title of Mun's book, England's Treasure in
Foreign
Trade, became a fundamental maxim in the political
economy,
not of England only, but of all other commercial
countries.
The inland or home trade, the most important of all,
the
trade in which an equal capital affords the greatest revenue,
and
creates the greatest employment to the people of the country,
was
considered as subsidiary only to foreign trade. It neither
brought
money into the country, it was said, nor carried any out
of it.
The country, therefore, could never become either richer
or
poorer by means of it, except so far as its prosperity or
decay
might indirectly influence the state of foreign trade.
A
country that has no mines of its own, must undoubtedly draw its
gold
and silver from foreign countries, in the same manner as one
that
has no vineyards of its own must draw its wines. It does not
seem
necessary, however, that the attention of government should
he more
turned towards the one than towards the other object. A
country
that has wherewithal to buy wine, will always get the
wine
which it has occasion for ; and a country that
has
wherewithal
to buy gold and silver, will never be in want of
those
metals. They are to be bought for a certain price, like all
other
commodities; and as they are the price of all other
commodities,
so all other commodities are the price of those
metals.
We trust, with perfect security, that the freedom of
trade,
without any attention of government, will always supply us
with
the wine which we have occasion for; and we may trust, with
equal
security, that it will always supply us with all the gold
and
silver which we can afford to purchase or to employ, either
in
circulating our commodities or in other uses.
The
quantity of every commodity which human industry can either
purchace
or produce, naturally regulates itself in every country
according
to the effectual demand, or according to the demand of
those
who are willing to pay the whole rent, labour, and profits,
which
must be paid in order to prepare and bring it to market.
But no
commodities regulate themselves more easily or more
exactly,
according to this effectual demand, than gold and silver
;
because, on account of the small bulk and great value of those
metals,
no commodities can be more easily transported from one
place
to another ; from the places where they are cheap, to those
where
they are dear ; from the places where they exceed, to those
where
they fall short of this effectual demand. If there were in
England,
for example, an effectual demand for an additional
quantity
of gold, a packet-boat could bring from Lisbon, or from
wherever
else it was to be had, fifty tons of gold, which could
be
coined into more than five millions of guineas. But if there
were an
effectual demand for grain to the same value, to import
it
would require, at five guineas a-ton, a million of tons of
shipping,
or a thousand ships of a thousand tons each. The navy
of
England would not be sufficient.
When
the quantity of gold and silver imported into any country
exceeds
the effectual demand, no vigilance of government can
prevent
their exportation. All the sanguinary laws of Spain and
Portugal
are not able to keep their gold and silver at home. The
continual
importations from Peru and Brazil exceed the effectual
demand
of those countries, and sink the price of those metals
there
below that in the neighbouring countries. If, on the
contrary,
in any particular country, their quantity fell short of
the
effectual demand, so as to raise their price above that of
the
neighbouring countries, the government would have no occasion
to take
any pains to import them. If it were even to take pains
to
prevent their importation, it would not be able to effectuate
it.
Those metals, when the Spartans had got wherewithal to
purchase
them, broke through all the barriers which the laws of
Lycurgus
opposed to their entrance into Lacedaemon. All the
sanguinary
laws of the customs are not able to prevent the
importation
of the teas of the Dutch and Gottenburg East India
comnpanies;
because somewhat cheaper than those of the British
company.
A pound of tea, however, is about a hundred times the
bulk of
one of the highest prices, sixteen shillings, that is
commonly
paid for it in silver, and more than two thousand times
the
bulk of the same price in gold, and, consequently, just so
many
times more difficult to smuggle.
It is
partly owing to the easy transportation of gold and silver,
from
the places where they abound to those where they are wanted,
that
the price of those metals does not fluctuate continually,
like
that of the greater part of other commodities, which are
hindered
by their bulk from shifting their situation, when the
market
happens to be either over or under-stocked with them. The
price
of those metals, indeed, is not altogether exempted from
variation
; but the changes to which it is liable are generally
slow,
gradual, and uniform. In Europe, for example, it is
supposed,
without much foundation, perhaps, that during the
course
of the present and preceding century, they have been
constantly,
but gradually, sinking in their value, on account of
the
continual importations from the Spanish West Indies. But to
make
any sudden change in the price of gold and silver, so as to
raise
or lower at once, sensibly and remarkably, the money price
of all
other commodities, requires such a revolution in commerce
as that
occasioned by the discovery of America.
If, not
withstanding all this, gold and silver should at any time
fall
short in a country which has wherewithal to purchase them,
there
are more expedients for supplying their place, than that of
almost
any other commodity. If the materials of manufacture are
wanted,
industry must stop. If provisions are wanted, the people
must
starve. But if money is wanted, barter will supply its
place,
though with a good deal of inconveniency. Buying and
selling
upon credit, and the different dealers compensating their
credits
with one another, once a-month, or once a-year, will
supply
it with less inconveniency. A well-regulated paper-money
will
supply it not only without any inconveniency, but, in some
cases,
with some advantages. Upon every account, therefore, the
attention
of government never was so unnecessarily employed, as
when
directed to watch over the preservation or increase of the
quantity
of money in any country.
No
complaint, however, is more common than that of a scarcity of
money.
Money, like wine, must always be scarce with those who
have
neither wherewithal to buy it, nor credit to borrow it.
Those
who have either, will seldom be in want either of the
money,
or of the wine which they have occasion for. This
complaint,
however, of the scarcity of money, is not always
confined
to improvident spendthrifts. It is sometimes general
through
a whole mercantile town and the country
in its
neighbourhood.
Over-trading is the common cause of it. Sober men,
whose
projects have been disproportioned to their capitals, are
as
likely to have neither wherewithal to buy money, nor credit to
borrow
it, as prodigals, whose expense has been disproportioned
to
their revenue. Before their projects can be brought to bear,
their
stock is gone, and their credit with it. They run about
everywhere
to borrow money, and everybody tells them that they
have
none to lend. Even such general complaints of the scarcity
of
money do not always prove that the usual number of gold and
silver
pieces are not circulating in the country, but that many
people
want those pieces who have nothing to give for them. When
the
profits of trade happen to be greater than ordinary
over-trading
becomes a general error, both among great and small
dealers.
They do not always send more money abroad than usual,
but
they buy upon credit, both at home and abroad, an unusual
quantity
of goods, which they send to some distant market, in
hopes
that the returns will come in before the demand for
payment.
The demand comes before the returns, and they have
nothing
at hand with which they can either purchase money or give
solid
security for borrowing. It is not any scarcity of gold and
silver,
but the difficulty which such people find in borrowing,
and
which their creditor find in getting payment, that occasions
the
general complaint of the scarcity of money.
It
would be too ridiculous to go about seriously to prove, that
wealth
does not consist in money, or in gold and silver ; but in
what
money purchases, and is valuable only for purchasing. Money,
no
doubt, makes always a part of the national capital ; but it
has
already been shown that it generally makes but a small part,
and
always the most unprofitable part of it.
It is
not because wealth consists more essentially in money than
in
goods, that the merchant finds it generally more easy to buy
goods
with money, than to buy money with goods ; but because
money
is the known and established instrument of commerce, for
which
every thing is readily given in exchange, but which is not
always
with equal readiness to be got in exchange for every
thing.
The greater part of goods, besides, are more perishable
than
money, and he may frequently sustain a much greater loss by
keeping
them. When his goods are upon hand, too, he is more
liable
to such demands for money as he may not be able to answer,
than
when he has got their price in his coffers. Over and above
all
this, his profit arises more directly from selling than from
buying;
and he is, upon all these accounts, generally much more
anxious
to exchange his goods for money than his money for goods.
But
though a particular merchant, with abundance of goods in his
warehouse,
may sometimes be ruined by not being able to sell them
in
time, a nation or country is not liable to the same accident,
The
whole capital of a merchant frequently consists in perishable
goods
destined for purchasing money. But it is but a very small
part of
the annual produce of the land and lahour of a country,
which
can ever be destined for purchasing gold and silver from
their
neighbours. The far greater part is circulated and consumed
among
themselves; and even of the surplus which is sent abroad,
the
greater part is generally destined for the purchase of other
foreign
goods. Though gold and silver, therefore, could not be
had in
exchange for the goods destined to purchase them, the
nation
would not be ruined. It might, indeed, suffer some loss
and
inconveniency, and be forced upon some of those expedients
which
are necessary for supplying the place of money. The annual
produce
of its land and labour, however, would be the same, or
very
nearly the same as usual ; because the same, or very nearly
the
same consumable capital would be employed in maintaining it.
And
though goods do not always draw money so readily as money
draws
goods, in the long-run they draw it more necessarily than
even it
draws them. Goods can serve many other purposes besides
purchasing
money, but money can serve no other purpose besides
purchasing
goods. Money, therefore, necessarily runs after goods,
but
goods do not always or necessarily run after money. The man
who
buys, does not always mean to sell again, but frequently to
use or
to consume ; whereas he who sells always means to buy
again.
The one may frequently have done the whole, but the other
can
never have done more than the one half of his business. It is
not for
its own sake that men desire money, but for the sake of
what
they can purchase with it.
Consumable
commodities, it is said, are soon destroyed; whereas
gold
and silver are of a more durable nature, and were it not for
this
continual exportation, might be accumulated for ages
together,
to the incredible augmentation of the real wealth of
the
country. Nothing, therefore, it is pretended, can be more
disadvantageous
to any country, than the trade which consists in
the
exchange of such lasting for such perishable commodities. We
do not,
however, reckon that trade disadvatageous, which consists
in the
exchange of the hardware of England for the wines of
France,
and yet hardware is a very durable commodity, and were it
not for
this continual exportation, might too be accumulated for
ages
together, to the incredible augmentation of the pots and
pans of
the country. But it readily occurs, that the number of
such
utensils is in every country necessarily limited by the use
which
there is for them ; that it would be absurd to have more
pots
and pans than were necessary for cooking the victuals
usually
consumed there; and that, if the quantity of victuals
were to
increase, the number of pots and pans would readily
increase
along with it ; a part of the increased quantity of
victuals
being employed in purchasing them, or in maintaining an
additional
number of workmen whose business it was to make them.
It
should as readily occur, that the quantity of gold and silver
is, in
every country, limited by the use which there is for those
metals
; that their use consists in circulating commodities, as
coin,
and in affording a species of household furniture, as
plate;
that the quantity of coin in every country is regulated by
the
value of the commodities which are to be circulated by it;
increase
that value, and immediately a part of it will be sent
abroad
to purchase, wherever it is to be had, the additional
quantity
of coin requisite for circulating them : that the
quantity
of plate is regulated by the number and wealth of those
private
families who choose to indulge themselves in that sort of
magnificence;
increase the number and wealth of such families,
and a
part of this increased wealth will most probably be
employed
in purchasing, wherever it is to be found, an additional
quantity
of plate ; that to attempt to increase the wealth of any
country,
either by introducing or by detaining in it an
unnecessary
quantity of gold and silver, is as absurd as it would
be to
attempt to increase the good cheer of private families, by
obliging
them to keep an unnecessary number of kitchen utensils.
As the
expense of purchasing those unnecessary utensils would
diminish,
instead of increasing, either the quantity or goodness
of the
family provisions; so the expense of purchasing an
unnecessary
quantity of gold and silver must, in every country,
as
necessarily diminish the wealth which feeds, clothes, and
lodges,
which maintains and employs the people. Gold and silver,
whether
in the shape of coin or of plate, are utensils, it must
he
remembered, as much as the furniture of the kitchen. Increase
the use
of them, increase the consumable commodities which are to
be
circulated, managed, and prepared by means of them, and you
will
infallibly increase the quantity ; but if you attempt by
extraordinary
means to increase the quantity, you will as
infallibly
diminish the use, and even the quantity too, which in
those
metals can never be greater than what the use requires.
Were
they ever to be accumulated beyond this quantity, their
transportation
is so easy, and the loss which attends their lying
idle
and unemployed so great, that no law could prevent their
being
immediately sent out of the country.
It is
not always necessary to accumulate gold and silver, in
order
to enable a country to carry on foreign wars, and to
maintain
fleets and armies in distant countries. Fleets and
armies
are maintained, not with gold and silver, but with
consumable
goods. The nation which, from the annual produce of
its
domestic industry, from the annual revenue arising out of its
lands,
and labour, and consumable stock, has wherewithal to
purchase
those consumable goods in distant countries, can
maintain
foreign wars there.
A
nation may purchase the pay and provisions of an army in a
distant
country three different ways ; by sending abroad either,
first,
some part of its accumulated gold and silver ; or,
secondly,
some part of the annual produce of its manufactures ;
or,
last of all, some part of its annual rude produce.
The
gold and silver which can properly be considered as
accumulated,
or stored up in any country, may be distinguished
into
three parts ; first, the circulating money; secondly, the
plate of
private families; and, last of all, the money which may
have
been collected by many years parsimony, and laid up in the
treasury
of the prince.
It can
seldom happen that much can be spared from the circulating
money
of the country ; because in that there can seldom be much
redundancy.
The value of goods annually bought and sold in any
country
requires a certain quantity of money to circulate and
distribute
them to their proper consumers, and can give
employment
to no more. The channel of circulation necessarily
draws
to itself a sum sufficient to fill it, and never admits any
more.
Something, however, is generally withdrawn from this
channel
in the case of foreign war. By the great number of people
who are
maintained abroad, fewer are maintained at home. Fewer
goods
are circulated there, and less money becomes necessary to
circulate
them. An extraordinary quantity of paper money of some
sort or
other, too, such as exchequer notes, navy bills, and bank
bills,
in England, is generally issued upon such occasions, and,
by
supplying the place of circulating gold and silver, gives an
opportunity
of sending a greater quantity of it abroad. All this,
however,
could afford but a poor resource for maintaining a
foreign
war, of great expense, and several years duration.
The
melting down of the plate of private families has, upon every
occasion,
been found a still more insignificant one. The French,
in the
beginning of the last war, did not derive so much
advantage
from this expedient as to compensate the loss of the
fashion.
The
accumulated treasures of the prince have in former times
afforded
a much greater and more lasting resource. In the present
times,
if you except the king of Prussia, to accumulate treasure
seems
to be no part of the policy of European princes.
The
funds which maintained the foreign wars of the present
century,
the most expensive perhaps which history records, seem
to have
had little dependency upon the exportation either of the
circulating
money, or of the plate of private
families, or of
the
treasure of the prince. The last French war cost Great
Britain
upwards of £90,000,000, including not only the
£75,000,000
of new debt that was contracted, but the additional
2s. in
the pound land-tax, and what was annually borrowed of the
sinking
fund. More than two-thirds of this expense were laid out
in
distant countries; in Germany, Portugal, America, in the ports
of the
Mediterranean, in the East and West Indies. The kings of
England
had no accumulated treasure. We never heard of any
extraordinary
quantity of plate being melted down. The
circulating
gold and silver of the country had not been supposed
to
exceed £18,000,000. Since the late recoinage of the gold,
however,
it is believed to have been a good deal under-rated. Let
us
suppose, therefore, according to the most exaggerated
computation
which I remember to have either seen or heard of,
that,
gold and silver together, it amounted to £30,000,000. Had
the war
been carried on by means of our money, the whole of it
must,
even according to this computation, have been sent out and
returned
again, at least twice in a period of between six and
seven
years. Should this be supposed, it would afford the most
decisive
argument, to demonstrate how unnecessary it is for
government
to watch over the preservation of money, since, upon
this
supposition, the whole money of the country must have gone
from
it, and returned to it again, two different times in so
short a
period, without any body's knowing any thing of the
matter.
The channel of circulation, however, never appeared more
empty
than usual during any part of this period. Few people
wanted
money who had wherewithal to pay for it. The profits of
foreign
trade, indeed, were greater than usual during the whole
war,
but especially towards the end of it. This occasioned, what
it
always occasions, a general over-trading in all the ports of
Great
Britain; and this again occasioned the usual complaint of
the
scarcity of money, which always follows over-trading. Many
people
wanted it, who had neither wherewithal to buy it, nor
credit
to borrow it ; and because the debtors found it difficult
to
borrow, the creditors found it difficult to get payment. Gold
and
silver, however, were generally to be had for their value, by
those
who had that value to give for them.
The
enormous expense of the late war, therefore, must have been
chiefly
defrayed, not by the exportation of gold and silver, but
by that
of British commodities of some kind or other. When the
government,
or those who acted under them, contracted with a
merchant
for a remittance to some foreign country, he would
naturally
endeavour to pay his foreign correspondent, upon whom
he
granted a bill, by sending abroad rather commodities than gold
and
silver. If the commodities of Great Britain were not in
demand
in that country, he would endeavour to
send them to some
other
country in which he could purchase a bill upon that
country.
The transportation of commodities, when properly suited
to the
market, is always attended with a considerable profit;
whereas
that of gold and silver is scarce ever attended with any.
When
those metals are sent abroad in order to purchase foreign
commodities,
the merchant's profit arises, not from the purchase,
but
from the sale of the returns. But when they are sent abroad
merely
to pay a debt, he gets no returns, and consequently no
profit.
He naturally, therefore, exerts his invention to find out
a way
of paying his foreign debts, rather by the exportation of
commodities,
than by that of gold and silver. The great quantity
of
British goods, exported during the course of the late war,
without
bringing back any returns, is accordingly remarked by the
author
of the Present State of the Nation.
Besides
the three sorts of gold and silver above mentioned, there
is in
all great commercial countries a good deal of bullion
alternately
imported and exported, for the purposes of foreign
trade.
This bullion, as it circulates among different commercial
countries,
in the same manner as the national coin circulates in
every
country, may be considered as the money of the great
mercantile
republic. The national coin receives its movement and
direction
from the commodities circulated within the precincts of
each
particular country ; the money in the mercantile republic,
from
those circulated between different countries. Both are
employed
in facilitating exchanges, the one between different
individuals
of the same, the other between those of different
nations.
Part of this money of the great mercantile republic may
have
been, and probably was, employed in carrying on the late
war. In
time of a general war, it is natural to suppose that a
movement
and direction should be impressed upon it, different
from
what it usually follows in profound peace, that it should
circulate
more about the seat of the war, and be more employed in
purchasing
there, and in the neighbouring countries, the pay and
provisions
of the different armies. But whatever part of this
money
of the mercantile republic Great Britain may have annually
employed
in this manner, it must have been annually purchased,
either
with British commodities, or with something else that had
been
purchased with them ; which still brings us back to
commodities,
to the annual produce of the land and labour of the
country,
as the ultimate resources which enabled us to carry on
the
war. It is natural, indeed, to suppose, that so great an
annual
expense must have been defrayed from a great annual
produce.
The expense of 1761, for example, amounted to more than
£19,000,000.
No accumulation could have supported so great an
annual
profusion. There is no annual produce, even of gold and
silver,
which could have supported it. The
whole gold and
silver
annually imported into both Spain and Portugal, according
to the
best accounts, does not commonly much exceed £6,000,000
sterling,
which, in some years, would scarce have paid four
months
expense of the late war.
The
commodities most proper for being transported to distatnt
countries,
in order to purchase there either the pay and
provisions
of an army, or some part of the money of the
mercantile
republic to be employed in purchasing them, seem to be
the
finer and more improved manufactures; such as contain a great
value
in a small bulk, and can therefore be exported to a great
distance
at little expense. A country whose industry produces a
great
annual surplus of such manufactures, which are usually
exported
to foreign countries, may carry on for many years a very
expensive
foreign war, without either exporting any considerable
quantity
of gold and silver, or even having any such quantity to
export.
A considerable part of the annual surplus of its
manufactures
must, indeed, in this case, be exported without
bringing
back any returns to the country, though it does to the
merchant
; the government purchasing of the merchant his bills
upon
foreign countries, in order to purchase there the pay and
provisions
of an army. Some part of this surplus, however, may
still
continue to bring back a return. The manufacturers during;
the war
will have a double demand upon them, and be called upon
first
to work up goods to be sent abroad, for paying the bills
drawn
upon foreign countries for the pay and provisions of the
army:
and, secondly, to work up such as are necessary for
purchasing
the common returns that had usually been consumed in
the
country. In the midst of the most destructive foreign war,
therefore,
the greater part of manufactures may frequently
flourish
greatly; and, on the contrary, they may decline on the
return
of peace. They may flourish amidst the ruin of their
country,
and begin to decay upon the return of its prosperity.
The
different state of many different branches of the British
manufactures
during the late war, and for some time after the
peace,
may serve as an illustration of what has been just now
said.
No
foreign war, of great expense or duration, could conveniently
be
carried on by the exportation of the rude produce of the soil.
The
expense of sending such a quantity of it into a foreign
country
as might purchase the pay and provisions of an army would
be too
great. Few countries, too, produce much more rude produce
than
what is sufficient for the subsistence of their own
inhabitants.
To send abroad any great quantity of it, therefore,
would
be to send abroad a part of the necessary subsistence of
the
people. It is otherwise with the exportation of manufactures.
The
maintenance of the people employed in them is kept at home,
and
only the surplus part of their work is exported. Mr Hume
frequently
takes notice of the inability of the ancient kings of
England
to carry on, without interruption, any foreign war of
long
duration. The English in those days had nothing wherewithal
to
purchase the pay and provisions of their armies in foreign
countries,
but either the rude produce of the soil, of which no
considerable
part could be spared from the home consumption, or a
few
manufactures of the coarsest kind, of which, as well as of
the
rude produce, the transportation was too expensive. This
inability
did not arise from the want of money, but of the finer
and
more improved manufactures. Buying and selling was transacted
by
means of money in England then as well as now. The quantity of
circulating
money must have borne the same proportion, to the
number
and value of purchases and sales usually transacted at
that
time, which it does to those transacted at present ; or,
rather,
it must have borne a greater proportion, because there
was
then no paper, which now occupies a great part of the
employment
of gold and silver. Among nations to whom commerce and
manufactures
are little known, the sovereign, upon extraordinary
occasions,
can seldom draw any considerable aid from his
subjects,
for reasons which shall be explained hereafter. It is
in such
countries, therefore, that he generally endeavours to
accumulate
a treasure, as the only resource against such
emergencies.
Independent of this necessity, he is, in such a
situation,
naturally disposed to the parsimony requisite for
accumulation.
In that simple state, the expense even of a
sovereign
is not directed by the vanity which delights in the
gaudy
finery of a court, but is employed in bounty to his
tenants,
and hospitality to his retainers. But bounty and
hospitality
very seldom lead to extravagance; though vanity
almost
always does. Every Tartar chief,
accordingly, has a
treasure.
The treasures of Mazepa, chief of the Cossacks in the
Ukraine,
the famous ally of Charles XII., are said to have been
very
great. The French kings of the Merovingian race had all
treasures.
When they divided their kingdom among their different
children,
they divided their treasures too. The Saxon princes,
and the
first kings after the Conquest, seem likewise to have
accumulated
treasures. The first exploit of every new reign was
commonly
to seize the treasure of the preceding king, as the most
essential
measure for securing the succession. The sovereigns of
improved
and commercial countries are not under the same
necessity
of accummlating treasures, because they can generally
draw
from their subjects extraordinary aids upon extraordinary
occasions.
They are likewise less disposed to do so. They
naturally,
perhaps necessarily, follow the mode of the times ;
and
their expense comes to be regulated by the same extravagant
vanity
which directs that of all the other great proprietors in
their
dominions. The insignificant pageantry of their court
becomes
every day more brilliant; and the expense of it not only
prevents
accumulation, but frequently encroaches upon the funds
destined
for more necessary expenses. What Dercyllidas said of
the
court of Persia, may be applied to that of several European
princes,
that he saw there much splendour, but little strength,
and
many servants, but few soldiers.
The
importation of gold and silver is not the principal, much
less
the sole benefit, which a nation derives from its foreign
trade.
Between whatever places foreign trade is carried on, they
all of
them derive two distinct benefits from it. It carries out
that
surplus part of the produce of their land and labour for
which
there is no demand among them, and brings back in return
for it
something else for which there is a demand. It gives a
value
to their superfluities, by exchanging them for something
else,
which may satisfy a part of their wants and increase their
enjoyments.
By means of it, the narrowness of the home market
does
not hinder the division of labour in any particular branch
of art
or manufacture from being carried to the highest
perfection.
By opening a more extensive market for whatever part
of the
produce of their labour may exceed the home consumption,
it
encourages them to improve its productive power, and to
augment
its annual produce to the utmost, and thereby to increase
the
real revenue and wealth of the society. These great and
important
services foreign trade is continually occupied in
performing
to all the different countries between which it is
carried
on. They all derive great benefit from it, though that in
which
the merchant resides generally derives the greatest, as he
is
generally more employed in supplying the wants, and carrying
out the
superfluities of his own, than of any other particular
country.
To import the gold and silver which may be wanted into
the
countries which have no mines, is, no doubt a part of the
business
of foreign commerce. It is, however, a most
insignificant
part of it. A country which carried on foreign
trade
merely upon this account, could scarce have occasion to
freight
a ship in a century.
It is
not by the importation of gold and silver that the
discovery
of America has enriched Europe. By the abundance of the
American
mines, those metals have become cheaper. A service of
plate
can now be purchased for about a third part of the corn, or
a third
part of the labour, which it would have cost in the
fifteenth
century. With the same annual expense of labour and
commodities,
Europe can annually purchase about three times the
quantity
of plate which it could have purchased at that time. But
when a
commodity comes to be sold for a third part of what bad
been
its usual price, not only those who purchased it before can
purchase
three times their former quantity, but it is brought
down to
the level of a much greater number of purchasers, perhaps
to more
than ten, perhaps to more than twenty times the former
number.
So that there may be in Europe at present, not only more
than
three times, but more than twenty or thirty times the
quantity
of plate which would have been in it, even in its
present
state of improvement, had the discovery of the American
mines
never been made. So far Europe has, no doubt, gained a real
conveniency,
though surely a very trifling one. The cheapness of
gold
and silver renders those metals rather less fit for the
purposes
of money than they were before. In order to make the
same
purchases, we must load ourselves with a greater quantity of
them,
and carry about a shilling in our pocket, where a groat
would
have done before. It is difficult to say which is most
trifling,
this inconveniency, or the opposite conveniency.
Neither
the one nor the other could have made any very essential
change
in the state of Europe. The discovery of America, however,
certainly
made a most essential one. By opening a new and
inexhaustible
market to all the commodities of Europe, it gave
occasion
to new divisions of labour and improvements of art,
which
in the narrow circle of the ancient commerce could never
have
taken place, for want of a market to take off the greater
part of
their produce. The productive powers of labour were
improved,
and its produce increased in all the different
countries
of Europe, and together with it the real revenue and
wealth
of the inhabitants. The commodities of Europe were almost
all new
to America, and many of those of America were new to
Europe.
A new set of exchanges, therefore, began to take place,
which
had never been thought of before, and which should
naturally
have proved as advantageous to the new, as it certainly
did to
the old continent. The savage injustice of the Europeans
rendered
an event, which ought to have been beneficial to all,
ruinous
and destructive to several of those unfortunate
countries.
The
discovery of a passage to the East Indies by the Cape of Good
Hope,
which happened much about the same time, opened perhaps a
still
more extensive range to foreign commerce, than even that of
America,
notwithstanding the greater distance. There were but two
nations
in America, in any respect, superior to the savages, and
these
were destroyed almost as soon as discovered. The rest were
mere
savages. But the empires of China, Indostan, Japan, as well
as
several others in the East Indies, without having richer mines
of gold
or silver, were, in every other respect, much richer,
better
cultivated, and more advanced in all arts and
manufactures,
than either Mexico or Peru, even though we should
credit,
what plainly deserves no credit, the exaggerated accounts
of the
Spanish writers concerning the ancient state of those
empires.
But rich and civilized nations can always exchange to a
much
greater value with one another, than with savages and
barbarians.
Europe, however, has hitherto derived much less
advantage
from its commerce with the East Indies, than from that
with
America. The Portuguese monopolized the East India trade to
themselves
for about a century ; and it was only indirectly, and
through
them, that the other nations of Europe could either send
out or
receive any goods from that country. When the Dutch, in
the
beginning of the last century, began to encroach upon them,
they
vested their whole East India commerce in an exclusive
company.
The English, French, Swedes, and Danes, have all
followed
their example; so that no great nation of Europe has
ever
yet had the benefit of a free commerce to the East Indies.
No
other reason need be assigned why it has never been so
advantageous
as the trade to America, which, between almost every
nation
of Europe and its own colonies, is free to all its
subjects.
The exclusive privileges of those East India companies,
their
great riches, the great favour and protection which these
have
procured them from their respective governments, have
excited
much envy against them. This envy has frequently
represented
their trade as altogether pernicious, on account of
the
great quantities of silver which it every year exports from
the
countries from which it is carried on. The parties concerned
have
replied, that their trade by this continual exportation of
silver,
might indeed tend to impoverish Europe in general, but
not the
particular country from which it was carried on ;
because,
by the exportation of a part of the returns to other
European
countries, it annually brought home a much greater
quantity
of that metal than it carried out. Both the objection
and the
reply are founded in the popular notion which I have been
just
now examining. It is therefore unnecessary to say any thing
further
about either. By the annual exportation of silver to the
East
Indies, plate is probably somrwhat dearer in Europe than it
otherwise
might have been ; and coined silver probably purchases
a
larger quantity both of labour and commodities. The former of
these
two effects is a very small loss, the latter a very small
advantage
; both too insignificant to deserve any part of the
public
attention. The trade to the East Indies, by opening a
market
to the commodities of Europe, or, what comes nearly to the
same
thing, to the gold and silver which is purchased with those
commodities,
must necessarily tend to increase the annual
production
of European commodities, and consequently the real
wealth
and revenue of Europe. That it has hitherto increased them
so
little, is probably owing to the restraints which it
everywhere
labours under.
I
thought it necessary, though at the hazard of being tedious, to
examine
at full length this popular notion, that wealth consists
in
money or in gold and silver. Money, in common language, as I
have
already observed, frequently signifies wealth ; and this
ambiguity
of expression has rendered this popular notion so
familiar
to us, that even they who are convinced of its
absurdity,
are very apt to forget their own principles, and, in
the
course of their reasonings, to take it for granted as a
certain
and undeniable truth. Some of the best English writers
upon
commerce set out with observing, that the wealth of a
country
consists, not in its gold and silver only, but in its
lands,
houses, and consumable goods of all different kinds. In
the
course of their reasonings, however, the lands, houses, and
consumable
goods, seem to slip out of their memory; and the
strain of
their argument frequently supposes that all wealth
consists
in gold and silver, and that to multiply those metals is
the
great object of national industry and commerce.
The two
principles being established, however, that wealth
consisted
in gold and silver, and that those metals could be
brought
into a country which had no mines, only by the balance of
trade,
or by exporting to a greater value than it imported ; it
necessarily
became the great object of political economy to
diminish
as much as possible the importation of foreign goods for
home
consumption, and to increase as much as possible the
exportation
of the produce of domestic industry. Its two great
engines
for enriching the country, therefore, were restraints
upon
importation, and encouragement to exportation.
The
restraints upon importation were of two kinds.
First,
restraints upon the importation of such foreign goods for
home
consumption as could be produced at home, from whatever
country
they were imported.
Secondly,
restraints upon the importation of goods of almost all
kinds,
from those particular countries with which the balance of
trade
was supposed to be disadvantageous.
Those
different restraints consisted sometimes in high duties,
and
sometimes in absolute prohibitions.
Exportation
was encouraged sometimes by drawbacks, sometimes by
bounties,
sometimes by advantageous treaties of commerce with
foreign
states, and sometimes by the establishment of colonies in
distant
countries.
Drawbacks
were given upon two different occasions. When the home
manufactures
were subject to any duty or excise, either the whole
or a
part of it was frequently drawn back upon their exportation
; and
when foreign goods liable to a duty were imported, in order
to be
exported again, either the whole or a part of this duty was
sometimes
given back upon such exportation.
Bounties
were given for the encouragemnent, either of some
beginning
manufactures, or of such sorts of industry of other
kinds
as were supposed to deserve particular favour.
By
advantageous treaties of commerce, particular privileges were
procured
in some foreign state for the goods and merchants of the
country,
beyond what were granted to those of other countries.
By the
establishment of colonies in distant countries, not only
particular
privileges, but a monopoly was frequently procured for
the
goods and merchants of the country which established them.
The two
sorts of restraints upon importation above mentioned,
together
with these four encouragements to exportation,
constitute
the six principal means by which the commercial system
proposes
to increase the quantity of gold and silver in any
country,
by turning the balance of trade in its favour. I shall
consider
each of them in a particular chapter, and, without
taking
much farther notice of their supposed tendency to bring
money
into the country, I shall examine chiefly what are likely
to be
the effects of each of them upon the annual produce of its
industry.
According as they tend either to increase or diminish
the
value of this annual produce, they must evidently tend either
to
increase or diminish the real wealth and revenue of the
country.
CHAPTER II.
OF
RESTRAINTS UPON IMPORTATION FROM FOREIGN COUNTRIES OF SUCH
GOODS
AS CAN BE PRODUCED AT HOME.
By
restraining, either by high duties, or by absolute
prohibitions,
the importation of such goods from foreign
countries
as can be produced at home, the monopoly of the home
market
is more or less secured to the domestic industry employed
in
producing them. Thus the prohibition of importing either live
cattle
or salt provisions from foreign countries, secures to the
graziers
of Great Britain the monopoly of the home market for
butcher's
meat. The high duties upon the importation of corn,
which,
in times of moderate plenty, amount to a prohibition, give
a like
advantage to the growers of that commodity. The
prohibition
of the importation of foreign woollen is equally
favourable
to the woollen manufacturers. The silk manufacture,
though
altogether employed upon foreign materials, has lately
obtained
the same advantage. The linen manufacture has not yet
obtained
it, but is making great strides towards it. Many other
sorts
of manufactures have, in the same manner obtained in Great
Britain,
either altogether, or very nearly, a monopoly against
their
countrymen. The variety of goods, of which the importation
into
Great Britain is prohibited, either absolutely, or under
certain
circumstances, greatly exceeds what can easily be
suspected
by those who are not well acquainted with the laws of
the
customs.
That
this monopoly of the home market frequently gives great
encouragement
to that particular species of industry which enjoys
it, and
frequently turns towards that employment a greater share
of both
the labour and stock of the society than would otherwise
have
gone to it, cannot be doubted. But whether it tends either
to
increase the general industry of the society, or to give it
the
most advantageous direction, is not, perhaps, altogether so
evident.
The
general industry of the society can never exceed what the
capital
of the society can employ. As the number of workmen that
can be
kept in employment by any particular person must bear a
certain
proportion to his capital, so the number of those that
can be
continually employed by all the members of a great society
must
bear a certain proportion to the whole capital of the
society,
and never can exceed that proportion. No regulation of
commerce
can increase the quantity of industry in any society
beyond
what its capital can maintain. It can only divert a part
of it
into a direction into which it might not otherwise have
gone;
and it is by no means certain that this artificial
direction
is likely to be more advantageous to the society, than
that
into which it would have gone of its own accord.
Every
individual is continually exerting himself to find out the
most
advantageous employment for whatever capital he can command.
It is
his own advantage, indeed, and not that of the society,
which
he has in view. But the study of his own advantage
naturally,
or rather necessarily, leads him to prefer that
employment
which is most advantageous to the society.
First,
every individual endeavours to employ his capital as near
home as
he can, and consequently as much as he can in the support
of
domestic industry, provided always that he can thereby obtain
the
ordinary, or not a great deal less than the ordinary profits
of
stock.
Thus,
upon equal, or nearly equal profits, every wholesale
merchant
naturally prefers the home trade to the foreign trade of
consumption,
and the foreign trade of consumption to the carrying
trade.
In the home trade, his capital is never so long out of his
sight
as it frequently is in the foreign trade of consumption. He
can
know better the character and situation of the persons whom
he
trusts; and if he should happen to be deceived, he knows
better
the laws of the country from which he must seek redress.
In the carrying
trade, the capital of the merchant is,
as it
were,
divided between two foreign countries, and no part of it is
ever
necessarily brought home, or placed under his own immediate
view
and command. The capital which an Amsterdam merchant employs
in
carrying corn from Koningsberg to Lisbon, and fruit and wine
from
Lisbon to Koningsberg, must generally be the one half of it
at
Koningsberg, and the other half at Lisbon. No part of it need
ever
come to Amsterdam. The natural residence of such a merchant
should
either be at Koningsberg or Lisbon ; and it can only be
some
very particular circumstances which can make him prefer the
residence
of Amsterdam. The uneasiness, however, which he feels
at
being separated so far from his capital, generally determines
him to
bring part both of the Koningsberg goods which he destines
for the
market of Lisbon, and of the Lisbon goods which he
destines
for that of Koningsberg, to Amsterdam ; and though this
necessarily
subjects him to a double charge of loading and
unloading
as well as to the payment of some duties and customs,
yet,
for the sake of having some part of his capital always under
his own
view and command, he willingly submits to this
extraordinary
charge; and it is in this manner that every country
which
has any considerable share of the carrying trade, becomes
always
the emporium, or general market, for the goods of all the
different
countries whose trade it carries on. The merchant, in
order
to save a second loading and unloading, endeavours always
to sell
in the home market, as much of the goods of all those
different
countries as he can; and thus, so far as he can, to
convert
his carrying trade into a foreign trade of consumption. A
merchant,
in the same manner, who is engaged in the foreign trade
of
consumption, when he collects goods for foreign markets, will
always
be glad, upon equal or nearly equal profits, to sell as
great a
part of them at home as he can. He saves himself the risk
and
trouble of exportation, when, so far as he can, he thus
converts
his foreign trade of consumption into a home trade. Home
is in
this manner the centre, if I may say so, round which the
capitals
of the inhabitants of every country are continually
circulating,
and towards which they are always tending, though,
by
particular causes, they may sometimes be driven off and
repelled
from it towards more distant employments. But a capital
employed
in the home trade, it has already been shown,
necessarily
puts into motion a greater quantity of domestic
industry,
and gives revenue and employment to a greater number of
the
inhabitants of the country, than an equal capital employed in
the
foreign trade of consumption; and one employed in the foreign
trade
of consumption has the same advantage over an equal capital
employed
in the carrying trade. Upon equal, or only nearly equal
profits,
therefore, every individual naturally inclines to employ
his
capital in the manner in which it is likely to afford the
greatest
support to domestic industry, and to give revenue and
employment
to the greatest number of people of his own country.
Secondly,
every individual who employs his capital in the support
of
domestic industry, necessarily endeavours so to direct that
industry,
that its produce may be of the greatest possible value.
The
produce of industry is what it adds to the subject or
materials
upon which it is employed. In proportion as the value
of this
produce is great or small, so will likewise be the
profits
of the employer. But it is only for the sake of profit
that
any man employs a capital in the support of industry; and he
will
always, therefore, endeavour to employ it in the support of
that
industry of which the produce is likely to be of the
greatest
value, or to exchange for the greatest quantity either
of
money or of other goods.
But the
annual revenue of every society is always precisely equal
to the
exchangeable value of the whole annual produce of its
industry,
or rather is precisely the same thing with that
exchangeable
value. As every individual, therefore, endeavours as
much as
he can, both to employ his capital in the support of
domestic
industry, and so to direct that industry that its
produce
maybe of the greatest value; every individual necessarily
labours
to render the annual revenue of the society as great as
he can.
He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the
public
interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it. By
preferring
the support of domestic to that of foreign industry,
he
intends only his own security ; and by directing that industry
in such
a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he
intends
only his own gain; and he is in this, as in many other
cases,
led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no
part of
his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society
that it
was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest, he
frequently
promotes that of the society more effectually than
when he
really intends to promote it. I have never known much
good
done by those who affected to trade for the public good. It
is an
affectation, indeed, not very common among merchants, and
very
few words need be employed in dissuading them from it.
What is
the species of domestic industry which his capital can
employ,
and of which the produce is likely to be of the greatest
value,
every individual, it is evident, can in his local
situation
judge much better than any statesman or lawgiver can do
for
him. The statesmn, who should attempt to direct private
people
in what manner they ought to employ their capitals, would
not
only load himself with a most unnecessary attention, but
assume
an authority which could safely be trusted, not only to no
single
person, but to no council or senate whatever. and which
would
nowhere be so dangerous as in the hands of a man who had
folly
and presumption enough to fancy himself fit to exercise it.
To give
the monopoly of the home market to the produce of
domestic
industry, in any particular art or manufacture, is in
some
measure to direct private people in what manner they ought
to
employ their capitals, and must in almost all cases be either
a
useless or a hurtful regulation. If the produce of domestic can
be
brought there as cheap as that of foreign industry, the
regulation
is evidently useless. If it cannot, it must generally
be
hurtful. It is the maxim of every prudent master of a family,
never
to attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to
make
than to buy. The tailor does not attempt to make his own
shoes,
but buys them of the shoemaker. The shoemaker does not
attempt
to make his own clothes, but employs a tailor. The farmer
attempts
to make neither the one nor the other, but employs those
different
artificers. All of them find it for their interest to
employ
their whole industry in a way in which they have some
advantage
over their neighbours, and to purchase with a part of
its
produce, or, what is the same thing, with the price of a part
of it,
whatever else they have occasion for.
What is
prudence in the conduct of every private family, can
scarce
be folly In that of a great kingdom. If a foreign country
can
supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make
it,
better buy it of them with some part of the produce of our
own
industry, employed in a way in which we have some advantage.
The
general industry of the country being always in proportion to
the
capital which employs it, will not thereby be diminished, no
more
than that of the abovementioned artificers; but only left to
find
out the way in which it can be employed with the greatest
advantage.
It is certainly not employed to the greatest
advantage,
when it is thus directed towards an object which it
can buy
cheaper than it can make. The value of its annual produce
is certainly
more or less diminished, when it is thus turned away
from
producing commodities evidently of more value than the
commodity
which it is directed to produce. According to the
supposition,
that commodity could be purchased from foreign
countries
cheaper than it can be made at home ; it could
therefore
have been purchased with a part only of the
commodities,
or, what is the same thing, with a part only of the
price
of the commodities, which the industry employed by an equal
capital
would have produced at home, had it been left to follow
its
natural course. The industry of the country, therefore, is
thus
turned away from a more to a less advantageous employment ;
and the
exchangeable value of its annual produce, instead of
being
increased, according to the intention of the lawgiver, must
necessarily
be diminished by every such regulation.
By
means of such regulations, indeed, a particular manufacture
may
sometimes be acquired sooner than it could have been
otherwise,
and after a certain time may be made at home as cheap,
or
cheaper, than in the foreign country. But though the industry
of the
society may be thus carried with advantage into a
particular
channel sooner than it could have been otherwise, it
will by
no means follow that the sum-total, either of its
industry,
or of its revenue, can ever be augmented by any such
regulation.
The industry of the society can augment only in
proportion
as its capital augments, and its capital can augment
only in
proportion to what can be gradually saved out of its
revenue.
But the immediate effect of every such regulation is to
diminish
its revenue; and what diminishes its revenue is
certainly
not very likely to augment its capital faster than it
would
have augmented of its own accord, had both capital and
industry
been left to find out their natural employments.
Though,
for want of such regulations, the society should never
acquire
the proposed manufacture, it would not upon that account
necessarily
be the poorer in anyone period of its duration. In
every
period of its duration its whole capital and industry might
still
have been employed, though upon different objects, in the
manner
that was most advantageous at the time. In every period
its
revenue might have been the greatest which its capital could
afford,
and both capital and revenue might have been augmented
with
the greatest possible rapidity.
The
natural advantages which one country has over another, in
producing
particular commodities, are sometimes so great, that it
is
acknowledged by all the world to be in vain to struggle with
them.
By means of glasses, hot-beds, and hot-walls, very good
grapes
can be raised in Scotland, and very good wine, too, can be
made of
them, at about thirty times the expense for which at
least
equally good can be brought from foreign countries. Would
it be a
reasonable law to prohibit the importation of all foreign
wines,
merely to encourage the making of claret and Burgundy in
Scotland
? But if there would be a manifest absurdity in turning
towards
any employment thirty times more of the capital and
industry
of the country than would be necessary to purchase from
foreign
countries an equal quantity of the commodities wanted,
there
must be an absurdity, though not altogether so glaring, yet
exactly
of the same kind, in turning towards any such employment
a
thirtieth, or even a three hundredth part more of either.
Whether
the advantages which one country has over another be
natural
or acquired, is in this respect of no consequence. As
long as
the one country has those advantages, and the other wants
them,
it will always be more advantageous for the latter rather
to buy
of the former than to make. It is an acquired advantage
only,
which one artificer has over his neighbour, who exercises
another
trade; and yet they both find it more advantageous to buy
of one
another, than to make what does not belong to their
particular
trades.
Merchants
and manufacturers are the people who derive the
greatest
advantage from this monopoly of the home market The
prohibition
of the importation of foreign cattle and of salt
provisions,
together with the high duties upon foreign corn,
which
in times of moderate plenty amount to a prohibition, are
not
near so advantageous to the graziers and farmers of Great
Britain,
as other regulations of the same kind are to its
merchants
and manufacturers. Manufactures, those of the finer
kind
especially, are more easily transported from one country to
another
than corn or cattle. It is in the fetching and carrying
manufactures,
accordingly, that foreign trade is chiefly
employed.
In manufactures, a very small advantage will enable
foreigners
to undersell our own workmen, even in the home market.
It will
require a very great one to enable them to do so in the
rude
produce of the soil. If the free importation of foreign
manufactures
were permitted, several of the home manufactures
would
probably suffer,and some of them perhaps go to ruin
altogether,
and a considerable part of the stock and industry at
present
employed in them, would be forced to find out some other
employment.
But the freest importation of the rude produce of the
soil
could have no such effect upon the agriculture of the
country.
If the
importation of foreign cattle, for example, were made ever
so
free, so few could be imported, that the grazing trade of
Great
Britain could be little affected by it. Live cattle are,
perhaps,
the only commodity of which the transportation is more
expensive
by sea than by land. By land they carry themselves to
market.
By sea, not only the cattle, but their food and their
water
too, must be carried at no small expense and inconveniency.
The
short sea between Ireland and Great Britain, indeed, renders
the
importation of Irish cattle more easy. But though the free
importation
of them, which was lately permitted only for a
limited
time, were rendered perpetual, it could have no
considerable
effect upon the interest of the graziers of Great
Britain.
Those parts of Great Britain which border upon the Irish
sea are
all grazing countries. Irish cattle could never be
imported
for their use, but must be drove through those very
extensive
countries, at no small expense and inconveniency,
before
they could arrive at their proper market. Fat cattle could
not be
drove so far. Lean cattle, therefore, could only be
imported;
and such importation could interfere not with the
interest
of the feeding or fattening countries, to which, by
reducing
the price of lean cattle it would rather be
advantageous,
but with that of the breeding countries only. The
small
number of Irish cattle imported since their importation was
permitted,
together with the good price at which lean cattle
still
continue to sell, seem to demonstrate, that even the
breeding
countries of Great Britain are never likely to be much
affected
by the free importation of Irish cattle. The common
people
of Ireland, indeed, are said to have sometimes opposed
with
violence the exportation of their cattle. But if the
exporters
had found any great advantage in continuing the trade,
they
could easily, when the law was on their side, have conquered
this
mobbish opposition.
Feeding
and fattening countries, besides, must always be highly
improved,
whereas breeding countries are generally uncultivated.
The
high price of lean cattle, by augmenting the value of
uncultivated
land, is like a bounty against improvement. To any
country
which was highly improved throughout, it would be more
advantageous
to import its lean cattle than to breed them. The
province
of Holland, accordingly, is said to follow this maxim at
present.
The mountains of Scotland, Wales, and Northumberland,
indeed,
are countries not capable of much improvement, and seem
destined
by nature to be the breeding countries of Great Britain.
The
freest importation of foreign cattle could have no other
effect
than to hinder those breeding countries from taking
advantage
of the increasing population and improvement of the
rest of
the kingdom, from raising their price to an exorbitant
height,
and from laying a real tax upon all the more improved and
cultivated
parts of the country.
The
freest importation of salt provisions, in the same manner,
could
have as little effect upon the interest of the graziers of
Great
Britain as that of live cattle. Salt provisions are not
only a
very bulky commodity, but when compared with fresh meat
they
are a commodity both of worse quality, and, as they cost
more
labour and expense, of higher price. They could never,
therefore,
come into competition with the fresh meat, though they
might
with the salt provisions of the country. They might be used
for
victualling ships for distant voyages, and such like uses,
but
could never make any considerable part of the food of the
people.
The small quantity of salt provisions imported from
Ireland
since their importation was rendered free, is an
experimental
proof that our graziers have nothing to apprehend
from
it. It does not appear that the
price of butchet's meat
has
ever been sensibly affected by it.
Even
the free importation of foreign corn could very little
affect
the interest of the farmers of Great Britain. Corn is a
much
more bulky commodity than butcher's meat. A pound of wheat
at a
penny is as dear as a pound of butcher's meat at fourpence.
The
small quantity of foreign corn imported even in times of the
greatest
scarcity, may satisfy our farmers that they can have
nothing
to fear from the freest importation. The average quantity
imported,
one year with another, amounts only, according to the
very
well informed author of the Tracts upon the Corn Trade, to
23,728
quarters of all sorts of grain, and does not exceed the
five
hundredth and seventy-one part of the annual consumption.
But as
the bounty upon corn occasions a greater exportation in
years
of plenty, so it must, of consequence, occasion a greater
importation
in years of scarcity, than in the actual state of
tillage
would otherwise take place. By means of it, the plenty of
one
year does not compensate the scarcity of another; and as the
average
quantity exported is necessarily augmented by it, so must
likewise,
in the actual state of tillage, the average quantity
imported.
If there were no bounty, as less corn would be
exported,
suit is probable that, one year with another, less
would
be imported than at present. The corn-merchants, the
fetchers
and carriers of corn between Great Britain and foreign
countries,
would have much less employment, and might suffer
considerably
; but the country gentlemen and farmers could suffer
very
little. It is in the corn-merchants, accordingly, rather
than
the country gentlemen and farmers, that I have observed the
greatest
anxiety for the renewal and continuation of the bounty.
Country
gentlemen and farmers are, to their great honour, of all
people,
the least subject to the wretched spirit of monopoly. The
undertaker
of a great manufactory is sometimes alarmed if another
work of
the same kind is established within twenty miles of him;
the
Dutch undertaker of the woollen manufacture at Abbeville,
stipulated
that no work of the same kind should be established
within
thirty leagues of that city. Farmers and country
gentlemen,
on the contrary, are generally disposed rather to
promote,
than to obstruct, the cultivation and improvement of
their
neighbours farms and estates. They have no secrets, such as
those
of the greater part of manufacturers, but are generally
rather
fond of communicating to their neighbours, and of
extending
as far as possible any new practice which they may have
found
to be advantageous. "Pius quaestus", says old Cato,
"stabilissimusque,
minimeque invidiosus; minimeque male
cogitantes
sunt, qui in eo studio occupati sunt." Country
gentlemen
and farmers, dispersed in different parts of the
country,
cannot so easily combine as merchants and manufacturers,
who
being collected into towns, and accustomed to that exclusive
corporation
spirit which prevails in them, naturally endeavour to
obtain,
against all their countrymen, the same exclusive
privilege
which they generally possess against the inhabitants of
their
respective towns. They accordingly seem to have been the
original
inventors of those restraints upon the importation of
foreign
goods, which secure to them the monopoly of the home
market.
It was probably in imitation of them, and to put
themselves
upon a level with those who, they found, were disposed
to
oppress them, that the country gentlemen and farmers of Great
Britain
so far forgot the generosity which is natural to their
station,
as to demand the exclusive privilege of supplying their
countrymen
with corn and butcher's meat. They did not, perhaps,
take
time to consider how much less their interest could be
affected
by the freedom of trade, than that of the people whose
example
they followed.
To
prohibit, by a perpetual law, the importation of foreign corn
and
cattle, is in reality to enact, that the population and
industry
of the country shall, at no time, exceed what the rude
produce
of its own soil can maintain.
There
seem, however, to be two cases, in which it will generally
be
advantageous to lay some burden upon foreign, for the
encouragement
of domestic industry.
The
first is, when some particular sort of industry is necessary
for the
defence of the country. The defence of Great Britain, for
example,
depends very much upon the number of its sailors and
shipping.
The act of navigation, therefore, very properly
endeavours
to give the sailors and shipping of Great Britain the
monopoly
of the trade of their own country, in some cases, by
absolute
prohibitions, and in others, by heavy burdens upon the
shipping
of foreign countries. The following are the principal
dispositions
of this act.
First,
All ships, of which the owners, masters, and three-fourths
of the
mariners, are not British subjects, are prohibited, upon
pain of
forfeiting ship and cargo, from trading to the British
settlements
and plantations, or from being employed in the
coasting
trade of Great Britain.
Secondly,
A great variety of the most bulky articles of
importation
can be brought into Great Britain only, either in
such
ships as are above described, or in ships of the country
where
those goods are produced, and of which the owners, masters,
and
three-fourths of the mariners, are of that particular country
; and
when imported even in ships of this latter kind, they are
subject
to double aliens duty. If imported in ships of any other
country,
the penalty is forfeiture of ship and goods. When this
act was
made, the Dutch were, what they still are, the great
carriers
of Europe; and by this regulation they were entirely
excluded
from being the carriers to Great Britain, or from
importing
to us the goods of any other European country.
Thirdly,
A great variety of the most bulky articles of
importation
are prohibited from being imported, even in British
ships,
from any country but that in which they are produced,
under
pain of forfeiting ship and cargo. This regulation, too,
was
probably intended against the Dutch. Holland was then, as
now,
the great emporium for all European goods ; and by this
regulation,
British ships were hindered from loading in Holland
the
goods of any other European country.
Fourthly,
Salt fish of all kinds, whale fins, whalebone, oil, and
blubber,
not caught by and cured on board British vessels, when
imported
into Great Britain, are subject to double aliens duty.
The
Dutch, as they are still the principal, were then the only
fishers
in Europe that attempted to supply foreign nations with
fish.
By this regulation, a very heavy burden was laid upon their
supplying
Great Britain.
When
the act of navigation was made, though England and Holland
were
not actually at war, the most violent animosity subsisted
between
the two nations. It had begun during the government of
the
long parliament, which first framed this act, and it broke
out
soon after in the Dutch wars, during that of the Protector
and of
Charles II. It is not impossible, therefore, that some of
the
regulations of this famous act may have proceeded from
national
animosity. They are as wise, however, as if they had all
been
dictated by the most deliberate wisdom. National animosity,
at that
particular time, aimed at the very same object which the
most
deliberate wisdom would have recommended, the diminution of
the
naval power of Holland, the only naval power which could
endanger
the security of England.
The act
of navigation is not favourable to foreign commerce, or
to the
growth of that opulence which can arise from it. The
interest
of a nation, in its commercial relations to foreign
nations,
is, like that of a merchant with regard to the different
people
with whom he deals, to buy as cheap, and to sell as dear
as
possible. But it will be most likely to buy cheap, when, by
the
most perfect freedom of trade, it encourages all nations to
bring
to it the goods which it has occasion to purchase ; and,
for the
same reason, it will be most likely to sell dear, when
its
markets are thus filled with the greatest number of buyers.
The act
of navigation, it is true, lays no burden upon foreign
ships
that come to export the produce of British industry. Even
the
ancient aliens duty, which used to be paid upon all goods,
exported
as well as imported, has, by several subsequent acts,
been
taken off from the greater part of the articles of
exportation.
But if foreigners, either by prohibitions or high
duties,
are hindered from coming to sell, they cannot always
afford
to come to buy ; because, coming without a cargo, they
must
lose the freight from their own country to Great Britain. By
diminishing
the number of sellers, therefore, we necessarily
diminish
that of buyers, and are thus likely not only to buy
foreign
goods dearer, but to sell our own cheaper, than if there
was a
more perfect freedom of trade. As defence, however, is of
much
more importance than opulence, the act of navigation is,
perhaps,
the wisest of all the commercial regulations of England.
The
second case, in which it will generally be advantageous to
lay
some burden upon foreign for the encouragement of domestic
industry,
is when some tax is imposed at home upon the produce of
the
latter. In this case, it seems reasonable that an equal tax
should
be imposed upon the like produce of the former. This would
not
give the monopoly of the borne market to domestic industry,
nor
turn towards a particular employment a greater share of the
stock
and labour of the country, than what would naturally go to
it. It
would only hinder any part of what would naturally go to
it from
being turned away by the tax into a less natural
direction,
and would leave the competition between foreign and
domestic
industry, after the tax, as nearly as possible upon the
same
footing as before it. In Great Britain, when any such tax is
laid
upon the produce of domestic industry, it is usual, at the
same
time, in order to stop the clamorous complaints of our
merchants
and manufacturers, that they will be undersold at home,
to lay
a much heavier duty upon the importation of all foreign
goods
of the same kind.
This
second limitation of the freedom of trade, according to some
people,
should, upon most occasions, be extended much farther
than to
the precise foreign commodities which could come into
competition
with those which had been taxed at home. When the
necessaries
of life have been taxed in any country, it becomes
proper,
they pretend, to tax not only the like necessaries of
life
imported from other countries, but all sorts of foreign
goods
which can come into competition with any thing that is the
produce
of domestic industry. Subsistence, they say, becomes
necessarily
dearer in consequence of such taxes ; and the price
of
labour must always rise with the price of the labourer's
subsistence.
Every commodity, therefore, which is the produce of
domestic
industry, though not immediately taxed itself, becomes
dearer
in consequence of such taxes, because the labour which
produces
it becomes so. Such taxes, therefore, are really
equivalent,
they say, to a tax upon every particular commodity
produced
at home. In order to put domestic upon the same footing
with
foreign industry, therefore, it becomes necessary, they
think,
to lay some duty upon every foreign commodity, equal to
this
enhancement of the price of the home commodities with which
it can
come into competition.
Whether
taxes upon the necessaries of life, such as those in
Great
Britain upon soap, salt, leather, candles, etc. necessarily
raise
the price of labour, and consequently that of all other
commodities,
I shall consider hereafter, when I come to treat of
taxes.
Supposing, however, in the mean time, that they have this
effect,
and they have it undoubtedly, this general enhancement of
the
price of all commodities, in consequence of that labour, is a
case
which differs in the two following respects from that of a
particular
commodity, of which the price was enhanced by a
particular
tax immediately imposed upon it.
First,
It might always be known with great exactness, how far the
price
of such a commodity could be enhanced by such a tax ; but
how far
the general enhancement of the price of labour might
affect
that of every different commodity about which labour was
employed,
could never be known with any tolerable exactness. It
would
be impossible, therefore, to proportion, with any tolerable
exactness,
the tax of every foreign, to the enhancement of the
price
of every home commodity.
Secondly,
Taxes upon the necessaries of life have nearly the same
effect
upon the circumstances of the people as a poor soil and a
bad
climate. Provisions are thereby rendered dearer, in the same
manner
as if it required extraordinary labour and expense to
raise
them. As, in the natural scarcity arising from soil and
climate,
it would be absurd to direct the people in what manner
they
ought to employ their capitals and industry, so is it
likewise
in the artificial scarcity arising from such taxes. To
be left
to accommodate, as well as they could, their industry to
their
situation, and to find out those employments in which,
notwithstanding
their unfavourable circumstances, they might have
some
advantage either in the home or in the foreign market, is
what,
in both cases, would evidently be most for their advantage.
To lay
a new-tax upon them, because they are already overburdened
with
taxes, and because they already pay too dear for the
necessaries
of life, to make them likewise pay too dear for the
greater
part of other commodities, is certainly a most absurd way
of
making amends.
Such
taxes, when they have grown up to a certain height, are a
curse
equal to the barrenness of the earth, and the inclemency of
the
heavens, and yet it is in the richest and most industrious
countries
that they have been most generally imposed. No other
countries
could support so great a disorder. As the strongest
bodies
only can live and enjoy health under an unwholesome
regimen,
so the nations only, that in every sort of industry have
the
greatest natural and acquired advantages, can subsist and
prosper
under such taxes. Holland is the country in Europe in
which
they abound most, and which, from peculiar circumstances,
continues
to prosper, not by means of them, as has been most
absurdly
supposed, but in spite of them.
As
there are two cases in which it will generally be advantageous
to lay
some burden upon foreign for the encouragement of domestic
industry,
so there are two others in which it may sometimes be a
matter
of deliberation, in the one, how far it is proper to
continue
the free importation of certain foreign goods; and, in
the
other, how far, or in what manner, it may be proper to
restore
that free importation, after it has been for some time
interrupted.
The
case in which it may sometimes be a matter of deliberation
how far
it is proper to continue the free importation of certain
foreign
goods, is when some foreign nation restrains, by high
duties
or prohibitions, the importation of some of our
manufactures
into their country. Revenge, in this case, naturally
dictates
retaliation, and that we should impose the like duties
and
prohibitions upon the importation of some or all of their
manufactures
into ours. Nations, accordingly, seldom fail to
retaliate
in this manner. The French have been particularly
forward
to favour their own manufactures, by restraining the
importation
of such foreign goods as could come into competition
with
them. In this consisted a great part of the policy of Mr
Colbert,
who, notwithstanding his great abilities, seems in this
case to
have been imposed upon by the sophistry of merchants and
manufacturers,
who are always demanding a monopoly against their
countrymen.
It is at present the opinion of the most intelligent
men in
France, that his operations of this kind have not been
beneficial
to his country. That minister, by the tariff of 1667,
imposed
very high duties upon a great number of foreign
manufactures.
Upon his refusing to moderate them in favour of the
Dutch,
they, in 1671, prohibited the importation of the wines,
brandies,
and manufactures of France. The war of 1672 seems to
have
been in part occasioned by this commercial dispute. The
peace
of Nimeguen put an end to it in 1678, by moderating some of
those
duties in favour of the Dutch, who in consequence took off
their
prohibition. It was about the same time that the French and
English
began mutually to oppress each other's industry, by the
like
duties and prohibitions, of which the French, however, seem
to have
set the first example, The spirit of hostility which has
subsisted
between the two nations ever since, has hitherto
hindered
them from being moderated on either side. In 1697, the
Ehglish
prohibited the importation of bone lace, the manufacture
of
Flanders. The government of that country, at that time under
the
dominion of Spain, prohibited, in return, the importation of
English
woollens. In 1700, the prohibition of importing bone lace
into
England was taken oft; upon condition that the importation
of
English woollens into Flanders should be put on the same
footing
as before.
There
may be good policy in retaliations of this kind, when there
is a
probability that they will procure the repeal of the high
duties
or prohibitions complained of. The recovery of a great
foreign
market will generally more than compensate the transitory
inconveniency
of paying dearer during a short time for some sorts
of
goods. To judge whether such retaliations are likely to
produce
such an effect, does not, perhaps, belong so much to the
science
of a legislator, whose deliberations ought to be governed
by
general principles, which are always the same, as to the skill
of that
insidious and crafty animal vulgarly called a statesman
or
politician, whose councils are directed by the momentary
fluctuations
of affairs. When there is no probability that any
such
repeal can be procured, it seems a bad method of
compensating
the injury done to certain classes of our people, to
do
another injury ourselves, not only to those classes, but to
almost
all the other classes of them. When our neighbours
prohibit
some manufacture of ours, we generally prohibit, not
only
the same, for that alone would seldom affect them
considerably,
but some other manufacture of theirs. This may, no
doubt,
give encouragement to some particular class of workmen
among
ourselves, and, by excluding some of their rivals, may
enable
them to raise their price in the home market. Those
workmen
however, who suffered by our neighbours prohibition, will
not be
benefited by ours. On the contrary, they, and almost all
the
other classes of our citizens, will thereby be obliged to pay
dearer
than before for certain goods. Every such law, therefore,
imposes
a real tax upon the whole country, not in favour of that
particular
class of workmen who were injured by our neighbours
prohibitions,
but of some other class.
The
case in which it may sometimes be a matter of deliberation,
how
far, or in what manner, it is proper to restore the free
importation
of foreign goods, after it has been for some time
interrupted,
is when particular manufactures, by means of high
duties
or prohibitions upon all foreign goods which can come into
competition
with them, have been so far extended as to employ a
great
multitude of hands. Humanity may in this case require that
the
freedom of trade should be restored only by slow gradations,
and
with a good deal of reserve and circumspection. Were those
high
duties and prohibitions taken away all at once, cheaper
foreign
goods of the same kind might be poured so fast into the
home
market, as to deprive all at once many thousands of our
people
of their ordinary employment and means of subsistence. The
disorder
which this would occasion might no doubt be very
considerable.
It would in all probability, however, be much less
than is
commonly imagined, for the two following reasons.
First,
All those manufactures of which any part is commonly
exported
to other European countries without a bounty, could be
very
little affected by the freest importation of foreign goods.
Such
manufactures must be sold as cheap abroad as any other
foreign
goods of the same quality and kind, and consequently must
be sold
cheaper at home. They would still, therefore, keep
possession
of the home market; and though a capricious man of
fashion
might sometimes prefer foreign wares, merely because they
were
foreign, to cheaper and better goods of the same kind that
were
made at home, this folly could, from the nature of things,
extend
to so few, that it could make no sensible impression upon
the
general employment of the people. But a great part of all the
different
branches of our woollen manufacture, of our tanned
leather,
and of our hardware, are annually exported to other
European
countries without any bounty, and these are the
manufactures
which employ the greatest number of hands. The silk,
perhaps,
is the manufacture which would suffer the most by this
freedom
of trade, and after it the linen, though the latter much
less
than the former.
Secondly,
Though a great number of people should, by thus
restoring
the freedom of trade, be thrown all at once out of
their
ordinary employment and common method of subsistence, it
would
by no means follow that they would thereby be deprived
either
of employment or subsistence. By the reduction of the army
and
navy at the end of the late war, more than 100,000 soldiers
and
seamen, a number equal to what is employed in the greatest
manufactures,
were all at once thrown out of their ordinary
employment
: but though they no doubt suffered some
inconveniency,
they were not thereby deprived of all employment
and
subsistence. The greater part of the seamen, it is probable,
gradually
betook themselves to the merchant service as they could
find
occasion, and in the mean time both they and the soldiers
were
absorbed in the great mass of the people, and employed in a
great
variety of occupations. Not only no great convulsion, but
no
sensible disorder, arose from so great a change in the
situation
of more than 100,000 men, all accustomed to the use of
arms,
and many of them to rapine and plunder. The number of
vagrants
was scarce anywhere sensibly increased by it ; even the
wages
of labour were not reduced by it in any occupation, so far
as I
have been able to learn, except in that of seamen in the
merchant
service. But if we compare together the habits of a
soldier
and of any sort of manufacturer, we shall find that those
of the
latter do not tend so much to disqualify him from being
employed
in a new trade, as those of the former from being
employed
in any. The manufacturer has always been accustomed to
look
for his subsistence from his labour only ; the soldier to
expect
it from his pay. Application and industry have been
familiar
to the one; idleness and dissipation to the other. But
it is
surely much easier to change the direction of industry from
one
sort of labour to another, than to turn idleness and
dissipation
to any. To the greater part of manufactures, besides,
it has
already been observed, there are other collateral
manufactures
of so similar a nature, that a workman can easily
transfer
his industry from one of them to another. The greater
part of
such workmen, too, are occasionally employed in country
labour.
The stock which employed them in a particular manufacture
before,
will still remain in the country, to employ an equal
number
of people in some other way. The capital of the country
remaining
the same, the demand for labour will likewise be the
same,
or very nearly the same, though it may be exerted in
different
places, and for different occupations. Soldiers and
seamen,
indeed, when discharged from the king's service, are at
liberty
to exercise any trade within any town or place of Great
Britain
or Ireland. Let the same natural liberty of exercising
what
species of industry they please, be restored to all his
Majesty's
subjects, in the same manner as to soldiers and seamen
; that
is, break down the exclusive privileges of corporations,
and
repeal the statute of apprenticeship, both which are really
encroachments
upon natural Liberty, and add to those the repeal
of the
law of settlements, so that a poor workman, when thrown
out of
employment, either in one trade or in one place, may seek
for it
in another trade or in another place, without the fear
either
of a prosecution or of a removal; and neither the public
nor the
individuals will suffer much more from the occasional
disbanding
some particular classes of manufacturers, than from
that of
the soldiers. Our manufacturers have no doubt great merit
with
their country, but they cannot have more than those who
defend
it with their blood, nor deserve to be treated with more
delicacy.
To
expect, indeed, that the freedom of trade should ever be
entirely
restored in Great Britain, is as absurd as to expect
that an
Oceana or Utopia should ever be established in it. Not
only
the prejudices of the public, but, what is much more
unconquerable,
the private interests of many individuals,
irresistibly
oppose it. Were the officers of the army to oppose,
with
the same zeal and unanimity, any reduction in the number of
forces,
with which master manufacturers set themselves against
every
law that is likely to increase the number of their rivals
in the
home market ; were the former to animate their soldiers.
In the
same manner as the latter inflame their workmen, to attack
with
violence and outrage the proposers of any such regulation;
to
attempt to reduce the army would be as dangerous as it has now
become
to attempt to diminish, in any respect, the monopoly which
our
manufacturers have obtained against us. This monopoly has so
much
increased the number of some particular tribes of them,
that,
like an overgrown standing army, they have become
formidable
to the government, and, upon many occasions,
intimidate
the legislature. The member of parliament who supports
every
proposal for strengthening this monopoly, is sure to
acquire
not only the reputation of understanding trade, but great
popularity
and influence with an order of men whose numbers and
wealth
render them of great importance. If he opposes them, on
the
contrary, and still more, if he has authority enough to be
able to
thwart them, neither the most acknowledged probity, nor
the
highest rank, nor the greatest public services, can protect
him
from the most infamous abuse and detraction, from personal
insults,
nor sometimes from real danger, arising from the
insolent
outrage of furious and disappointed monopolists.
The
undertaker of a great manufacture, who, by the home markets
being
suddenly laid open to the competition of foreigners, should
be
obliged to abandon his trade, would no doubt suffer very
considerably.
That part of his capital which had usually been
employed
in purchasing materials, and in paying his workmen,
might,
without much difficulty, perhaps, find another employment
; but
that part of it which was fixed in workhouses, and in the
instruments
of trade, could scarce be disposed of without
considerable
loss. The equitable regard, therefore, to his
interest,
requires that changes of this kind should never be
introduced
suddenly, but slowly, gradually, and after a very long
warning.
The legislature, were it possible that its deliberations
could
be always directed, not by the clamorous importunity of
partial
interests, but by an extensive view of the general good,
ought,
upon this very account, perhaps, to be particularly
careful,
neither to establish any new monopolies of this kind,
nor to
extend further those which are already established. Every
such
regulation introduces some degree of real disorder into the
constitution
of the state, which it will be difficult afterwards
to cure
without occasioning another disorder.
How far
it may be proper to impose taxes upon the importation of
foreign
goods, in order not to prevent their importation, but to
raise a
revenue for government, I shall consider hereafter when I
come to
treat of taxes. Taxes imposed with a view to prevent, or
even to
diminish importation, are evidently as destructive of the
revenue
of the customs as of the freedom of trade.
CHAPTER III.
OF THE
EXTRAORDINARY RESTRAINTS UPON THE IMPORTATION OF GOODS OF
ALMOST
ALL KINDS, FROM THOSE COUNTRIES WITH WHICH THE BALANCE IS
SUPPOSED
TO BE DISADVANTAGEOUS.
Part I
- Of the Unreasonableness of those Restraints, even upon
the
Principles of the Commercial System.
To lay
extraordinary restraints upon the importation of goods of
almost
all kinds, from those particular countries with which the
balance
of trade is supposed to be disadvantageous, is the second
expedient
by which the commercial system proposes to increase the
quantity
of gold and silver. Thus, in Great Britain, Silesia
lawns
may be imported for home consumption, upon paying certain
duties;
but French cambrics and lawns are prohibited to be
imported,
except into the port of London, there to be warehoused
for
exportation. Higher duties are imposed upon the wines of
France
than upon those of Portugal, or indeed of any other
country.
By what is called the impost 1692, a duty of five
and-twenty
per cent. of the rate or value, was laid upon all
French
goods; while the goods of other nations were, the greater
part of
them, subjected to much lighter duties, seldom exceeding
five
per cent. The wine, brandy, salt, and vinegar of France,
were
indeed excepted; these commodities being subjected to other
heavy
duties, either by other laws, or by particular clauses of
the
same law. In 1696, a second duty of twenty-five per cent. the
first
not having been thought a sufficient discouragement, was
imposed
upon all French goods, except brandy ; together with a
new
duty of five-and-twenty pounds upon the ton of French wine,
and
another of fifteen pounds upon the ton of French vinegar.
French
goods have never been omitted in any of those general
subsidies
or duties of five per cent. which have been imposed
upon
all, or the greater part, of the goods enumerated in the
book of
rates. If we count the one-third and two-third subsidies
as
making a complete subsidy between them, there have been five
of
these general subsidies; so that, before the commencement of
the
present war, seventy-five per cent. may be considered as the
lowest
duty to which the greater part of the goods of the growth,
produce,
or manufacture of France, were liable. But upon the
greater
part of goods, those duties are equivalent to a
prohibition.
The French, in their turn, have, I believe, treated
our
goods and manufactures just as hardly; though I am not so
well
acquainted with the particular hardships which they have
imposed
upon them. Those mutual restraints have put an end to
almost
all fair commerce between the two nations; and smugglers
are now
the principal importers, either of British goods into
France,
or of French goods into Great Britain. The principles
which I
have been examining, in the foregoing chapter, took their
origin
from private interest and the spirit of monopoly ; those
which I
am going te examine in this, from national prejudice and
animosity.
They are, accordingly, as might well be expected,
still
more unreasonable. They are so, even upon the principles of
the
commercial system.
First,
Though it were certain that in the case of a free trade
between
France and England, for example, the balance would be in
favour
of France, it would by no means follow that such a trade
would
be disadvantageous to England, or that the general balance
of its
whole trade would thereby be turned more against it. If
the
wines of France are better and cheaper than those of
Portugal,
or its linens than those of Germany, it would be more
advantageous
for Great Britain to purchase both the wine and the
foreign
linen which it had occasion for of France, than of
Portugal
and Germany. Though the value of the annual importations
from
France would thereby be greatly augmented, the value of the
whole
annual importations would be diminished, in proportion as
the
French goods of the same quality were cheaper than those of
the
other two countries. This would be the case, even upon the
supposition
that the whole French goods imported were to be
consumed
in Great Britain.
But,
Secondly, A great part of them might be re-exported to other
countries,
where, being sold with profit, they might bring back a
return.
equal in value, perhaps, to the prime cost of the whole
French
goods imported. What has frequently been said of the East
India
trade, might possibly be true of the French; that though
the
greater part of East India goods were bought with gold and
silver,
the re-exportation of a part of them to other countries
brought
back more gold and silver to that which carried on the
trade,
than the prime cost of the whole amounted to. One of the
most
important branches of the Dutch trade at present, consists
in the
carriage of French goods to other European countries. Some
part
even of the French wine drank in Great Britain, is
clandestinely
imported from Holland and Zealand. If there was
either
a free trade between France and England, or if French
goods
could be imported upon paying only the same duties as those
of
other European nations, to be drawn back upon exportation,
England
might have some share of a trade which is found so
advantageous
to Holland.
Thirdly,
and lastly, There is no certain criterion by which we
can
determine on which side what is called the balance between
any two
countries lies, or which of them exports to the greatest
value.
National prejudice and animosity, prompted always by the
private
interest of particular traders, are the principles which
generally
direct our judgment upon all questions concerning it.
There
are two criterions, however, which have frequently been
appealed
to upon such occasions, the custom-house books and the
course
of exchange. The custom-house books, I think, it is now
generally
acknowledged, are a very uncertain criterion, on
account
of the inaccuracy of the valuation at which the greater
part of
goods are rated in them. The course of exchange is,
perhaps,
almost equally so.
When
the exchange between two places, such as London and Paris,
is at
par, it is said to be a sign that the debts due from London
to
Paris are compensated by those due from Paris to London. On
the
contrary, when a premium is paid at London for a bill upon
Paris,
it is said to be a sign that the debts due from London to
Paris
are not compensated by those due from Paris to London, but
that a
balance in money must be sent out from the latter place;
for the
risk, trouble, and expense, of exporting which, the
premium
is both demanded and given. But the ordinary state of
debt
and credit between those two cities must necessarily be
regulated,
it is said, by the ordinary course of their dealings
with
one another. When neither of them imports from from other to
a
greater amount than it exports to that other, the debts and
credits
of each may compensate one another. But when one of them
imports
from the other to a greater value than it exports to that
other,
the former necessarily becomes indebted to the latter in a
greater
sum than the latter becomes indebted to it: the debts and
credits
of each do not compensate one another, and money must be
sent
out from that place of which the debts overbalance the
credits.
The ordinary course of exchange, therefore, being an
indication
of the ordinary state of debt and credit between two
places,
must likewise be an indication of the ordinary course of
their
exports and imports, as these necessarily regulate that
state.
But
though the ordinary course of exchange shall be allowed to be
a
sufficient indication of the ordinary state of debt and credit
between
any two places, it would not from thence follow, that the
balance
of trade was in favour of that place which had the
ordinary
state of debt and credit in its favour. The ordinary
state
of debt and credit between any two places is not always
entirely
regulated by the ordinary course of their dealings with
one
another, but is often influenced by that of the dealings of
either
with many other places. If it is usual, for example, for
the
merchants of England to pay for the goods which they buy of
Hamburg,
Dantzic, Riga, etc. by bills upon Holland, the ordinary
state
of debt and credit between England and Holland will not be
regulated
entirely by the ordinary course of the dealings of
those
two countries with one another, but will be influenced by
that of
the dealings in England with those other places. England
may be
obliged to send out every year money to Holland, though
its
annual exports to that country may exceed very much the
annual
value of its imports from thence, and though what is
called
the balance of trade may be very much in favour of
England.
In the
way, besides, in which the par of exchange has hitherto
been
computed, the ordinary course of exchange can afford no
sufficient
indication that the ordinary state of debt and credit
is in
favour of that country which seems to have, or which is
supposed
to have, the ordinary course of exchange in its favour ;
or, in
other words, the real exchange may be, and in fact often
is, so
very different from the computed one, that, from the
course
of the latter, no certain conclusion can, upon many
occasions,
be drawn concerning that of the former.
When
for a sum or money paid in England, containing, according to
the
standard of the English mint, a certain number of ounces of
pure
silver, you receive a bill for a sum of money to be paid in
France,
containing, according to the standard of the French mint,
an
equal number of ounces of pure silver, exchange is said to be
at par
between England and France. When you pay more, you are
supposed
to give a premium, and exchange is said to be against
England,
and in favour of France. When you pay less, you are
supposed
to get a premium, and exchange is said to be against
France,
and in favour of England.
But,
first, We cannot always judge of the value of the current
money
of different countries by the standard of their respective
mints.
In some it is more, in others it is less worn, clipt, and
otherwise
degenerated from that standard. But the value of the
current
coin of every country, compared with that of any other
country,
is in proportion, not to the quantity of pure silver
which
it ought to contain, but to that which it actually does
contain.
Before the reformation of the silver coin in King
William's
time, exchange between England and Holland, computed in
the
usual manner, according to the standard of their respective
mints,
was five-and twenty per cent. against England. But the
value
of the current coin of England, as we learn from Mr
Lowndes,
was at that time rather more than five-and-twenty per
cent.
below its standard value. The real exchange, therefore, may
even at
that time have been in favour of England, notwithstanding
the
computed exchange was so much against it ; a smaller number
or
ounces of pure silver, actually paid in England, may have
purchased
a bill for a greater number of ounces of pure silver to
be paid
in Holland, and the man who was supposed to give, may in
reality
have got the premium. The French coin was, before the
late
reformation of the English gold coin, much less wore than
the
English, and was perhaps two or three per cent. nearer its
standard.
If the computed exchange with France, therefore, was
not
more than two or three per cent. against England, the real
exchange
might have been in its favour. Since the reformation of
the
gold coin, the exchange has been constantly in favour of
England,
and against France.
Secondly,
In some countries the expense of coinage is defrayed by
the
government; in others, it is defrayed by the private people,
who
carry their bullion to the mint, and the government even
derives
some revenue from the coinage. In England it is defrayed
by the
government; and if you carry a pound weight of standard
silver
to the mint, you get back sixty-two shillings, containing
a pound
weight of the like standard silver. In France a duty of
eight
per cent. is deducted for the coinage, which not only
defrays
the expense of it, but affords a small revenue to the
government.
In England, as the coinage costs nothing, the current
coin
can never be much more valuable than the quantity of bullion
which
it actually contains. In France, the workmanship, as you
pay for
it, adds to the value, in the same manner as to that of
wrought
plate. A sum of French money, therefore, containing an
equal
weight of pure silver, is more valuable than a sum of
English
money containing an equal weight of pure silver, and must
require
more bullion, or other commodities, to purchase it.
Though
the current coin of the two countries, therefore, were
equally
near the standards of their respective mints, a sum of
English
money could not well purchase a sum of French money
containing
an equal number of ounces of pure silver, nor,
consequently,
a bill upon France for such a sum. If, for such a
bill,
no more additional money was paid than what was sufficient
to
compensate the expense of the French coinage, the real
exchange
might be at par between the two countries; their debts
and
credits might mutually compensate one another, while the
computed
exchange was considerably in favour of France. If less
than
this was paid, the real exchange might be in favour of
England,
while the computed was in favour of France.
Thirdly,
and lastly, In some places, as at Amsterdam, Hamburg,
Venice,
etc. foreign bills of exchange are paid in what they call
bank
money ; while in others, as at London, Lisbon, Antwerp,
Leghorn,
etc. they are paid in the common currency of the
country.
What is called bank money, is always of more value than
the
same nominal sum of common currency. A thousand guilders in
the
bank of Amsterdam, for example, are of more vallue than a
thousand
guilders of Amsterdam currency. The difference between
them is
called the agio of the bank, which at Amsterdam is
generally
about five per cent. Supposing the current money of the
two
countries equally near to the standard of their respective
mints,
and that the one pays foreign bills in this common
currency,
while the other pays them in bank money, it is evident
that
the computed exchange may be in favour of that which pays in
bank
money, though the real exchange should be in favour of that
which
pays in current money; for the same reason that the
computed
exchange may be in favour of that which pays in better
money,
or in money nearer to its own standard, though the real
exchange
should be in favour of that which pays in worse. The
computed
exchange, before the late reformation of the gold coin,
was
generally against London with Amsterdam, Hamburg, Venice,
and, I
believe, with all other places which pay in what is called
bank
money. It will by no means follow, however, that the real
exchange
was against it. Since the reformation of the gold coin,
it has
been in favour of London, even with those places. The
computed
exchange has generally been in favour of London with
Lisbon,
Antwerp, Leghorn, and, if you except France, I believe
with
most other parts of Europe that pay in common currency ; and
it is
not improbable that the real exchange was so too.
Digression
concerning Banks of Deposit, particularly concerning
that of
Amsterdam.
The
currency of a great state, such as France or England,
generally
consists almost entirely of its own coin. Should this
currency,
therefore, be at any time worn, clipt, or otherwise
degraded
below its standard value, the state, by a reformation of
its
coin, can effectually re-establish its currency. But the
currency
of a small state, such as Genoa or Hamburg, can seldom
consist
altogether in its own coin, but must be made up, in a
great
measure, of the coins of all the neighbouring states with
which
its inhabitants have a continual intercourse. Such a state,
therefore,
by reforming its coin, will not always be able to
reform
its currency. If foreign bills of exchange are paid in
this
currency, the uncertain value of any sum, of what is in its
own
nature so uncertain, must render the exchange always very
much
against such a state, its currency being in all foreign
states
necessarily valued even below what it is worth.
In
order to remedy the inconvenience to which this
disadvantageous
exchange must have subjected their merchants,
such
small states, when they began to attend to the interest of
trade,
have frequently enacted that foreign bills of exchange of
a
certain value should be paid, not in common currency, but by an
order
upon, or by a transfer in the books of a certain bank,
established
upon the credit, and under the protection of the
state,
this bank being always obliged to pay, in good and true
money,
exactly according to the standard of the state. The banks
of
Venice, Genoa, Amsterdam, Hamburg, and Nuremberg, seem to have
been
all originally established with this view, though some of
them
may have afterwards been made subservient to other purposes.
The
money of such banks, being better than the common currency of
the
country, necessarily bore an agio, which was greater or
smaller,
according as the currency was supposed to be more or
less
degraded below the standard of the state. The agio of the
bank of
Hamburg, for example, which is said to be commonly about
fourteen
per cent. is the supposed difference between the good
standard
money of the state, and the clipt, worn, and diminished
currency,
poured into it from all the neighbouring states.
Before
1609, the great quantity of clipt and worn foreign coin
which
the extensive trade of Amsterdam brought from all parts of
Europe,
reduced the value of its currency about nine per cent.
below
that of good money fresh from the mint. Such money no
sooner
appeared, than it was melted down or carried away, as it
always
is in such circumstances. The merchants, with plenty of
currency,
could not always find a sufficient quantity of good
money
to pay their bills of exchange ; and the value of those
bills,
in spite of several regulations which were made to prevent
it,
became in a great measure uncertain.
In
order to remedy these inconveniencies, a bank was established
in
1609, under the guarantee of the city. This bank received both
foreign
coin, and the light and worn coin of the country, at its
real
intrinsic value in the good standard money of the country,
deducting
only so much as was neccssary for defraying the expense
of
coinage and the other necessary expense of management. For the
value
which remained after this small deduction was made, it gave
a
credit in its books. This credit was called bank money, which,
as it
represented money exactly according to the standard of the
mint,
was always of the same real value, and intrinsically worth
more
than current money. It was at the same time enacted, that
all
bills drawn upon or negotiated at Amsterdam, of the value of
600
guilders and upwards, should be paid in bank money, which at
once
took away all uncertainty in the value of those bills. Every
merchant,
in consequence of this regulation, was obliged to keep
an
account with the bank, in order to pay his foreign bills of
exchange,
which necessarily occasioned a certain demand for bank
money.
Bank money, over and above both its in
trinsic superiority to
currency,
and the additional value which this demand necessarily
gives
it, has likewise some other advantages, It is secure from
fire,
robbery, and other accidents; the city of Amsterdam is
bound
for it; it can be paid away by a simple transfer, without
the
trouble of counting, or the risk of transporting it from one
place
to another. In consequence of those different advantages,
it
seems from the beginning to have borne an agio; and it is
generally
believed that all the money originally deposited in the
bank,
was allowed to remain there, nobody caring to demand
payment
of a debt which he could sell for a premium in the
market.
By demanding payment of the bank, the owner of a bank
credit
would lose this premium. As a shilling fresh from the mint
will
buy no more goods in the market than one of our common worn
shillings,
so the good and true money which might be brought from
the
coffers of the bank into those of a private person, being
mixed
and confounded with the common currency of the country,
would
be of no more value than that currency, from which it could
no
longer be readily distinguished. While it remained in the
coffers
of the bank, its superiority was known and ascertained.
When it
had come into those of a private person, its superiority
could
not well be ascertained without more trouble than perhaps
the
difference was worth. By being brought from the coffers of
the
bank, besides, it lost all the other advantages of bank
money;
its security, its easy and safe transferability, its use
in
paying foreign bills of exchange. Over and above all this, it
could
not be brought from those coffers, as will appear by and
by,
without previously paying for the keeping.
Those
deposits of coin, or those deposits which the bank was
bound
to restore in coin, constituted the original capital of the
bank,
or the whole value of what was represented by what is
called
bank money. At present they are supposed to constitute but
a very
small part of it. In order to facilitate the trade in
bullion,
the bank has been for these many years in the practice
of
giving credit in its books, upon deposits of gold and silver
bullion.
This credit is generally about five per cent. below the
mint
price of such bullion. The bank grants at the same time what
is
called a recipice or receipt, entitling the person who makes
the
deposit, or the bearer, to take out the bullion again at any
time
within six months, upon transferring to the bank a quantity
of bank
money equal to that for which credit had been given in
its
books when the deposit was made, and upon paying one-fourth
per
cent. for the keeping, if the deposit was in silver ; and
one-half
per cent. if it was in gold; but at the same time
declaring,
that in default of such payment, and upon the
expiration
of this term, the deposit should belong to the bank,
at the
price at which it had been received, or for which credit
had been
given in the transfer books. What is thus paid for the
keeping
of the deposit may be considered as a sort of warehouse
rent;
and why this warehouse rent should be so much dearer for
gold
than for silver, several different reasons have been
assigned.
The fineness of gold, it has been said, is more
difficult
to be ascertained than that of silver. Frauds are more
easily
practised, and occasion a greater loss in the most
precious
metal. Silver, besides, being the standard metal, the
state,
it has been said, wishes to encourage more the making of
deposits
of silver than those of gold.
Deposits
of bullion are most commonly made when the price is
somewhat
lower than ordinary, and they are taken out again when
it
happens to rise. In Holland the market price of bullion is
generally
above the mint price, for the same reason that it was
so in
England before the late reformation of the gold coin. The
difference
is said to be commonly from about six to sixteen
stivers
upon the mark, or eight ounces of silver, of eleven parts
of fine
and one part alloy. The bank price, or the credit which
the
bank gives for the deposits of such silver (when made in
foreign
coin, of which the fineness is well known and
ascertained,
such as Mexico dollars), is twenty-two guilders the
mark :
the mint price is about twenty-three guilders, and the
market
price is from twenty-three guilders six, to twenty-three
guilders
sixteen stivers, or from two to three per cent. above
the
mint price.
The following are the prices at which the
bank of Amsterdam at
present
{September 1775} receives bullion and coin of different
kinds:
SILVER
Mexico dollars ................. 22 Guilders / mark
French crowns .................. 22
English silver coin .............
22
Mexico dollars, new coin ........ 21
10
Ducatoons ....................... 3
0
Rix-dollars ..................... 2
8
Bar
silver, containing 11-12ths fine silver, 21 Guilders / mark,
and in
this proportion down to 1-4th fine, on which 5 guilders
are
given. Fine bars, ................. 28
Guilders / mark.
GOLD
Portugal coin ................. 310
Guilders / mark
Guineas ....................... 310
Louis d'ors, new .............. 310
Ditto old ..............
300
New ducats .................... 4
19 8 per ducat
Bar or
ingot gold is received in proportion to its fineness,
compared
with the above foreign gold coin. Upon fine bars the
bank
gives 340 per mark. In general, however, something more is
given
upon coin of a known fineness, than upon gold and silver
bars,
of which the fineness cannot be ascertained but by a
process
of melting and assaying.
The
proportions between the bank price, the mint price, and the
market
price of gold bullion, are nearly the same. A person can
generally
sell his receipt for the difference between the mint
price
of bullion and the market price. A receipt for bullion is
almost
always worth something, and it very seldom happens,
therefore,
that anybody suffers his receipts to expire, or allows
his
bullion to fall to the bank at the price at which it had been
received,
either by not taking it out before the end of the six
months,
or by neglecting to pay one fourth or one half per cent.
in
order to obtain a new receipt for another six months. This,
however,
though it happens seldom, is said to happen sometimes,
and
more frequently with regard to gold than with regard to
silver,
on account of the higher warehouse rent which is paid for
the
keeping of the more precious metal.
The
person who, by making a deposit of bullion, obtains both a
bank
credit and a receipt, pays his bills of exchange as they
become
due, with his bank credit; and either sells or keeps his
receipt,
according as he judges that the price of bullion is
likely
to rise or to fall. The receipt and the bank credit seldom
keep
long together, and there is no occasion that they should.
The
person who has a receipt, and who wants to take out bullion,
finds
always plenty of bank credits, or bank money, to buy at the
ordinary
price, and the person who has bank money, and wants to
take
out bullion, finds receipts always in equal abundance.
The
owners of bank credits, and the holders of receipts,
constitute
two different sorts of creditors against the bank. The
holder
of a receipt cannot draw out the bullion for which it is
granted,
without re-assigning to the bank a sum of bank money
equal
to the price at which the bullion had been received. If he
has no
bank money of his own, he must purchase it of those who
have
it. The owner of bank money cannot draw out bullion, without
producing
to the bank receipts for the quantity which he wants.
If he has
none of his own, he must buy them of those who have
them.
The holder of a receipt, when he purchases bank money,
purchases
the power of taking out a quantity of bullion, of which
the
mint price is five per cent. above the bank price. The agio
of five
per cent. therefore, which he commonly pays for it, is
paid,
not for an imaginary, but for a real value. The owner of
bank
money, when he purchases a receipt, purchases the power of
taking
out a quantity of bullion, of which the market price is
commonly
from two to three per cent. above the mint price. The
price
which he pays for it, therefore, is paid likewise for a
real
value. The price of the receipt, and the price of the bank
money,
compound or make up between them the full value or price
of the
bullion.
Upon
deposits of the coin current in the country, the bank grant
receipts
likewise, as well as bank credits; but those receipts
are
frequently of no value and will bring no price in the market.
Upon
ducatoons, for example, which in the currency pass for three
guilders
three stivers each, the bank gives a credit of three
guilders
only, or five per cent. below their current value. It
grants
a receipt likewise, entitling the bearer to take out the
number
of ducatoons deposited at any time within six months, upon
paying
one fourth per cent. for the keeping. This receipt will
frequently
bring no price in the market. Three guilders, bank
money,
generally sell in the market for three guilders three
stivers,
the full value of the ducatoons, if they were taken out
of the
bank ; and before they can be taken out, one-fourth per
cent.
must be paid for the keeping, which would be mere loss to
the
holder of the receipt. If the agio of the bank, however,
should
at any time fall to three per cent. such receipts might
bring
some price in the market, and might sell for one and
three-fourths
per cent. But the agio of the bank being now
generally
about five per cent. such receipts are frequently
allowed
to expire, or, as they express it, to fall to the bank.
The
receipts which are given for deposits of gold ducats fall to
it yet
more frequently, because a higher warehouse rent, or one
half
per cent. must be paid for the keeping of them, before they
can be
taken out again. The five per cent. which the bank gains,
when
deposits either of coin or bullion are allowed to fall to
it,
maybe considered as the warehouse rent for the perpetual
keeping
of such deposits.
The sum
of bank money, for which the receipts are expired, must
be very
considerable. It must comprehend the whole original
capital
of the bank, which, it is generally supposed, has been
allowed
to remain there from the time it was first deposited,
nobody
caring either to renew his receipt, or to take out his
deposit,
as, for the reasons already assigned, neither the one
nor the
other could be done without loss. But whatever may be the
amount
of this sum, the proportion which it bears to the whole
mass of
bank money is supposed to be very small. The bank of
Amsterdam
has, for these many years past, been the great
warehouse
of Europe for bullion, for which the receipts are very
seldom
allowed to expire, or, as they express it, to fall to the
bank.
The far greater part of the bank money, or of the credits
upon
the books of the bank, is supposed to have been created, for
these
many years past, by such deposits, which the dealers in
bullion
are continually both making and withdrawing.
No
demand can be made upon the bank, but by means of a recipice
or
receipt. The smaller mass of bank money, for which the
receipts
are expired, is mixed and confounded with the much
greater
mass for which they are still in force; so that, though
there
may be a considerable sum of bank money, for which there
are no
receipts, there is no specific sum or portion of it which
may not
at any time be demanded by one. The bank cannot be debtor
to two
persons for the same thing; and the owner of bank money
who has
no receipt, cannot demand payment of the bank till he
buys
one. In ordinary and quiet times, he can find no difficulty
in
getting one to buy at the market price, which generally
corresponds
with the price at which he can sell the coin or
bullion
it entitles him to take out of the bank.
It
might be otherwise during a public calamity ; an invasion, for
example,
such as that of the French in 1672. The owners of bank
money
being then all eager to draw it out of the bank, in order
to have
it in their own keeping, the demand for receipts might
raise
their price to an exorbitant height. The holders of them
might
form extravagant expectations, and, instead of two or three
per
cent. demand half the bank money for which credit had been
given
upon the deposits that the receipts had respectively been
granted
for. The enemy, informed of the constitution of the bank,
might
even buy them up, in order to prevent the carrying away of
the
treasure. In such emergencies, the bank, it is supposed,
would
break through its ordinary rule of making payment only to
the
holders of receipts. The holders of receipts, who had no bank
money,
must have received within two or three per cent. of the
value
of the deposit for which their respective receipts had been
granted.
The bank, therefore, it is said, would in this case make
no
scruple of paying, either with money or bullion, the full
value
of what the owners of bank money, who could get no
receipts,
were credited for in its books; paying, at the same
time,
two or three per cent. to such holders of receipts as had
no bank
money, that being the whole value which, in this state of
things,
could justly be supposed due to them.
Even in
ordinary and quiet times, it is the interest of the
holders
of receipts to depress the agio, in order either to buy
bank
money (and consequently the bullion which their receipts
would
then enable them to take out of the bank ) so much cheaper,
or to
sell their receipts to those who have bank money, and who
want to
take out bullion, so much dearer ; the price of a receipt
being
generally equal to the difference between the market price
of bank
money and that of the coin or bullion for which the
receipt
had been granted. It is the interest of the owners of
bank
money, on the contrary, to raise the agio, in order either
to sell
their bank money so much dearer, or to buy a receipt so
much
cheaper. To prevent the stock-jobbing tricks which those
opposite
interests might sometimes occasion, the bank has of late
years
come to the resolution, to sell at all times bank money for
currency
at five per cent. agio, and to buy it in again at four
per
cent. agio. In consequence of this resolution, the agio can
never
either rise above five, or sink below four per cent. ; and
the
proportion between the market price of bank and that of
current
money is kept at all times very near the proportion
between
their intrinsic values. Before this resolution was taken,
the
market price of bank money used sometimes to rise so high as
nine
per cent. agio, and sometimes to sink so low as par,
according
as opposite interests happened to influence the market.
The
bank of Amsterdam professes to lend out no part of what is
deposited
with it, but for every guilder for which it gives
credit
in its books, to keep in its repositories the value of a
guilder
either in money or bullion. That it keeps in its
repositories
all the money or bullion for which there are
receipts
in force for which it is at all times liable to be
called
upon, and which in reality is continually going from it,
and
returning to it again, cannot well be doubted. But whether it
does so
likewise with regard to that part of its capital for
which
the receipts are long ago expired, for which, in ordinary
and
quiet times, it cannot be called upon, and which, in reality,
is very
likely to remain with it for ever, or as long as the
states
of the United Provinces subsist, may perhaps appear more
uncertain.
At Amsterdam, however, no point of faith is better
established
than that, for every guilder circulated as bank
money,
there is a correspondent guilder in gold or silver to be
found
in the treasures of the bank. The city is guarantee that it
should
be so. The bank is under the direction of the four
reigning
burgomasters who are changed every year. Each new set of
burgomasters
visits the treasure, compares it with the books,
receives
it upon oath, and delivers it over, with the same awful
solemnity
to the set which succeeds ; and in that sober and
religious
country, oaths are not yet disregarded. A rotation of
this
kind seems alone a sufficient security against any practices
which
cannot be avowed. Amidst all the revolutions which faction
has
ever occasioned in the government of Amsterdam, the
prevailing
party has at no time accused their predecessors of
infidelity
in the administration of the bank. No accusation could
have
affected more deeply the reputation and fortune of the
disgraced
party ; and if such an accusation could have been
supported,
we may be assured that it would have been brought. In
1672,
when the French king was at Utrecht, the bank of Amsterdam
paid so
readily, as left no doubt of the fidelity with which it
had
observed its engagements. Some of the pieces which were then
brought
from its repositories, appeared to have been scorched
with
the fire which happened in the town-house soon after the
bank
was established. Those pieces, therefore, must have lain
there
from that time.
What
may be the amount of the treasure in the bank, is a question
which
has long employed the speculations of the curious. Nothing
but
conjecture can be offered concerning it. It is generally
reckoned,
that there are about 2000 people who keep accounts with
the
bank; and allowing them to have, one with another, the value
of
£1500 sterling lying upon their respective accounts (a very
large
allowance), the whole quantity of bank money, and
consequently
of treasure in the bank, will amount to about
£3,000,000
sterling, or, at eleven guilders the pound sterling,
33,000,000
of guilders ; a great sum, and sufficient to carry on
a very
extensive circulation, but vastly below the extravagant
ideas
which some people have formed of this treasure.
The
city of Amsterdam derives a considerable revenue from the
bank.
Besides what may be called the warehouse rent above
mentioned,
each person, upon first opening an account with the
bank,
pays a fee of ten guilders ; and for every new account,
three
guilder's three stivers; for every transfer, two stivers;
and if
the transfer is for less than 300 guilders, six stivers,
in
order to discourage the multiplicity of small transactions.
The
person who neglects to balance his account twice in the year,
forfeits
twenty-five guilders. The person who orders a transfer
for
more than is upon his account, is obliged to pay three per
cent.
for the sum overdrawn, and his order is set aside into the
bargain.
The bank is supposed, too, to make a considerable profit
by the
sale of the foreign coin or bullion which sometimes falls
to it
by the expiring of receipts, and which is always kept till
it can
be sold with advantage. It makes a profit, likewise, by
selling
bank money at five per cent. agio, and buying it in at
four.
These different emoluments amount to a good deal more than
what is
necessary for paying the salaries of officers, and
defraying
the expense of management. What is paid for the keeping
of
bullion upon receipts, is alone supposed to amount to a neat
annual
revenue of between 150,000 and 200,000 guilders. Public
utility,
however, and not revenue, was the original object of
this
institution. Its object was to relieve the merchants from
the
inconvenience of a disadvantageous exchange. The revenue
which
has arisen from it was unforeseen, and may be considered as
accidental.
But it is now time to return from this long
digression,
into which I have been insensibly led, in
endeavouring
to explain the reasons why the exchange between the
countries
which pay in what is called bank money, and those which
pay in
common currency, should generally appear to be in favour
of the
former, and against the latter. The former pay in a
species
of money, of which the intrinsic value is always the
same,
and exactly agreeable to the standard of their respective
mints ;
the latter is a species of money, of which the intrinsic
value
is continually varying, and is almost always more or less
below
that standard.
PART II. - Of the Unreasonableness of those
extraordinary
Restraints,
upon other Principles.
In the
foregoing part of this chapter, I have endeavoured to
show,
even upon the principles of the commercial system, how
unnecessary
it is to lay extraordinary restraints upon the
importation
of goods from those countries with which the balance
of
trade is supposed to be disadvantageous.
Nothing,
however, can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of
the
balance of trade, upon which, not only these restraints, but
almost
all the other regulations of commerce, are founded. When
two
places trade with one another, this doctrine supposes that,
if the
balance be even, neither of them either loses or gains;
but if
it leans in any degree to one side, that one of them
loses,
and the other gains, in proportion to its declension from
the
exact equilibrium. Both suppositions
are false. A trade,
which
is forced by means of bounties and monopolies, may be, and
commonly
is, disadvantageous to the country in whose favour it is
meant
to be established, as I shall endeavour to show hereafter.
But
that trade which, without force or constraint, is naturally
and
regularly carried on between any two places, is always
advantageous,
though not always equally so, to both.
By
advantage or gain, I understand, not the increase of the
quantity
of gold and silver, but that of the exchangeable value
of the
annual produce of the land and labour of the country, or
the
increase of the annual revenue of its inhabitants.
If the
balance be even, and if the trade between the two places
consist
altogether in the exchange of their native commodities,
they
will, upon most occasions, not only both gain, but they will
gain
equally, or very nearly equally ; each will, in this case,
afford
a market for a part of the surplus produce of the other;
each
will replace a capital which had been employed in raising
and
preparing for the market this part of the surplus produce of
the
other, and which had been distributed among, and given
revenue
and maintenance to, a certain number of its inhabitants.
Some
part of the inhabitants of each, therefore, will directly
derive
their revenue and maintenance from the other. As the
commodities
exchanged, too, are supposed to be of equal value, so
the two
capitals employed in the trade will, upon most occasions,
be
equal, or very nearly equal ; and both being employed in
raising
the native commodities of the two countries, the revenue
and
maintenance which their distribution will afford to the
inhabitants
of each will be equal, or very nearly equal. This
revenue
and maintenance, thus mutually afforded, will be greater
or
smaller, in proportion to the extent of their dealings. If
these
should annually amount to £100,000, for example, or to
£1,000,000,
on each side, each of them will afford an annual
revenue,
in the one case, of £100,000, and, in the other, of
£1,000,000,
to the inhabitants of the other.
If
their trade should be of such a nature, that one of them
exported
to the other nothing but native commodities, while the
returns
of that other consisted altogether in foreign goods; the
balance,
in this case, would still be supposed even, commodities
being
paid for with commodities. They would, in this case too,
both
gain, but they would not gain equally; and the inhabitants
of the
country which exported nothing but native commodities,
would
derive the greatest revenue from the trade. If England, for
example,
should import from France nothing but the native
commodities
of that country, and not having such commodities of
its own
as were in demand there, should annually repay them by
sending
thither a large quantity of foreign goods, tobacco, we
shall
suppose, and East India goods ; this trade, though it would
give
some revenue to the inhabitants of both countries, would
give
more to those of France than to those of England. The whole
French
capital annually employed in it would annually be
distributed
among the people of France; but that part of the
English
capital only, which was employed in producing the English
commodities
with which those foreign goods were purchased, would
be
annually distributed among the people of England. The greater
part of
it would replace the capitals which had been employed in
Virginia,
Indostan, and China, and which had given revenue and
maintenance
to the inhabitants of those distant countries. If the
capitals
were equal, or nearly equal, therefore, this employment
of the
French capital would augment much more the revenue of the
people
of France, than that of the English capital would the
revenue
of the people of England. France would, in this case,
carry
on a direct foreign trade of consumption with England;
whereas
England would carry on a round-about trade of the same
kind
with France. The different effects of a capital employed in
the
direct, and of one employed in the round-about foreign trade
of
consumption, have already been fully explained.
There
is not, probably, between any two countries, a trade which
consists
altogether in the exchange, either of native commodities
on both
sides, or of native commodities on one side, and of
foreign
goods on the other. Almost all countries exchange with
one
another, partly native and partly foreign goods That country,
however,
in whose cargoes there is the greatest proportion of
native,
and the least of foreign goods, will always be the
principal
gainer.
If it
was not with tobacco and East India
goods, but with gold
and
silver, that England paid for the commodities annually
imported
from France, the balance, in this case, would be
supposed
uneven, commodities not being paid for with commodities,
but
with gold and silver. The trade, however, would in this case,
as in
the foregoing, give some revenue to the inhabitants of both
countries,
but more to those of France than to those of England.
It
would give some revenue to those of England. The capital which
had
been employed in producing the English goods that purchased
this
gold and silver, the capital which had been distributed
among,
and given revenue to, certain inhabitants of England,
would
thereby be replaced, and enabled to continue that
employment.
The whole capital of England would no more be
diminished
by this exportation of gold and silver, than by the
exportation
of an equal value of any other goods. On the
contrary,
it would, in most cases, be augmented. No goods are
sent
abroad but those for which the demand is sup- posed to be
greater
abroad than at home, and of which the returns,
consequently,
it is expected, will be of more value at home than
the
commodities exported. If the tobacco which in England is
worth
only £100,000, when sent to France, will purchase wine
which
is in England worth £110,000, the exchange will augment the
capital
of England by £10,000. If £100,000 of English gold, in
the
same manner, purchase French wine, which in England is worth
£110,000,
this exchange will equally augment the capital of
England
by £10,000. As a merchant, who has £110,000 worth of wine
in his
cellar, is a richer man than he who has only £100,000
worth
of tobacco in his warehouse, so is he likewise a richer man
than he
who has only £100,000 worth of gold in his coffers. He
can put
into motion a greater quantity of industry, and give
revenue,
maintenance, and employment, to a greater number of
people,
than either of the other two. But the capital of the
country
is equal to the capital of all its different inhabitants;
and the
quantity of industry which can be annually maintained in
it is
equal to what all those different capitals can maintain.
Both
the capital of the country, therefore, and the quantity of
industry
which can be annually maintained in it, must generally
be
augmented by this exchange. It would, indeed, be more
advantageous
for England that it could purchase the wines of
France
with its own hardware and broad cloth, than with either
the
tobacco of Virginia, or the gold and silver of Brazil and
Peru. A
direct foreign trade of consumption is always more
advantageous
than a round-about one. But a round-about foreign
trade
of consumption, which is carried on with gold and silver,
does
not seem to be less advantageous than any other equally
round-about
one. Neither is a country which has no mines, more
likely
to be exhausted of gold and silver by this annual
exportation
of those metals, than one which does not grow tobacco
by the
like annual exportation of that plant. As a country which
has
wherewithal to buy tobacco will never be long in want of it,
so
neither will one be long in want of gold and silver which has
wherewithal
to purchase those metals.
It is a
losing trade, it is said, which a workman carries on with
the
alehouse; and the trade which a manufacturing nation would
naturally
carry on with a wine country, may be considered as a
trade
of the same nature. I answer, that the trade with the
alehouse
is not necessarily a losing trade. In its own nature it
is just
as advantageous as any other, though, perhaps, somewhat
more
liable to be abused. The employment of a brewer, and even
that of
a retailer of fermented liquors, are as necessary
division's
of labour as any other. It will generally be more
advantageous
for a workman to buy of the brewer the quantity he
has
occasion for, than to brew it himself ; and if he is a poor
workman,
it will generally be more advantageous for him to buy it
by
little and little of the retailer, than a large quantity of
the
brewer. He may no doubt buy too much of either, as he may of
any
other dealers in his neighbourhood; of the butcher, if he is
a
glutton ; or of the draper, if he affects to be a beau among
his
companions. It is advantageous to the great body of workmen,
notwithstanding,
that all these trades should be free, though
this
freedom may be abused in all of them, and is more likely to
be so,
perhaps, in some than in others. Though individuals,
besides,
may sometimes ruin their fortunes by an excessive
consumption
of fermented liquors, there seems to be no risk that
a
nation should do so. Though in every country there are many
people
who spend upon such liquors more than they can afford,
there
are always many more who spend less. It deserves to be
remarked,
too, that if we consult experience, the cheapness of
wine
seems to be a cause, not of drunkenness, but of sobriety.
The
inhabitants of the wine countries are in general the soberest
people
of Europe; witness the Spaniards, the Italians, and the
inhabitants
of the southern provinces of France. People are
seldom
guilty of excess in what is their daily fare. Nobody
affects
the character of liberality and good fellowship, by being
profuse
of a liquor which is as cheap as small beer. On the
contrary,
in the countries which, either from excessive heat or
cold,
produce no grapes, and where wine consequently is dear and
a
rarity, drunkenness is a common vice, as among the northern
nations,
and all those who live between the tropics, the negroes,
for
example on the coast of Guinea. When a French regiment comes
from
some of the northern provinces of France, where wine is
somewhat
dear, to be quartered in the southern, where it is very
cheap,
the soldiers, I have frequently heard
it observed, are at
first
debauched by the cheapness and novelty of good wine ; but
after a
few months residence, the greater part of them become as
sober
as the rest of the inhabitants. Were the duties upon
foreign
wines, and the excises upon malt, beer, and ale, to be
taken
away all at once, it might, in the same manner, occasion in
Great
Britain a pretty general and temporary drunkenness among
the
middling and inferior ranks of people, which would probably
be soon
followed by a permanent and almost universal sobriety. At
present,
drunkenness is by no means the vice of people of
fashion,
or of those who can easily afford the most expensive
liquors.
A gentleman drunk with ale has scarce ever been seen
among
us. The restraints upon the wine trade in Great Britain,
besides,
do not so much seem calculated to hinder the people from
going,
if I may say so, to the alehouse, as from going where they
can buy
the best and cheapest liquor. They favour the wine trade
of
Portugal, and discourage that of France. The Portuguese, it is
said,
indeed, are better customers for our manufactures than the
French,
and should therefore be encouraged in preference to them.
As they
give us their custom, it is pretended we should give them
ours.
The sneaking arts of underling tradesmen are thus erected
into
political maxims for the conduct of a great empire ; for it
is the
most underling tradesmen only who make it a rule to employ
chiefly
their own customers. A great trader purchases his goods
always
where they are cheapest and best, without regard to any
little
interest of this kind.
By such
maxims as these, however, nations have been taught that
their
interest consisted in beggaring all their neighbours. Each
nation
has been made to look with an invidious eye upon the
prosperity
of all the nations with which it trades, and to
consider
their gain as its own loss. Commerce, which ought
naturally
to be, among nations as among individuals, a bond of
union
and friendship, has become the most fertile source of
discord
and animosity. The capricious ambition of kings and
ministers
has not, during the present and the preceding century,
been
more fatal to the repose of Europe, than the impertinent
jealousy
of merchants and manufacturers. The violence and
injustice
of the rulers of mankind is an ancient evil, for which,
I am
afraid, the nature of human affairs can scarce admit of a
remedy
: but the mean rapacity, the monopolizing spirit, of
merchants
and manufacturers, who neither are, nor ought to be,
the
rulers of mankind, though it cannot, perhaps, be corrected,
may
very easily be prevented from disturbing the tranquillity of
anybody
but themselves.
That it
was the spirit of monopoly which originally both invented
and
propagated this doctrine, cannot be doubted and they who
first
taught it, were by no means such fools as they who believed
it. In
every country it always is, and must be, the interest of
the
great body of the people, to buy whatever they want of those
who
sell it cheapest. The proposition is so very manifest, that
it
seems ridiculous to take any pains to prove it ; nor could it
ever
have been called in question, had not the interested
sophistry
of merchants and manufacturers confounded the common
sense
of mankind. Their interest is, in this respect, directly
opposite
to that of the great body of the people. As it is the
interest
of the freemen of a corporation to hinder the rest of
the
inhabitants from employing any workmen but themselves; so it
is the
interest of the merchants and manufacturers of every
country
to secure to themselves the monopoly of the home market.
Hence,
in Great Britain, and in most other European countries,
the
extraordinary duties upon almost all goods imported by alien
merchants.
Hence the high duties and prohibitions upon all those
foreign
manufactures which can come into competition with our
own.
Hence, too, the extraordinary restraints upon the
importation
of almost all sorts of goods from those countries
with
which the balance of trade is supposed to be
disadvantageous;
that is, from those against whom national
animosity
happens ta be most violently inflamed.
The
wealth of neighbouring nations, however, though dangerous in
war and
politics, is certainly advantageous in trade. In a state
of
hostility, it may enable our enemies to maintain fleets and
armies
superior to our own; but in a state of peace and commerce
it must
likewise enable them to exchange with us to a greater
value,
and to afford a better market, either for the immediate
produce
of our own industry, or for whatever is purchased with
that
produce. As a rich man is likely to be a better customer to
the
industrious people in his neighbourhood, than a poor, so is
likewise
a rich nation. A rich man, indeed, who is himself a
manufacturer,
is a very dangerous neighbour to all those who deal
in the
same way. All the rest of the neighbourhood, however, by
far the
greatest number, profit by the good market which his
expense
affords them. They even profit by his underselling the
poorer
workmen who deal in the same way with him. The
manufacturers
of a rich nation, in the same manner, may no doubt
be very
dangerous rivals to those of their neighbours. This very
competition,
however, is advantageous to the great body of the
people,
who profit greatly, besides, by the good market which the
great
expense of such a nation affords them in every other way.
Private
people, who want to make a fortune, never think of
retiring
to the remote and poor provinces of the country, but
resort
either to the capital, or to some of the great commercial
towns.
They know, that where little wealth circulates, there is
little
to be got; but that where a great deal is in motion, some
share
of it may fall to them. The same maxim which would in this
manner
direct the common sense of one, or ten, or twenty
individuals,
should regulate the judgment of one, or ten, or
twenty
millions, and should make a whole nation regard the riches
of its
neighbours, as a probable cause and occasion for itself to
acquire
riches. A nation that would enrich itself by foreign
trade,
is certainly most likely to do so, when its neighbours are
all
rich, industrious and commercial nations. A great nation,
surrounded
on all sides by wandering savages and poor barbarians,
might,
no doubt, acquire riches by the cultivation of its own
lands,
and by its own interior commerce, but not by foreign
trade.
It seems to have been in this manner that the ancient
Egyptians
and the modern Chinese acquired their great wealth. The
ancient
Egyptians, it is said, neglected foreign commerce, and
the
modem Chinese, it is known, hold it in the utmost contempt,
and
scarce deign to afford it the decent protection of the laws.
The
modern maxims of foreign commerce, by aiming at the
impoverishment
of all our neighbours, so far as they are capable
of
producing their intended effect, tend to render that very
commerce
insignificant and contemptible.
It is
in consequence of these maxims, that the commerce between
France
and England has, in both countries, been subjected to so
many
discouragements and restraints. If those two countries,
however,
were to consider their real interest, without either
mercantile
jealousy or national animosity, the commerce of France
might
be more advantageous to Great Britain than that of any
other
country, and, for the same reason, that of Great Britain to
France.
France is the nearest neighbour to Great Britain. In the
trade
between the southern coast of England and the northern and
north-western
coast of France, the returns might be expected, in
the same
manner as in the inland trade, four, five, or six times
in the
year. The capital, therefore, employed in this trade
could,
in each of the two countries, keep in motion four, five,
or six
times the quantity of industry, and afford employment and
subsistence
to four, five, or six times the number of people,
which
all equal capital could do in the greater part of the other
branches
of foreign trade. Between the parts of France and Great
Britain
most remote from one another, the returns might be
expected,
at least, once in the year ; and even this trade would
so far
be at least equally advantageous, as the greater part of
the
other branches of our foreign European trade. It would be, at
least,
three times more advantageous than the boasted trade with
our
North American colonies, in which the returns were seldom
made in
less than three years, frequently not in less than four
or five
years. France, besides, is supposed to contain 24,000,000
of
inhabitants. Our North American colonies were never supposed
to
contain more than 3,000,000; and France is a much richer
country
than North America; though, on account of the more
unequal
distribution of riches, there is much more poverty and
beggary
in the one country than in the other. France, therefore,
could
afford a market at least eight times more extensive, and,
on
account of the superior frequency of the returns,
four-and-twenty
times more advantageous than that which our North
American
colonies ever afforded. The trade of Great Britain would
be just
as advantageous to France, and, in proportion to the
wealth,
population, and proximity of the respective countries,
would
have the same superiority over that which France carries on
with
her own colonies. Such is the very great difference between
that
trade which the wisdom of both nations has thought proper to
discourage,
and that which it has favoured the most.
But the
very same circumstances which would have rendered an open
and
free commerce between the two countries so advantageous to
both,
have occasioned the principal obstructions to that
commerce.
Being nighbours, they are necessarily enemies, and the
wealth
and power of each becomes, upon that account, more
formidable
to the other; and what would increase the advantage of
national
friendship, serves only to inflame the violence of
national
animosity. They are both rich and industrious nations;
and the
merchants and manufacturers of each dread the competition
of the
skill and activity of those of the other. Mercantile
jealousy
is excited, and both inflames, and is itself inflamed,
by the
violence of national animosity, and the traders of both
countries
have announced, with all the passionate confidence of
interested
falsehood, the certain ruin of each, in consequence of
that
unfavourable balance of trade, which, they pretend, would be
the
infallible effect of an unrestrained commerce with the other.
There
is no commercial country in Europe, of which the
approaching
ruin has not frequently been foretold by the
pretended
doctors of this system, from all unfavourably balance
of
trade. After all the anxiety,
however, which they have
excited
about this, after all the vain attempts of almost all
trading
nations to turn that balance in their own favour, and
against
their neighbours, it does not appear that any one nation
in
Europe has been, in any respect, impoverished by this cause.
Every
town and country, on the contrary, in proportion as they
have
opened their ports to all nations, instead of being ruined
by this
free trade, as the principles of the commercial system
would
lead us to expect, have been enriched by it. Though there
are in
Europe indeed, a few towns which, in same respects,
deserve
the name of free ports, there is no country which does
so.
Holland, perhaps, approaches the nearest to this character of
any,
though still very remote from it; and Holland, it is
acknowledged,
not only derives its whole wealth, but a great part
of its
necessary subsistence, from foreign trade.
There
is another balance, indeed, which has already been
explained,
very different from the balance of trade, and which,
according
as it happens to be either favourable or unfavourable,
necessarily
occasions the prosperity or decay of every nation.
This is
the balance of the annual produce and consumption. If the
exchangeable
value of the annual produce, it has already been
observed,
exceeds that of the annual consumption, the capital of
the
society must annually increase in proportion to this excess.
The
society in this case lives within its revenue; and what is
annually
saved out of its revenue, is naturally added to its
capital,
and employed so as to increase still further the annual
produce.
If the exchangeable value of the annual produce, on the
contrary,
fall short of the annual consumption, the capital of
the
society must annually decay in prorportion to this
deficiency.
The expense of the society, in this case, exceeds its
revenue,
and necessarily encroaches upon its capital. Its
capital,
therefore, must necessarily decay, and, together with
it, the
exchangeable value of the annual produce of its industry.
This
balance of produce and consumption is entirely different
from
what is called the balance of trade. It might take place in
a
nation which had no foreign trade, but which was entirely
separated
from all the world. It may take place in the whole
globe
of the earth, of which the wealth, population, and
improvement,
may be either gradually increasing or gradually
decaying.
The
balance of produce and consumption may be constantly in
favour
of a nation, though what is called the balance of trade be
generally
against it. A nation may import to a greater value than
it
exports for half a century, perhaps, together; the gold and
silver
which comes into it during all this time, may be all
immediately
sent out of it; its circulating coin may gradually
decay,
different sorts of paper money being substituted in its
place,
and even the debts, too, which it contracts in the
principal
nations with whom it deals, may be gradually
increasing;
and yet its real wealth, the exchangeable value of
the
annual produce of its lands and labour, may, during the same
period,
have been increasing in a much greater proportion. The
state
of our North American colonies, and of the trade which they
carried
on with Great Britain, before the commencement of the
present
disturbances, {This paragraph was written in the year
1775.}
may serve as a proof that this is by no means an
impossible
supposition.
CHAPTER IV.
OF
DRAWBACKS.
Merchants
and manufacturers are not contented with the monopoly
of the
home market, but desire likewise the most extensive
foreign
sale for their goods. Their country has no jurisdiction
in
foreign nations, and therefore can seldom procure them any
monopoly
there. They are generally obliged, therefore, to content
themselves
with petitioning for certain encouragements to
exportation.
Of
these encouragements, what are called drawbacks seem to be the
most
reasonable. To allow the merchant to draw back upon
exportation,
either the whole, or a part of whatever excise or
inland
duty is imposed upon domestic industry, can never occasion
the
exportation of a greater quantity of goods than what would
have
been exported had no duty been imposed. Such encouragements
do not
tend to turn towards any particular employment a greater
share
of the capital of the country, than what would go to that
employment
of its own accord, but only to hinder the duty from
driving
away any part of that share to other employments. They
tend
not to overturn that balance which naturally establishes
itself
among all the various employments of the society, but to
hinder
it from being overturned by the duty. They tend not to
destroy,
but to preserve, what it is in most cases advantageous
to
preserve, the natural division and distribution of labour in
the
society.
The
same thing may be said of the drawbacks upon the
re-exportation
of foreign goods imported, which, in Great
Britain,
generally amount to by much the largest part of the duty
upon
importation. By the second of the rules, annexed to the act
of
parliament, which imposed what is now called the old subsidy,
every
merchant, whether English or alien. was allowed to draw
back
half that duty upon exportation ; the English merchant,
provided
the exportation took place within twelve months; the
alien,
provided it took place within nine months. Wines,
currants,
and wrought silks, were the only goods which did not
fall
within this rule, having other and more advantageous
allowances.
The duties imposed by this act of parliament were, at
that
time, the only duties upon the importation of foreign goods.
The
term within which this, and all other drawbacks could be
claimed,
was afterwards (by 7 Geo. I. chap. 21. sect. 10.)
extended
to three years.
The
duties which have been imposed since the old subsidy, are,
the
greater part of them, wholly drawn back upon exportation.
This
general rule, however, is liable to a great number of
exceptions;
and the doctrine of drawbacks has become a much less
simple
matter than it was at their first institution.
Upon
the exportation of some foreign goods, of which it was
expected
that the importation would greatly exceed what was
necessary
for the home consumption, the whole duties are drawn
back,
without retaining even half the old subsidy. Before the
revolt
of our North American colonies, we had the monopoly of the
tobacco
of Maryland and Virginia. We imported about ninety-six
thousand
hogsheads, and the home consumption was not supposed to
exceed
fourteen thousand. To facilitate the great exportation
which
was necessary, in order to rid us of the rest, the whole
duties
were drawn back, provided the exportation took place
within
three years.
We
still have, though not altogether, yet very nearly, the
monopoly
of the sugars of our West Indian islands. If sugars are
exported
within a year, therefore, all the duties upon
importation
are drawn back; and if exported within three years,
all the
duties, except half the old subsidy, which still
continues
to be retained upon the exportation of the greater part
of
goods. Though the importation of sugar exceeds a good deal
what is
necessary for the home consumption, the excess is
inconsiderable,
in comparison of what it used to be in tobacco.
Some
goods, the particular objects of the jealousy of our own
manufacturers,
are prohibited to be imported for home
consumption.
They may, however, upon paying certain duties,be
imported
and warehoused for exportation. But upon such
exportation
no part of these duties is drawn back. Our
manufacturers
are unwilling, it seems, that even this restricted
importation
should be encouraged, and are afraid lest some part
of
these goods should be stolen out of the warehouse, and thus
come
into competition with their own. It is under these
regulations
only that we can import wrought silks, French
cambrics
and lawns, calicoes, painted, printed, stained, or dyed,
etc.
We are
unwilling even to be the carriers of French goods, and
choose
rather to forego a profit to ourselves than to suffer
those
whom we consider as our enemies to make any profit by our
means.
Not only half the old subsidy, but the second twenty-five
per
cent. is retained upon the exportation of all French goods.
By the
fourth of the rules annexed to the old subsidy, the
drawback
allowed upon the exportation of all wines amounted to a
great
deal more than half the duties which were at that time paid
upon
their importation ; and it seems at that time to have been
the
object of the legislature to give somewhat more than ordinary
encouragement
to the carrying trade in wine. Several of the other
duties,
too which were imposed either at the same time or
subsequent
to the old subsidy, what is called the additional
duty,
the new subsidy, the one-third and two-thirds subsidies,
the
impost 1692, the tonnage on wine, were allowed to be wholly
drawn
back upon exportation. All those duties, however, except
the
additional duty and impost 1692, being paid down in ready
money
upon importation, the interest of so large a sum occasioned
an
expense, which made it unreasonable to expect any profitable
carrying
trade in this article. Only a part, therefore of the
duty
called the impost on wine, and no part of the twenty-five
pounds
the ton upon French wines, or of the duties imposed in
1745,
in 1763, and in 1778, were allowed to be drawn back upon
exportation.
The two imposts of five per cent. imposed in 1779
and
1781, upon all the former duties of customs, being allowed to
be
wholly drawn back upon the exportation of all other goods,
were
likewise allowed to be drawn back upon that of wine. The
last
duty that has been particularly imposed upon wine, that of
1780,
is allowed to be wholly drawn back ; an indulgence which,
when so
many heavy duties are retained, most probably could never
occasion
the exportation of a single ton of wine. These rules
took
place with regard to all places of lawful exportation,
except
the British colonies in America.
The
15th Charles II, chap. 7, called an act for the encouragement
of
trade, had given Great Britain the monopoly of supplying the
colonies
with all the commodities of the growth or manufacture of
Europe,
and consequently with wines. In a country of so extensive
a coast
as our North American and West Indian colonies, where our
authority
was always so very slender, and where the inhabitants
were
allowed to carry out in their own ships their non-enumerated
commodities,
at first to all parts of Europe, and afterwards to
all
parts of Europe south of Cape Finisterre, it is not very
probable
that this monopoly could ever be much respected ; and
they
probably at all times found means of bringing back some
cargo
from the countries to which they were allowed to carry out
one.
They seem, however, to have found some difficulty in
importing
European wines from the places of their growth; and
they
could not well import them from Great Britain, where they
were
loaded with many heavy duties, of which a considerable part
was not
drawn back upon exportation. Madeira wine, not being an
European
commodity, could be imported directly into America and
the
West Indies, countries which, in all their non-enumerated
commodities,
enjoyed a free trade to the island of Madeira. These
circumstances
had probably introduced that general taste for
Madeira
wine, which our officers found established in all our
colonies
at the commencement of the war which began in 1755, and
which
they brought back with them to the mother country, where
that
wine had not been much in fashion before. Upon the
conclusion
of that war, in 1763 (by the 4th Geo. III, chap. 15,
sect.
12), all the duties except £3, 10s. were allowed to be
drawn
back upon the exportation to the colonies of all wines.
except
French wines, to the commerce and consumption of which
national
prejudice would allow no sort of encouragement. The
period
between the granting of this indulgence and the revolt of
our
North American colonies, was probably too short to admit of
any
considerable change in the customs of those countries.
The
same act which, in the drawbacks upon all wines, except
French
wines, thus favoured the colonies so much more than other
countries,
in those upon the greater part of other commodities,
favoured
them much less. Upon the exportation of the greater part
of
commodities to other countries, half the old subsidy was drawn
back.
But this law enacted, that no part of that duty should be
drawn
back upon the exportation to the colonies of any
commodities
of the growth or manufacture either of Europe or the
East
Indies, except wines, white calicoes, and muslins.
Drawbacks
were, perhaps, originally granted for the encouragement
of the
carrying trade, which, as the freight of the ship is
frequently
paid by foreigners in money, was supposed to be
peculiarly
fitted for bringing gold and silver into the country.
But
though the carrying trade certainly deserves no peculiar
encouragement,
though the motive of the institution was, perhaps,
abundantly
foolish, the institution itself seems reasonable
enough.
Such drawbacks cannot force into this trade a greater
share
of the capital of the country than what would have gone to
it of
its own accord, had there been no duties upon importation;
they
only prevent its being excluded altogether by those duties.
The
carrying trade, though it deserves no preference, ought not
to be
precluded, but to be left free, like all other trades. It
is a
necessary resource to those capitals which cannot find
employment,
either in the agriculture or in the manufactures of
the
country, either in its home trade, or in its foreign trade of
consumption.
The
revenue of the customs, instead of suffering, profits from
such
drawbacks, by that part of the duty which is retained. If
the
whole duties had been retained, the foreign goods upon which
they
are paid could seldom have been exported, nor consequently
imported,
for want of a market. The duties, therefore, of which a
part is
retained, would never have been paid.
These
reasons seem sufficiently to justify drawbacks, and would
justify
them, though the whole duties, whether upon the produce
of
domestic industry or upon foreign goods, were always drawn
back
upon exportation. The revenue of excise would, in this case
indeed,
suffer a little, and that of the customs a good deal
more;
but the natural balance of industry, the natural division
and
distribution of labour, which is always more or less
disturbed
by such duties, would be more nearly re-established by
such a
regulation.
These
reasons, however, will justify drawbacks only upon
exporting
goods to those countries which are altogether foreign
and
independent, not to those in which our merchants and
manufacturers
enjoy a monopoly. A drawback, for example, upon the
exportation
of European goods to our American colonies, will not
always
occasion a greater exportation than what would have taken
place
without it. By means of the monopoly which our merchants
and
manufacturers enjoy there, the same quantity might
frequently,
perhaps, be sent thither, though the whole duties
were
retained. The drawback, therefore, may frequently be pure
loss to
the revenue of excise and customs, without altering the
state
of the trade, or rendering it in any respect more
extensive.
How far such drawbacks can be justified as a proper
encouragement
to the industry of our colonies, or how far it is
advantageous
to the mother country that they should be exempted
from
taxes which are paid by all the rest of their
fellow-subjects,
will appear hereafter, when I come to treat of
colonies.
Drawbacks,
however, it must always be understood, are useful only
in
those cases in which the goods, for the exportation of which
they
are given, are really exported to some foreign country, and
not
clandestinely re-imported into our own. That some drawbacks,
particularly
those upon tobacco, have frequently been abused in
this
manner, and have given occasion to many frauds, equally
hurtful
both to the revenue and to the fair trader, is well
known.
CHAPTER V.
OF
BOUNTIES.
Bounties
upon exportation are, in Great Britain, frequently
petitioned
for, and sometimes granted, to the produce of
particular
branches of domestic industry. By means of them, our
merchants
and manufacturers, it is pretended, will be enabled to
sell
their goods as cheap or cheaper than their rivals in the
foreign
market. A greater quantity, it is said, will thus be
exported,
and the balance of trade consequently turned more in
favour
of our own country. We cannot give our workmen a monopoly
in the
foreign, as we have done in the home market. We cannot
force
foreigners to buy their goods, as we have done our own
countrymen.
The next best expedient, it has been thought,
therefore,
is to pay them for buying. It is in this manner that
the
mercantile system proposes to enrich the whole country, and
to put
money into all our pockets, by means of the balance of
trade.
Bounties,
it is allowed, ought to be given to those branches of
trade
only which cannot be carried on without them. But every
branch
of trade in which the merchant can sell his goods for a
price
which replaces to him, with the ordinary profits of stock,
the
whole capital employed in preparing and sending them to
market,
can be carried on without a bounty. Every such branch is
evidently
upon a level with all the other branches of trade which
are
carried on without bounties, and cannot, therefore, require
one
more than they. Those trades only require bounties, in which
the
merchant is obliged to sell his goods for a price which does
not
replace to him his capital, together with the ordinary
profit,
or in which he is obliged to sell them for less than it
really
cost him to send them to market. The bounty is given in
order
to make up this loss, and to encourage him to continue, or,
perhaps,
to begin a trade, of which the expense is supposed to be
greater
than the returns, of which every operation eats up a part
of the
capital employed in it, and which is of such a nature,
that if
all other trades resembled it, there would soon be no
capital
left in the country.
The
trades, it is to be observed, which are carried on by means
of
bounties, are the only ones which can be carried on between
two
nations for any considerable time together, in such a manner
as that
one of them shall alway's and regularly lose, or sell its
goods
for less than it really cost to send them to market. But if
the
bounty did not repay to the merchant what he would otherwise
lose
upon the price of his goods, his own interest would soon
oblige
him to employ his stock in another way, or to find out a
trade
in which the price of the goods would replace to him, with
the
ordinary profit, the capital employed in sending them to
market.
The effect of bounties, like that of all the other
expedients
of the mercantile system, can only be to force the
trade
of a country into a channel much less advantageous than
that in
which it would naturally run of its own accord.
The
ingenious and well-informed author of the Tracts upon the
Corn
Trade has shown very clearly, that since the bounty upon the
exportation
of corn was first established, the price of the corn
exported,
valued moderately enough, has exceeded that of the corn
imported,
valued very high, by a much greater sum than the amount
of the
whole bounties which have been paid during that period.
This,
he imagines, upon the true principles of the mercantile
system,
is a clear proof that this forced corn trade is
beneficial
to the nation, the value of the exportation exceeding
that of
the importation by a much greater sum than the whole
extraordinary
expense which the public has been at in order to
get it
exported. He does not consider that this extraordinary
expense,
or the bounty, is the smallest part of the expense which
the
exportation of corn really costs the society. The capital
which
the farmer employed in raising it must likewise be taken
into
the account. Unless the price of the corn, when sold in the
foreign
markets, replaces not only the bounty, but this capital,
together
with the ordinary profits of stock, the society is a
loser
by the difference, or the national stock is so much
diminished.
But the very reason for which it has been thought
necessary
to grant a bounty, is the supposed insufficiency of the
price
to do this.
The
average price of corn, it has been said, has fallen
considerably
since the establishment of the bounty. That the
average
price of corn began to fall somewhat towards the end of
the
last century, and has continued to do so during the course of
the
sixty-four first years of the present, I have already
endeavoured
to show. But this event, supposing it to be real, as
I
believe it to be, must have happened in spite of the bounty,
and
cannot possibly have happened in consequence of it. It has
happened
in France, as well as in England, though in France there
was not
only no bounty, but, till 1764, the exportation of corn
was
subjected to a general prohibition. This gradual fall in the
average
price of grain, it is probable, therefore, is ultimately
owing
neither to the one regulation nor to the other, but to that
gradual
and insensible rise in the real value of silver, which,
in the
first book of this discourse, I have endeavoured to show,
has
taken place in the general market of Europe during the course
of the
present century. It seems to be altogether impossible that
the
bounty could ever contribute to lower the price of grain.
In
years of plenty, it has already been observed, the bounty, by
occasioning
an extraordinary exportation, necessarily keeps up
the
price of corn in the home market above what it would
naturally
fall to. To do so was the avowed purpose of the
institution.
In years of scarcity, though the bounty is
frequently
suspended, yet the great exportation which it
occasions
in years of plenty, must frequently hinder, more or
less,
the plenty of one year from relieving the scarcity of
another.
Both in years of plenty and in years of scarcity,
therefore,
the bounty necessarily tends to raise the money price
of corn
somewhat higher than it otherwise would be in the home
market.
That in the actual state of tillage the
bounty must necessarily
have
this tendency, will not, I apprehend, be disputed by any
reasonable
person. But it has been thought by many people, that
it
tends to encourage tillage, and that in two different ways ;
first,
by opening a more extensive foreign market to the corn of
the
farmer, it tends, they imagine, to increase the demand for,
and
consequently the production of, that commodity; and, secondly
by
securing to him a better price than he could otherwise expect
in the
actual state of tillage, it tends, they suppose, to
encourage
tillage. This double encouragement must they imagine,
in a
long period of years, occasion such an increase in the
production
of corn, as may lower its price in the home market,
much
more than the bounty can raise it in the actual state which
tillage
may, at the end of that period, happen to be in.
I
answer, that whatever extension of the foreign market can be
occasioned
by the bounty must, in every particular year, be
altogether
at the expense of the home market ; as every bushel of
corn,
which is exported by means of the bounty, and which would
not
have been exported without the bounty, would have remained in
the
home market to increase the consumption, and to lower the
price
of that commodity. The corn bounty, it is to be observed,
as well
as every other bounty upon exportation, imposes two
different
taxes upon the people; first, the tax which they are
obliged
to contribute, in order to pay the bounty ; and,
secondly,
the tax which arises from the advanced price of the
commodity
in the home market, and which, as the whole body of the
people
are purchasers of corn, must, in this particular
commodity,
be paid by the whole body of the people. In this
particular
commodity, therefore, this second tax is by much the
heaviest
of the two. Let us suppose that, taking one year with
another,
the bounty of 5s. upon the exportation of the quarter of
wheat
raises the price of that commodity in the home market only
6d. the
bushel, or 4s. the quarter higher than it otherwise would
have
been in the actual state of the crop. Even upon this very
moderate
supposition, the great body of the people, over and
above
contributing the tax which pays the bounty of 5s. upon
every
quarter of wheat exported, must pay another of 4s. upon
every
quarter which they themselves consume. But according to the
very
well informed author of the Tracts upon the Corn Trade, the
average
proportion of the corn exported to that consumed at home,
is not
more than that of one to thirty-one. For every 5s.
therefore,
which they contribute to the payment of the first tax,
they
must contribute £6:4s. to the payment of the second. So very
heavy a
tax upon the first necessary of life-must either reduce
the
subsistence of the labouring poor, or it must occasion some
augmentation
in their pecuniary wages, proportionable to that in
the
pecuniary price of their subsistence. So far as it operates
in the
one way, it must reduce the ability of the labouring poor
to
educate and bring up their children, and must, so far, tend to
restrain
the population of the country. So far as it operate's in
the
other, it must reduce the ability of the employers of the
poor,
to employ so great a number as they otherwise might do, and
must so
far tend to restrain the industry of the country. The
extraordinary
exportation of corn, therefore occasioned by the
bounty,
not only in every particular year diminishes the home,
just as
much as it extends the foreign market and consumption,
but, by
restraining the population and industry of the country,
its
final tendency is to stint and restrain the gradual extension
of the
home market ; and thereby, in the long-run, rather to
diminish
than to augment the whole market and consumption of
corn.
This
enhancement of the money price of corn, however, it has been
thought,
by rendering that commodity more profitable to the
farmer,
must necessarily encourage its production.
I
answer, that this might be the case, if the effect of the
bounty
was to raise the real price of corn, or to enable the
farmer,
with an equal quantity of it, to maintain a greater
number
of labourers in the same manner, whether liberal,
moderate,
or scanty, than other labourers are commonly maintained
in his
neighbourhood. But neither the bounty, it is evident, nor
any
other human institution, can have any such effect. It is not
the
real, but the nominal price of corn, which can in any
considerable
degree be affected by the bounty. And though the
tax,
which that institution imposes upon the whole body of the
people,
may be very burdensome to those who pay it, it is of very
little
advantage to those who receive it.
The
real effect of the bounty is not so much to raise the real
value
of corn, as to degrade the real value of silver ; or to
make an
equal quantity of it exchange for a smaller quantity, not
only of
corn, but of all other home made commodities; for the
money
price of corn regulates that of all other home made
commodities.
It
regulates the money price of labour, which must always be such
as to
enable the labourer to purchase a quantity of corn
sufficient
to maintain him and his family, either in the liberal,
moderate,
or scanty manner, in which the advancing, stationary,
or
declining, circumstances of the society, oblige his employers
to
maintain him.
It
regulates the money price of all the other parts of the rude
produce
of land, which, in every period of improvement, must bear
a
certain proportion to that of corn, though this proportion is
different
in different periods. It regulates, for example, the
money
price of grass and hay, of butcher's meat, of horses, and
the
maintenance of horses, of land carriage consequently, or of
the
greater part of the inland commerce of the country.
By
regulating the money price of all the other parts of the rude
produce
of land, it regulates that of the materials of almost all
manufactures;
by regulating the money price of labour, it
regulates
that of manufacturing art and industry ; and by
regulating
both, it regulates that of the complete manufacture.
The
money price of labour, and of every thing that is the
produce,
either of land or labour, must necessarily either rise
or fall
in proportion to the money price of corn.
Though
in consequence of the bounty, therefore, the farmer should
be
enabled to sell his corn for 4s. the bushel, instead of 3s:6d.
and to
pay his landlord a money rent proportionable to this rise
in the
money price of his produce; yet if, in consequence of this
rise in
the price of corn, 4s. will purchase no more home made
goods
of any other kind than 3s. 6d. would have done before,
neither
the circumstances of the farmer, nor those of the
landlord,
will be much mended by this change. The farmer will not
be able
to cultivate much better ; the landlord will not be able
to live
much better. In the purchase of foreign commodities, this
enhancement
in the price of corn may give them some little
advantage.
In that of home made commodities, it can give them
none at
all. And almost the whole expense of the farmer, and the
far
greater part even of that of the landlord, is in home made
commodities.
That
degradation in the value of silver, which is the effect of
the
fertility of the mines, and which operates equally, or very
nearly
equally, through the greater part of the commercial world,
is a matter
of very little consequence to any particular country.
The
consequent rise of all money prices, though it does not make
those
who receive them really richer, does not make them really
poorer.
A service of plate becomes really cheaper, and every
thing
else remains precisely of the same real value as before.
But
that degradation in the value of silver, which, being the
effect
either of the peculiar situation or of the political
institutions
of a particular country, takes place only in that
country,
is a matter of very great consequence, which, far from
tending
to make anybody really richer, tends to make every body
really
poorer. The rise in the money price of all commodities,
which
is in this case peculiar to that country, tends to
discourage
more or less every sort of industry which is carried
on
within it, and to enable foreign nations, by furnishing almost
all
sorts of goods for a smaller quantity of silver than its own
workmen
can afford to do, to undersell them, not only in the
foreign,
but even in the home market.
It is
the peculiar situation of Spain and Portugal, as
proprietors
of the mines. to be the distributers of gold and
silver
to all the other countries of Europe. Those metals ought
naturally,
therefore, to be somewhat cheaper in Spain and
Portugal
than in any other part of Europe. The difference, how.
ever,
should be no more than the amount of the freight and
insurance
; and, on account of the great value and small bulk of
those
metals, their freight is no great matter, and their
insurance
is the same as that of any other goods of equal value.
Spain
and Portugal, therefore, could suffer very little from
their
peculiar situation, if they did not aggravate its
disadvantages
by their political institutions.
Spain
by taxing, and Portugal by prohibiting, the exportation of
gold
and silver, load that exportation with the expense of
smuggling,
and raise the value of those metals in other countries
so much
more above what it is in their own, by the whole amount
of this
expense. When you dam up a stream of water, as soon as
the dam
is full, as much water must run over the dam-head as if
there
was no dam at all. The prohibition of exportation cannot
detain
a greater quantity of gold and silver in Spain and
Portugal,
than what they can afford to employ, than what the
annual
produce of their land and labour will allow them to
employ,
in coin, plate, gilding, and other ornaments of gold and
silver.
When they have got this quantity, the dam is full, and
the
whole stream which flows in afterwards must run over. The
annual
exportation of gold and silver from Spain and Portugal,
accordingly,
is, by all accounts, notwithstanding these
restraints,
very near equal to the whole annual importation. As
the
water, however, must always be deeper behind the dam-head
than
before it, so the quantity of gold and silver which these
restraints
detain in Spain and Portugal, must, in proportion to
the
annual produce of their land and labour, be greater than what
is to
be found in other countries. The higher and stronger the
dam-head,
the greater must be the difference in the depth of
water
behind and before it. The higher the tax, the higher the
penalties
with which the prohibition is guarded, the more
vigilant
and severe the police which looks after the execution of
the
law, the greater must be the difference in the proportion of
gold
and silver to the annual produce of the land and labour of
Spain
and Portugal, and to that of other countries. It is said,
accordingly,
to be very considerable, and that you frequently
find
there a profusion of plate in houses, where there is nothing
else
which would in other countries be thought suitable or
correspondent
to this sort of magnificence. The cheapness of gold
and
silver, or, what is the same thing, the dearness of all
commodities,
which is the necessary effect of this redundancy of
the
precious metals, discourages both the agriculture and
manufactures
of Spain and Portugal, and enables foreign nations
to
supply them with many sorts of rude, and with almost all sorts
of
manufactured produce, for a smaller quantity of gold and
silver
than what they themselves can either raise or make them
for at
home. The tax and prohibition operate in two different
ways.
They not only lower very much the value of the precious
metals
in Spain and Portugal, but by detaining there a certain
quantity
of those metals which would otherwise flow over other
countries,
they keep up their value in those other countries
somewhat
above what it otherwise would be, and thereby give those
countries
a double advantage in their commerce with Spain and
Portugal.
Open the flood-gates, and there will presently be less
water
above, and more below the dam-head, and it will soon come
to a
level in both places. Remove the tax and the prohibition,
and as
the quantity of gold and silver will diminish considerably
in
Spain and Portugal, so it will increase somewhat in other
countries
; and the value of those metals, their proportion to
the
annual produce of land and labour, will soon come to a level,
or very
near to a level, in all. The loss which Spain and
Portugal
could sustain by this exportation of their gold and
silver,
would be altogether nominal and imaginary. The nominal
value
of their goods, and of the annual produce of their land and
labour,
would fall, and would be expressed or represented by a
smaller
quantity of silver than before; but their real value
would
be the same as before, and would be sufficient to maintain,
command,
and employ the same quantity of labour. As the nominaly
value
of their goods would fall, the real value of what remained
of
their gold and silver would rise, and a smaller quantity of
those
metals would answer all the same purposes of commerce and
circulation
which had employed a greater quantity before. The
gold
and silver which would go abroad would not go abroad for
nothing,
but would bring back an equal value of goods of some
kind or
other. Those goods, too, would not be all matters of mere
luxury
and expense, to be consumed by idle people, who produce
nothing
in return for their consumption. As the real wealth and
revenue
of idle people would not be augmented by this
extraordinary
exportation of gold and silver, so neither would
their
consumption be much augmented by it. Those goods would
probably,
the greater part of them, and certainly some part of
them,
consist in materials, tools, and provisions, for the
employment
and maintenance of industrious people, who would
reproduce,
with a profit, the full value of their consumption.
A part
of the dead stock of the society would thus be turned into
active
stock, and would put into motion a greater quantity of
industry
than had been employed before. The annual produce of
their
land and labour would immediately be augmented a little,
and in
a few years would probably be augmented a great deal;
their
industry being thus relieved from one of the most
oppressive
burdens which it at present labours under.
The
bounty upon the exportation of corn necessarily operates
exactly
in the same way as this absurd policy of Spain and
Portugal.
Whatever be the actual state of tillage, it renders our
corn
somewhat dearer in the home market than it otherwise would
be in
that state, and somewhat cheaper in the foreign; and as the
average
money price of corn regulates, more or less, that of all
other
commodities, it lowers the value of silver considerably in
the
one, and tends to raise it a little in the other. It enables
foreigners,
the Dutch in particular, not only to eat our corn
cheaper
than they otherwise could do, but sometimes to eat it
cheaper
than even our own people can do upon the same occasions;
as we
are assured by an excellent authority, that of Sir Matthew
Decker.
It hinders our own workmen from furnishing their goods
for so
small a quantity of silver as they otherwise might do, and
enables
the Dutch to furnish theirs for a smaller. It tends to
render
our manufactures somewhat dearer in every market, and
theirs
somewhat cheaper, than they otherwise would be, and
consequently
to give their industry a double advantage over our
own.
The
bounty, as it raises in the home market, not so much the
real,
as the nominal price of our corn; as it augments, not the
quantity
of labour which a certain quantity of corn can maintain
and
employ, but only the quantity of silver which it will
exchange
for ; it discourages our manufactures, without rendering
any
considerable service, either to our farmers or country
gentlemen.
It puts, indeed, a little more money into the pockets
of
both, and it will perhaps be somewhat difficult to persuade
the
greater part of them that this is not rendering them a very
considerable
service. But if this money sinks in its value, in
the
quantity of labour, provisions, and home-made commodities of
all
different kinds which it is capable of purchasing, as much as
it
rises in its quantity, the service will be little more than
nominal
and imaginary.
There
is, perhaps, but one set of men in the whole commonwealth
to whom
the bounty either was or could be essentially
serviceable.
These were the corn merchants, the exporters and
importers
of corn. In years of plenty, the bounty necessarily
occasioned
a greater exportation than would otherwise have taken
place ;
and by hindering the plenty of the one year from
relieving
the scarcity of another, it occasioned in years of
scarcity
a greater importation than would otherwise have been
necessary.
It increased the business of the corn merchant in
both;
and in the years of scarcity, it not only enabled him to
import
a greater quantity, but to sell it for a better price, and
consequently
with a greater profit, than he could otherwise have
made,
if the plenty of one year had not been more or less
hindered
from relieving the scarcity of another. It is in this
set of
men, accordingly, that I have observed the greatest zeal
for the
continuance or renewal of the bounty.
Our
country gentlemen, when they imposed the high duties upon the
exportation
of foreign corn, which in times of moderate plenty
amount
to a prohibition, and when they established the bounty,
seem to
have imitated the conduct of our manufacturers. By the
one
institution, they secured to themselves the monopoly of the
home
market, and by the other they endeavoured to prevent that
market
from ever being overstocked with their commodity. By both
they
endeavoured to raise its real value, in the same manner as
our
manufacturers had, by the like institutions, raised the real
value
of many different sorts of manufactured goods. They did
not,
perhaps, attend to the great and essential difference which
nature
has established between corn and almost every other sort
of
goods. When, either by the monopoly of the home market, or by
a
bounty upon exportation, you enable our woollen or linen
manufacturers
to sell their goods for somewhat a better price
than
they otherwise could get for them, you raise, not only the
nominal,
but the real price of those goods; you render them
equivalent
to a greater quantity of labour and subsistence; you
increase
not only the nominal, but the real profit, the real
wealth
and revenue of those manufacturers ; and you enable them,
either
to live better themselves, or to employ a greater quantity
of
labour in those particular manufactures. You really encourage
those
manufactures, and direct towards them a greater quantity of
the
industry of the country than what would properly go to them
of its
own accord. But when, by the like institutions, you raise
the
nominal or money price of corn, you do not raise its real
value ;
you do not increase the real wealth, the real revenue,
either
of our farmers or country gentlemen ; you do not encourage
the
growth of corn, because you do not enable them to maintain
and
employ more labourers in raising it. The nature of things has
stamped
upon corn a real value, which cannot be altered by merely
altering
its money price. No bounty upon exportation, no monopoly
of the
home market, can raise that value. The freest competition
cannot
lower it, Through the world in general, that value is
equal
to the quantity of labour which it can maintain, and in
every
particular place it is equal to the quantity of labour
which
it can maintain in the way, whether liberal, moderate, or
scanty,
in which labour is commonly maintained in that place.
Woollen
or linen cloth are not the regulating commodities by
which
the real value of all other commodities must be finally
measured
and determined ; corn is. The real value of every other
commodity
is finally measured and detemnined by the proportion
which
its average money price bears to the average money price of
corn.
The real value of corn does not vary with those variations
in its
average money price, which sometimes occur from one
century
to another ; it is the real value of silver which varies
with
them.
Bounties
upon the exportation of any homemade commodity are
liable,
first, to that general objection which may be made to all
the
different expedients of the mercantile system ; the objection
of
forcing some part of the industry of the country into a
channel
less advantageous than that in which it would run of its
own
accord ; and, secondly, to the particular objection of
forcing
it not only into a channel that is less advantageous, but
into
one that is actually disadvantageous ; the trade which
cannot
be carried on but by means of a bounty being necessarily a
losing
trade. The bounty upon the exportation of corn is liable
to this
further objection, that it can in no respect promote the
raising
of that particular commodity of which it was meant to
encourage
the production. When our country gentlemen, therefore,
demanded
the establishment of the bounty, though they acted in
imitation
of our merchants and manufacturers, they did not act
with
that complete comprehension of their own interest, which
commonly
directs the conduct of those two other orders of people.
They
loaded the public revenue with a very considerable expense:
they
imposed a very heavy tax upon the whole body of the people ;
but
they did not, in any sensible degree, increase the real value
of
their own commodity; and by lowering somewhat the real value
of
silver, they discouraged, in some degree, the general industry
of the
country, and, instead of advancing, retarded more or less
the
improvement of their own lands, which necessarily depend upon
the
general industry of the country.
To
encourage the production of any commodity, a bounty upon
production,
one should imagine, would have a more direct
operation
than one upon exportation. It would, besides, impose
only
one tax upon the people, that which they must contribute in
order
to pay the bounty. Instead of raising, it would tend to
lower
the price of the commodity in the home market ; and
thereby,
instead of imposing a second tax upon the people, it
might,
at least in part, repay them for what they had contributed
to the
first. Bounties upon production, however, have been very
rarely
granted. The prejudices established by the commercial
system
have taught us to believe, that national wealth arises
more
immediately from exportation than from production. It has
been
more favoured, accordingly, as the more immediate means of
bringing
money into the country. Bounties upon production, it has
been
said too, have been found by experience more liable to
frauds
than those upon exportation. How far this is true, I know
not.
That bounties upon exportation have been abused, to many
fraudulent
purposes, is very well known. But it is not the
interest
of merchants and manufacturers, the great inventors of
all
these expedients, that the home market should be overstocked
with
their goods; an event which a bounty upon production might
sometimes
occasion. A bounty upon exportation, by enabling them
to send
abroad their surplus part, and to keep up the price of
what
remains in the home market, effectually prevents this. Of
all the
expedients of the mercantile system, accordingly, it is
the one
of which they are the fondest. I have known the different
undertakers
of some particular works agree privately among
themselves
to give a bounty out of their own pockets upon the
exportation
of a certain proportion of the goods which they dealt
in.
This expedient succeeded so well, that it more than doubled
the
price of their goods in the home market, notwithstanding a
very
considerable increase in the produce. The operation of the
bounty
upon corn must have been wonderfully different, if it has
lowered
the money price of that commodity.
Something
like a bounty upon production, however, has been
granted
upon some particular occasions. The tonnage bounties
given
to the white herring and whale fisheries may, perhaps, be
considered
as somewhat of this nature. They tend directly, it may
be
supposed, to render the goods cheaper in the home market than
they
otherwise would be. In other respects, their effects, it
must be
acknowledged, are the same as those of bounties upon
exportation.
By means of them, a part of the capital of the
country
is employed in bringing goods to market, of which the
price
does not repay the cost, together with the ordinary profits
of
stock.
But
though the tonnage bounties to those fisheries do not
contribute
to the opulence of the nation, it may, perhaps, be
thought
that they contribute to its defence, by augmenting the
number
of its sailors and shipping. This, it may be alleged, may
sometimes
be done by means of such bounties, at a much smaller
expense
than by keeping up a great standing navy, if I may use
such an
expression, in the same way as a standing army.
Notwithstanding
these favourable allegations, however, the
following
considerations dispose me to believe, that in granting
at
least one of these bounties, the legislature has been very
grossly
imposed upon:
First,
The herring-buss bounty seems too large.
From
the commencement of the winter fishing 1771, to the end of
the
winter fishing 1781, the tonnage bounty upon the herring-buss
fishery
has been at thirty shillings the ton. During these eleven
years,
the whole number of barrels caught by the herring-buss
fishery
of Scotland amounted to 378,347. The herrings caught and
cured
at sea are called sea-sticks. In order to render them what
are
called merchantable herrings, it is necessary to repack them
with an
additional quantity of salt ; and in this case, it is
reckoned,
that three barrels of sea-sticks are usually repacked
into
two barrels of merchantable herrings. The number of barrels
of
merchantable herrings, therefore, caught during these eleven
years,
will amount only, according to this account, to 252,231¼.
During
these eleven years, the tonnage bounties paid amounted to
£155,463:11s.
or 8s:2¼d. upon every barrel of sea-sticks, and to
12s:3¾d.
upon every barrel of merchantable herrings.
The
salt with which these herrings are cured is sometimes Scotch,
and
sometimes foreign salt ; both which are delivered, free of
all
excise duty, to the fish-curers. The excise duty upon Scotch
salt is
at present 1s:6d., that upon foreign salt 10s. the
bushel.
A barrel of herrings is supposed to require about one
bushel
and one-fourth of a bushel foreign salt. Two bushels are
the
supposed average of Scotch salt. If the herrings are entered
for
exportation, no part of this duty is paid up; if entered for
home
consumption, whether the herrings were cured with foreign or
with
Scotch salt, only one shilling the barrel is paid up. It was
the old
Scotch duty upon a bushel of salt, the quantity which, at
a low
estimation, had been supposed necessary for curing a barrel
of
herrings. In Scotland, foreign salt is very little used for
any
other purpose but the curing of fish. But from the 5th April
1771 to
the 5th April 1782, the quantity of foreign salt imported
amounted
to 936,974 bushels, at eighty-four pounds the bushel ;
the
quantity of Scotch salt delivered from the works to the
fish-curers,
to no more than 168,226, at fifty-six pounds the
bushel
only. It would appear, therefore, that it is principally
foreign
salt that is used in the fisheries. Upon every barrel of
herrings
exported, there is, besides, a bounty of 2s:8d. and more
than
two-thirds of the buss-caught herrings are exported. Put all
these
things together, and you will find that, during these
eleven
years, every barrel of buss-caught herrings, cured with
Scotch
salt, when exported, has cost government 17s:11¾d.; and,
when
entered for home consumption, 14s:3¾d.; and that every
barrel
cured with foreign salt, when exported, has cost
government
£1:7:5¾d. ; and, when entered for home consumption,
£1:3:9¾d.
The price of a barrel of good merchantable herrings
runs
from seventeen and eighteen to four and five-and-twenty
shillings
; about a guinea at an average. {See the accounts at
the end
of this Book.}
Secondly, The bounty to the white-herring fishery is a
tonnage
bounty, and is proportioned to the burden of the ship,
not to
her diliglence or success in the fishery ; and it has, I
am
afraid, been too common for the vessels to fit out for the
sole
purpose of catching, not the fish but the bounty. In the
year
1759, when the bounty was at fifty shillings the ton, the
whole
buss fishery of Scotland brought in only four barrels of
sea-sticks.
In that year, each barrel of sea-sticks cost
government,
in bounties alone, £113:15s.; each barrel of
merchantable
herrings £159:7:6.
Thirdly, The mode of fishing, for which this
tonnage bounty
in the
white herring fishery has been given (by busses or decked
vessels
from twenry to eighty tons burden ), seems not so well
adapted
to the situation of Scotland, as to that of Holland, from
the
practice of which country it appears to have been borrowed.
Holland
lies at a great distance from the seas to which herrings
are
known principally to resort, and can, therefore, carry on
that
fishery only in decked vessels, which can carry water and
provisions
sufficient for a voyage to a distant sea ; but the
Hebrides,
or Western Isdands, the islands of Shetland, and the
northern
and north-western coasts of Scotland, the countries in
whose
neighbourhood the herring fishery is principally carried
on. are
everywhere intersected by arms of the sea, which run up a
considerable
way into the land, and which, in the language of the
country,
are called sea-lochs. It is to these sea-lochs that the
herrings
principally resort during the seasons in which they
visit
these seas; for the visits of this, and, I am assured, of
many
other sorts of fish, are not quite regular and constant. A
boat-fishery,
therefore, seems to be the mode of fishing best
adapted
to the peculiar situation of Scotland, the fishers
carrying
the herrings on shore as fast as they are taken, to he
either
cured or consumed fresh. But the great encouragement which
a
bounty of 30s. the ton gives to the buss-fishery, is
necessarily
a discouragement to the boat-fishery, which, having
no such
bounty, cannot bring its cured fish to market upon the
same
terms as the buss-fishery. The boat-fishery; accordingly,
which,
before the establishment of the buss-bounty, was very
considerable,
and is said to have employed a number of seamen,
not
inferior to what the buss-fishery employs at present, is now
gone
almost entirely to decay. Of the former extent, however, of
this
now ruined and abandoned fishery, I must acknowledge that I
cannot
pretend to speak with much precision. As no bounty
was-paid
upon the outfit of the boat-fishery, no account was
taken
of it by the officers of the customs or salt duties.
Fourthly, In many parts of Scotland, during certain
seasons
of the
year, herrings make no inconsiderable part of the food of
the
common people. A bounty which tended to lower their price in
the
home market, might countribute a good deal to the relief of a
great
number of our fellow-subjects, whose circumstances are by
no
means affuent. But the herring-bus bounty contributes to no
such
good purpose. It has ruined the boat fishery, which is by
far the
best adapted for the supply of the home market; and the
additional
bounty of 2s:8d. the barrel upon exportation, carries
the
greater part, more than two-thirds, of the produce of the
buss-fishery
abroad. Between thirty and forty years ago, before
the
establishment of the buss-bounty, 16s. the barrel, I have
been
assured, was the common price of white herrings. Between ten
and
fifteen years ago, before the boat-fishery was entirely
ruined,
the price was said to have run from seventeen to twenty
shillings
the barrel. For these last five years, it has, at an
average,
been at twenty-five shillings the barrel. This high
price,
however, may have been owing to the real scarcity of the
herrings
upon the coast of Scotland. I must observe, too, that
the
cask or barrel, which is usually sold with the herrings, and
of
which the price is included in all the foregoing prices, has,
since
the commencement of the American war, risen to about double
its
former price, or from about 3s. to about 6s. I must likewise
observe,
that the accounts I have received of the prices of
former
times, have been by no means quite uniform and consistent,
and an
old man of great accuracy and experience has assured me,
that,
more than fifty years ago, a guinea was the usual price of
a
barrel of good merchantable herrings; and this, I imagine, may
still
be looked upon as the average price. All accounts, however,
I
think, agree that the price has not been lowered in the home
market
in consequence of the buss-bounty.
When
the undertakers of fisheries, after such liberal bounties
have
been bestowed upon them, continue to sell their commodity at
the
same, or even at a higher price than they were accustomed to
do
before, it might be expected that their profits should be very
great ;
and it is not improbable that those of some individuals
may
have been so. In general, however, I have every reason to
believe
they have been quite otherwise. The usual effect of such
bounties
is, to encourage rash undertakers to adventure in a
business
which they do not understand; and what they lose by
their
own negligence and ignorance, more than compensates all
that
they can gain by the utmost liberality of government. In
1750,
by the same act which first gave the bounty of 30s. the ton
for the
encouragement of the white herring fishery (the 23d Geo.
II.
chap. 24), a joint stock company was erected, with a capital
of
£500,000, to which the subscribers (over and above all other
encouragements,
the tonnage bounty just now mentioned, the
exportation
bounty of 2s:8d. the barrel, the delivery of both
British
and foreign salt duty free) were, during the space of
fourteen
years, for every hundred pounds which they subscribed
and
paid into the stock of the society, entitled to three pounds
a-year,
to be paid by the receiver-general of the customs in
equal
half-yearly payments. Besides this great company, the
residence
of whose governor and directors was to be in London, it
was
declared lawful to erect different fishing chambers in all
the
different out-ports of the kingdom, provided a sum not less
than
£10,000 was subscribed into the capital of each, to be
managed
at its own risk, and for its own profit and loss. The
same
annuity, and the same encouragements of all kinds, were
given
to the trade of those inferior chambers as to that of the
great
company. The subscription of the great company was soon
filled
up, and several different fishing chambers were erected in
the
different out-ports of the kingdom. In spite of all these
encouragements,
almost all those different companies, both great
and
small, lost either the whole or the greater part of their
capitals;
scarce a vestige now remains of any of them, and the
white-herring
fishery is now entirely, or almost entirely,
carried
on by private adventurers.
If any
particular manufacture was necessary, indeed, for the
defence
of the society, it might not always be prudent to depend
upon
our neighbours for the supply; and if such manufacture could
not
otherwise be supported at home, it might not be unreasonable
that
all the other branches of industry should be taxed in order
to support
it. The bounties upon the exportation of British made
sail-cloth,
and British made gunpowder, may, perhaps, both be
vindicated
upon this principle.
But
though it can very seldom be reasonable to tax the industry
of the
great body of the people, in order to support that of some
particular
class of manufacturers ; yet, in the wantonness of
great
prosperity, when the public enjoys a greater revenue than
it
knows well what to do with, to give such bounties to favourite
manufactures,
may, perhaps, be as natural as to incur any other
idle
expense. In public, as well as in private expenses, great
wealth,
may, perhaps, frequently be admitted as an apology for
great
folly. But there must surely be something more than
ordinary
absurdity in continuing such profusion in times of
general
difficulty and distress.
What is
called a bounty, is sometimes no more than a drawback,
and,
consequently, is not liable to the same objections as what
is
properly a bounty. The bounty, for example, upon refined sugar
exported,
may be considered as a drawback of the duties upon the
brown
and Muscovado sugars, from which it is made; the bounty
upon
wrought silk exported, a drawback of the duties upon raw and
thrown
silk imported; the bounty upon gunpowder exported, a
drawback
of the duties upon brimstone and saltpetre imported. In
the
language of the customs, those allowances only are called
drawbacks
which are given upon goods exported in the same form in
which
they are imported. When that form has been so altered by
manufacture
of any kind as to come under a new denomination, they
are
called bounties.
Premiums
given by the public to artists and manufacturers, who
excel
in their particular occupations, are not liable to the same
objections
as bounties. By encouraging extraordinary dexterity
and
ingenuity, they serve to keep up the emulation of the workmen
actually
employed in those respective occupations, and are not
considerable
enough to turn towards any one of them a greater
share
of the capital of the country than what would go to it of
its own
accord. Their tendency is not to overturn the natural
balance
of employments, but to render the work which is done in
each as
perfect and complete as possible. The expense of
premiums,
besides, is very trifling, that of bounties very great.
The
bounty upon corn alone has sometimes cost the public, in one
year,
more than £300,000.
Bounties
are sometimes called premiums, as drawbacks are
sometimes
called bounties. But we must, in all cases, attend to
the
nature of the thing, without paying any regard to the word.
Digression
concerning the Corn Trade and Corn Laws.
I
cannot conclude this chapter concerning bounties, without
observing,
that the praises which have been bestowed upon the law
which
establishes the bounty upon the exportation of corn, and
upon
that system of regulations which is connected with it, are
altogether
unmerited. A particular examination of the nature of
the
corn trade, and of the principal British laws which relate to
it,
will sufficiently demonstrate the truth of this assertion.
The
great importance of this subject must justify the length of
the
digression.
The
trade of the corn merchant is composed of four different
branches,
which, though they may sometimes be all carried on by
the
same person, are, in their own nature, four separate and
distinct
trades. These are, first, the trade of the inland
dealer;
secondly, that of the merchant-importer for home
consumption
; thirdly, that of the merchant-exporter of home
produce
for foreign consumption ; and, fourthly, that of the
merchant-carrier,
or of the importer of corn, in order to export
it
again.
I. The
interest of the inland dealer, and that of the great body
of the
people, how opposite soever they may at first appear, are,
even in
years of the greatest scarcity, exactly the same. It is
his
interest to raise the price of his corn as high as the real
scarcity
of the season requires, and it can never be his interest
to
raise it higher. By raising the price, he discourages the
consumption,
and puts every body more or less, but particularly
the
inferior ranks of people, upon thrift and good management If,
by
raising it too high, he discourages the consumption so much
that
the supply of the season is likely to go beyond the
consumption
of the season, and to last for some time after the
next
crop begins to come in, he runs the hazard, not only of
losing
a considerable part of his corn by natural causes, but of
being
obliged to sell what remains of it for much less than what
he
might have had for it several months before. If, by not
raising
the price high enough, he discourages the consumption so
little,
that the supply of the season is likely to fall short of
the
consumption of the season, he not only loses a part of the
profit
which he might otherwise have made, but he exposes the
people
to suffer before the end of the season, instead of the
hardships
of a dearth, the dreadful horrors of a famine. It is
the
interest of the people that their daily, weekly, and monthly
consumption
should be proportioned as exactly as possible to the
supply
of the season. The interest of the inland corn dealer is
the
same. By supplying them, as nearly as he can judge, in this
proportion,
he is likely to sell all his corn for the highest
price,
and with the greatest profit ; and his knowledge of the
state
of the crop, and of his daily, weekly, and monthly sales,
enables
him to judge, with more or less accuracy, how far they
really
are supplied in this manner. Without intending the
interest
of the people, he is necessarily led, by a regard to his
own
interest, to treat them, even in years of scarcity, pretty
much in
the same manner as the prudent master of a vessel is
sometimes
obliged to treat his crew. When he foresees that
provisions
are likaly to run short, he puts them upon short
allowance.
Though from excess of caution he should sometimes do
this
without any real necessity, yet all the inconveniencies
which
his crew can thereby suffer are inconsiderable, in
comparison
of the danger, misery, and ruin, to which they might
sometimes
be exposed by a less provident conduct. Though, from
excess
of avarice, in the same manner, the inland corn merchant
should
sometimes raise the price of his corn somewhat higher than
the
scarcity of the season requires, yet all the inconveniencies
which
the people can suffer from this conduct, which effectually
secures
them from a famine in the end of the season, are
inconsiderable,
in comparison of what they might have been
exposed
to by a more liberal way of dealing in the beginning of
it the
corn merchant himself is likely to suffer the most by this
excess
of avarice; not only from the indignation which it
generally
excites against him, but, though he should escape the
effects
of this indignation, from the quantity of corn which it
necessarily
leaves upon his hands in the end of the season, and
which,
if the next season happens to prove favourable, he must
always
sell for a much lower price than he might otherwise have
had.
Were it
possible, indeed, for one great company of merchants to
possess
themselves of the whole crop of an extensive country, it
might
perhaps be their interest to deal with it, as the Dutch are
said to
do with the spiceries of the Moluccas, to destroy or
throw
away a considerable part of it, in order to keep up the
price
of the rest. But it is scarce possible, even by the
violence
of law, to establish such an extensive monopoly with
regard
to corn ; and wherever the law leaves the trade free, it
is of
all commodities the least liable to be engrossed or
monopolized
by the forced a few large capitals, which buy up the
greater
part of it. Not only its value far exceeds what the
capitals
of a few private men are capable of purchasing; but,
supposing
they were capable of purchasing it, the manner in which
it is
produced renders this purchase altogether impracticable.
As, in
every civilized country, it is the commodity of which the
annual
consumption is the greatest ; so a greater quantity of
industry
is annually employed in pruducing corn than in producing
any
other commodity. When it first comes from the ground, too, it
is
necessarily divided among a greater number of owners than any
other
commodity ; and these owners can never be collected into
one
place, like a number of independent manufacturers, but are
necessarily
scattered through all the different corners of the
country.
These first owners either immediately supply the
consumers
in their own neighbourhood, or they supply other inland
dealers,
who supply those consumers. The inland dealers in corn,
therefore,
including both the farmer and the baker, are
necessarily
more numerous than the dealers in any other commodity
; and
their dispersed situation renders it altogether impossible
for
them to enter into any general combination. If, in a year of
scarcity,
therefore, any of them should find that he had a good
deal
more corn upon hand than, at the current price, he could
hope to
dispose of before the end of the season, he would never
think
of keeping up this price to his own loss, and to the sole
benefit
of his rivals and competitors, but would immediately
lower
it, in order to get rid of his corn before the new crop
began
to come in. The same motives, the same interests, which
would
thus regulate the conduct of any one dealer, would regulate
that of
every other, and oblige them all in general to sell their
corn at
the price which, according to the best of their judgment,
was
most suitable to the scarcity or plenty of the season.
Whoever
examines, with attention, the history of the dearths and
famines
which have afflicted any part of Europe during either the
course
of the present or that of the two preceding centuries, of
several
of which we have pretty exact accounts, will find, I
believe,
that a dearth never has arisen from any combination
among
the inland dealers in corn, nor from any other cause but a
real
scarcity, occasioned sometimes, perhaps, and in some
particular
places, by the waste of war, but in by far the
greatest
number of cases by the fault of the seasons; and that a
famine
has never arisen from any other cause but the violence of
government
attempting, by improper means, to remedy the
inconveniencies
of a dearth.
In an
extensive corn country, between all the different parts of
which
there is a free commerce and communication, the scarcity
occasioned
by the most unfavourable seasons can never be so great
as to
produce a famine ; and the scantiest crop, if managed with
frugality
and economy, will maintain, through the year, the same
number
of people that are commonly fed in a more affluent manner
by one
of moderate plenty. The seasons most unfavourable to the
crop
are those of excessive drought or excessive rain. But as
corn
grows equally upon high and low lands, upon grounds that are
disposed
to be too wet, and upon those that are disposed to be
too
dry, either the drought or the rain, which is hurtful to one
part of
the country, is favourable to another ; and though, both
in the
wet and in the dry season, the crop is a good deal less
than in
one more properly tempered ; yet, in both, what is lost
in one
part of the country is in some measure compensated by what
is
gained in the other. In rice countries, where the crop not
only
requires a very moist soil, but where, in a certain period
of its
growing, it must be laid under water, the effects of a
drought
are much more dismal. Even in such countries, however,
the
drought is, perhaps, scarce ever so universal as necessarily
to
occasion a famine, if the government would allow a free trade.
The
drought in Bengal, a few years ago, might probably have
occasioned
a very great dearth. Some improper regulations, some
injudicious
restraints, imposed by the servants of the East India
Company
upon the rice trade, contributed, perhaps, to turn that
dearth
into a famine.
When
the government, in order to remedy the inconveniencies of a
dearth,
orders all the dealers to sell their corn at what it
supposes
a reasonable price, it either hinders them from bringing
it to
market, which may sometimes produce a famine even in the
beginning
of the season ; or, if they bring it thither, it
enables
the people, and thereby encourages them to consume it so
fast as
must necessarily produce a famine before the end of the
season.
The unlimited, unrestrained freedom of the corn trade, as
it is
the only effectual preventive of the miseries of a famine,
so it
is the best palliative of the inconveniencies of a dearth;
for the
inconveniencies of a real scarcity cannot be remedied ;
they
can only be palliated. No trade deserves more the full
protection
of the law, and no trade requires it so much ; because
no
trade is so much exposed to popular odium.
In
years of scarcity, the inferior ranks of people impute their
distress
to the avarice of the corn merchant, who becomes the
object
of their hatred and indignation. Instead of making profit
upon
such occasions, therefore, he is often in danger of being
utterly
ruined, and of having his magazines plundered and
destroyed
by their violence. It is in years of scarcity, however,
when
prices are high, that the corn merchant expects to make his
principal
profit. He is generally in contract with some farmers
to
furnish him, for a certain number of years, with a certain
quantity
of corn, at a certain price. This contract price is
settled
according to what is supposed to be the moderate and
reasonable,
that is, the ordinary or average price, which, before
the
late years of scarcity, was commonly about 28s. for the
quarter
of wheat, and for that of other grain in proportion. In
years
of scarcity, therefore, the corn merchant buys a great part
of his
corn for the ordinary price, and sells it for a much
higher.
That this extraordinary profit, however, is no more than
sufficient
to put his trade upon a fair level with other trades,
and to
compensate the many losses which he sustains upon other
occasions,
both from the perishable nature of the commodity
itself,
and from the frequent and unforeseen fluctuations of its
price,
seems evident enough, from this single circumstance, that
great
fortunes are as seldom made in this as in any other trade.
The
popular odium, however, which attends it in years of
scarcity,
the only years in which it can be very profitable,
renders
people of character and fortune averse to enter into it.
It is
abandoned to an inferior set of dealers; and millers,
bakers,
meal-men, and meal-factors, together with a number of
wretched
hucksters, are almost the only middle people that, in
the
home market, come between the grower and the consumer.
The
ancient policy of Europe, instead of discountenancing this
popular
odium against a trade so beneficial to the public, seems,
on the
contrary, to have authorised and encouraged it.
By the
5th and 6th of Edward VI cap. 14, it was enacted, that
whoever
should buy any corn or grain, with intent to sell it
again,
should be reputed an unlawful engrosser, and should, for
the
first fault, suffer two months imprisonment, and forfeit the
value
of the corn ; for the second, suffer six months
imprisonment,
and forfeit double the value; and, for the third,
be set
in the pillory, suffer imprisonment during the king's
pleasure,
and forfeit all his goods and chattels. The ancient
policy
of most other parts of Europe was no better than that of
England.
Our
ancestors seem to have imagined, that the people would buy
their
corn cheaper of the farmer than of the corn merchant, who,
they
were afraid, would require, over and above the price which
he paid
to the farmer, an exorbitant profit to himself. They
endeavoured,
therefore, to annihilate his trade altogether. They
even
endeavoured to hinder, as much as possible, any middle man
of any
kind from coming in between the grower and the consumer;
and
this was the meaning of the many restraints which they
imposed
upon the trade of those whom they called kidders, or
carriers
of corn ; a trade which nobody was allowed to exercise
without
a licence, ascertaining his qualifications as a man of
probity
and fair dealing. The authority of three justices of the
peace
was, by the statute of Edward VI. necessary in order to
grant
this licence. But even this restraint was afterwards
thought
insufficient, and, by a statute of Elizabeth, the
privilege
of granting it was confined to the quarter-sessions.
The
ancient policy of Europe endeavoured, in this manner, to
regulate
agriculture, the great trade of the country, by maxims
quite
different from those which it established with regard to
manufactures,
the great trade of the towns. By leaving a farmer
no
other customers but either the consumers or their immediate
factors,
the kidders and carriers of corn, it endeavoured to
force
him to exercise the trade, not only of a farmer, but of a
corn
merchant, or corn retailer. On the contrary, it, in many
cases,
prohibited the manufacturer from exercising the trade of a
shopkeeper,
or from selling his own goods by retail. It meant, by
the one
law, to promote the general interest of the country, or
to
render corn cheap, without, perhaps, its being well understood
how
this was to be done. By the other, it meant to promote that
of a
particular order of men, the shopkeepers, who would be so
much
undersold by the manufacturer, it was supposed, that their
trade
would be ruined, if he was allowed to retail at all.
The
manufacturer, however, though he had been allowed to keep a
shop,
and to sell his own goods by retail, could not have
undersold
the common shopkeeper. Whatever part of his capital he
might
have placed in his shop, he must have withdrawn it from his
manufacture.
In order to carry on his business on a level with
that of
other people, as he must have had the profit of a
manufacturer
on the one part, so he must have had that of a
shopkeper
upon the other. Let us suppose, for example, that in
the
particular town where he lived, ten per cent. was the
ordinary
profit both of manufacturing and shopkeeping stock ; he
must in
this case have charged upon every piece of his own goods,
which
he sold in his shop, a profit of twenty per cent. When he
carried
them from his workhouse to his shop, he must have valued
them at
the price for which he could have sold them to a dealer
or
shopkeeper, who would have bought them by wholesale. If he
valued
them lower, he lost a part of the profit of his
manufacturing
capital. When, again, he sold them from his shop,
unless
he got the same price at which a shopkeeper would have
sold
them, he lost a part of the profit of his shop- keeping
capital.
Though he might appear, therefore, to make a double
profit
upon the same piece of goods, yet, as these goods made
successively
a part of two distinct capitals, he made but a
single
profit upon the whole capital employed about them ; and if
he made
less than his profit, he was a loser, and did not employ
his
whole capital with the same advantage as the greater part of
his
neighbours.
What
the manufacturer was prohibited to do, the farmer was in
some
measure enjoined to do ; to divide his capital between two
different
employments; to keep one part of it in his granaries
and
stack-yard, for supplying the occasional demands of the
market,
and to employ the other in the cultivation of his land.
But as
he could not afford to employ the latter for less than the
ordinary
profits of farming stock, so he could as little afford
to
employ the former for less than the ordinary profits of
mercantile
stock. Whether the stock which really carried on the
business
of a corn merchant belonged to the person who was called
a
farmer, or to the person who was called a corn merchant, an
equal
profit was in both cases requisite, in order to indemnify
its
owner for employing it in this manner, in order to put his
business
on a level with other trades, and in order to hinder him
from
having an interest to change it as soon as possible for some
other.
The farmer, therefore, who was thus forced to exercise the
trade
of a corn merchant, could not afford to sell his corn
cheaper
than any other corn merchant would have been obliged to
do in
the case of a free competition.
The
dealer who can employ his whole stock in one single branch of
business,
has an advantage of the same kind with the workman who
can
employ his whole labour in one single operation. As the
latter
acquires a dexterity which enables him, with the same two
hands,
to perform a much greater quantity of work, so the former
acquires
so easy and ready a method of transacting his business,
of
buying and disposing of his goods, that with the same capital
he can
transact a much greater quantity of business. As the one
can
commonly afford his work a good deal cheaper, so the other
can
commonly afford his goods somewhat cheaper, than if his stock
and
attention were both employed about a greater variety of
objects.
The greater part of manufacturers could not afford to
retail
their own goods so cheap as a vigilant and active
shopkeeper,
whose sole business it was to buy them by wholesale
and to
retail them again. The greater part of farmers could still
less
afford to retail their own corn, to supply the inhabitants
of a
town, at perhaps four or five miles distance from the
greater
part of them, so cheap as a vigilant and active corn
merchant,
whose sole business it was to purchase corn by
wholesale,
to collect it into a great magazine, and to retail it
again.
The law
which prohibited the manufacturer from exercising the
trade
of a shopkeeper, endeavoured to force this division in the
employment
of stock to go on faster than it might otherwise have
done.
The law which obliged the farmer to exercise the trade of a
corn
merchant, endeavoured to hinder it from going on so fast.
Both
laws were evident violations of natural liberty, and
therefore
unjust; and they were both, too, as impolitic as they
were
unjust. It is the interest of every society, that things of
this
kind should never either he forced or obstructed. The man
who
employs either his labour or his stock in a greater variety
of ways
than his situation renders necessary, can never hurt his
neighbour
by underselling him. He may hurt himself, and he
generally
does so. Jack-of-all-trades will never be rich, says
the
proverb. But the law ought always to trust people with the
care of
their own interest, as in their local situations they
must
generally he able to judge better of it than the legislature
can do.
The law, however, which obliged the farmer to exercise
the
trade of a corn merchant was by far the most pernicious of
the
two.
It obstructed
not only that division in the employment of stock
which
is so advantageous to every society, but it obstructed
likewise
the improvement and cultivation of the land. By obliging
the
farmer to carry on two trades instead of one, it forced him
to
divide his capital into two parts, of which one only could be
employed
in cultivation. But if he had been at liberty to sell
his
whole crop to a corn mercliant as fast as he could thresh it
out,
his whole capital might have returned immediately to the
land,
and have been employed in buying more cattle, and hiring
more
servants, in order to improve and cultivate it better. But
by
being obliged to sell his corn by retail, he was obliged to
keep a
great part of his capital in his granaries and stack-yard
through
the year, and could not therefore cultivate so well as
with
the same capital he might otherwise have done. This law,
therefore,
necessarily obstructed the improvement of the land,
and,
instead of tending to render corn cheaper, must have tended
to
render it scarcer, and therefore dearer, than it would
otherwise
have been.
After
the business of the farmer, that of the corn merchant is in
reality
the trade which, if properly protected and encouraged,
would
contribute the most to the raising of corn. It would
support
the trade of the farmer, in the same manner as the trade
of the
wholesale dealer supports that of the manufacturer.
The
wholesale dealer, by affording a ready market to the
manufacturer,
by taking his goods off his hand as fast as he can
make
them, and by sometimes even advancing their price to him
before
he has made them, enables him to keep his whole capital,
and
sometimes even more than his whole capital, constantly
employed
in manufacturing, and consequently to manufacture a much
greater
quantity of goods than if he was obliged to dispose of
them
himself to the immediate consumers, or even to the
retailers. As the capital of the wholesale merchant,
too, is
generally
sufficient to replace that of many manufacturers, this
intercourse
between him and them interests the owner of a large
capital
to support the owners of a great number of small ones,
and to
assist them in those losses and misfortunes which might
otherwise
prove ruinous to them.
An
intercourse of the same kind universally established between
the
farmers and the corn merchants, would be attended with
effects
equally beneficial to the farmers. They would be enabled
to keep
their whole capitals, and even more than their whole
capitals
constantly employed in cultivation. In case of any of
those
accidents to which no trade is more liable than theirs,
they
would find in their ordinary customer, the wealthy corn
merchant,
a person who had both an interest to support them, and
the
ability to do it ; and they would not, as at present, be
entirely
dependent upon the forbearance of their landlord, or the
mercy
of his steward. Were it possible, as perhaps it is not, to
establish
this intercourse universally, and all at once ; were it
possible
to turn all at once the whole farming stock of the
kingdom
to its proper business, the cultivation of land,
withdrawing
it from every other employment into which any part of
it may
be at present diverted; and were it possible, in order to
support
and assist, upon occasion, the operations of this great
stock,
to provide all at once another stock almost equally great;
it is
not, perhaps, very easy to imagine how great, how
extensive,
and how sudden, would be the improvement which this
change
of circumstances would alone produce upon the whole face
of the
country.
The
statute of Edward VI. therefore, by prohibiting as much as
possible
any middle man from coming in between the grower and the
consumer,
endeavoured to annihilate a trade, of which the free
exercise
is not only the best palliative of the inconveniencics
of a
dearth, but the best preventive of that calamity ; after the
trade
of the farmer, no trade contributing so much to the growing
of corn
as that of the corn merchant.
The
rigour of this law was afterwards softened by several
subsequent
statutes, which successvely permitted the engrossing
of corn
when the price of wheat should not exceed 20s. and 24s.
32s.
and 40s. the quarter. At last, by the 15th of Charles II.
c.7,
the engrossing or buying of corn, in order to sell it again,
as long
as the price of wheat did not exceed 48s. the quarter,
and
that of other grain in proportion, was declared lawful to all
persons
not being forestallers, that is, not selling again in the
same
market within three months. All the freedom which the trade
of the
inland corn dealer has ever yet enjoyed was bestowed upon
it by
this statute. The statute of the twelfth of the present
king,
which repeals almost all the other ancient laws against
engrossers
and forestallers, does not repeal the restrictions of
this
particular statute, which therefore still continue in force.
This
statute, however, authorises in some measure two very absurd
popular
prejudices.
First, It supposes, that when the price of wheat
has risen so
high as
48s. the quarter, and that of other grain in proportion,
corn is
likely to be so engrossed as to hurt the people. But,
from
what has been already said, it seems evident enough, that
corn
can at no price be so engrossed by the inland dealers as to
hurt
the people; and 48s. the quarter, besides, though it may be
considered
as a very high price, yet, in years of scarcity, it is
a price
which frequently takes place immediately after harvest,
when
scarce any part of the new crop can be sold off, and when it
is
impossible even for ignorance to suppose that any part of it
can be
so engrossed as to hurt the people.
Secondly, It supposes that there is a certain price
at which
corn is
likely to be forestalled, that is, bought up in order to
be sold
again soon after in the same market, so as to hurt the
people.
But if a merchant ever buys up corn, either going to a
particular
market, or in a particular market, in order to sell it
again
soon after in the same market, it must be because he judges
that
the market cannot be so liberally supplied through the whole
season
as upon that particular occasion, and that the price,
therefore,
must soon rise. If he judges wrong in this, and if the
price
does not rise, he not only loses the whole profit of the
stock
which he employs in this manner, but a part of the stock
itself,
by the expense and loss which necessarily attend the
storing
and keeping of corn. He hurts himself, therefore, much
more
essentially than he can hurt even the particular people whom
he may
hinder from supplying themselves upon that particular
market
day, because they may afterwards supply themselves just as
cheap
upon any other market day. If he judges right, instead of
hurting
the great body of the people, he renders them a most
important
service. By making them feel the inconveniencies of a
dearth
somewhat earlier than they otherwise might do, he prevents
their
feeling them afterwads so severely as they certainly would
do, if
the cheapness of price encouraged them to consume faster
than
suited the real scarcity of the season. When the scarcity is
real,
the best thing that can be done for the people is, to
divide
the inconvenience of it as equally as possible, through
all the
different months and weeks and days of the year. The
interest
of the corn merchant makes him study to do this as
exactly
as he can; and as no other person can have either the
same
interest, or the same knowledge, or the same abilities, to
do it
so exactly as he, this most important operation of commerce
ought
to be trusted entirely to him; or, in other words, the corn
trade,
so far at least as concerns the supply of the home market,
ought
to be left perfectly free.
The
popular fear of engrossing and forestalling may be compared
to the
popular terrors and suspicions of witchcraft. The
unfortunate
wretches accused of this latter crime were not more
innocent
of the misfortunes imputed to them, than those who have
been
accused of the former. The law which put an end to all
prosecutions
against witchcraft, which put it out of any man's
power
to gratify his own malice by accusing his neighbour of that
imaginary
crime, seems effectually to have put an end to those
fears
and suspicions, by taking away the great cause which
encouraged
and supported them. The law which would restore entire
freedom
to the inland trade of corn, would probably prove as
effectual
to put an end to the popular fears of engrossing and
forestalling.
The
15th of Charles II. c. 7, however, with all its
imperfections,
has, perhaps, contributed more, both to the
plentiful
supply of the home market, and to the increase of
tillage,
than any other law in the statute book. It is from this
law
that the inland corn trade has derived all the liberty and
protection
which it has ever yet enjoyed ; and both the supply of
the
home market and the interest of tillage are much more
effectually
promoted by the inland, than either by the
importation
or exportation trade.
The
proportion of the average quantity of all sorts of grain
imported
into Great Britain to that of all sorts of grain
consumed,
it has been computed by the author of the Tracts upon
the
Corn Trade, does not exceed that of one to five hundred and
seventy.
For supplying the home market, therefore, the importance
of the
inland trade must be to that of the importation trade as
five
hundred and seventy to one.
The
average quantity of all sorts of grain exported from Great
Britain
does not, according to the same author, exceed the
one-and-thirtieth
part of the annual produce. For the
encouragement
of tillage, therefore, by providing a market for
the
home produce, the importance of the inland trade must be to
that of
the exportation trade as thirty to one.
I have
no great faith in political arithmetic, and I mean not to
warrant
the exactness of either of these computations. I mention
them
only in order to show of how much less consequence, in the
opinion
of the most judicious and experienced persons, the
foreign
trade of corn is than the home trade. The great cheapness
of corn
in the years immediately preceding the establishment of
the
bounty may, perhaps with reason, be ascribed in some measure
to the
operation of this statute of Charles II. which had been
enacted
about five-and-twenty years before, and which had,
therefore,
full time to produce its effect.
A very
few words will sufficiently explain all that I have to say
concerning
the other three branches of the corn trade.
II. The
trade of the merchant-importer of foreign corn for home
consumption,
evidently contributes to the immediate supply of the
home
market, and must so far be immediately beneficial to the
great
body of the people. It tends, indeed, to lower somewhat the
average
money price of corn, but not to diminish its real value,
or the
quantity of labour which it is capable of maintaining. If
importation
was at all times free, our farmers and country
gentlemen
would probably, one year with another, get less money
for
their corn than they do at present, when importation is at
most
times in effect prohibited ; but the money which they got
would
be of more value, would buy more goods of all other kinds,
and
would employ more labour. Their real wealth, their real
revenue,
therefore, would be the same as at present, though it
might
be expressed by a smaller quantity of silver, and they
would
neither be disabled nor discouraged from cultivating corn
as much
as they do at present. On the contrary, as the rise in
the
real value of silver, in consequence of lowering the money
price
of corn, lowers somewhat the money price of all other
commodities,
it gives the industry of the country where it takes
place
some advantage in all foreign markets and thereby tends to
encourage
and increase that industry. But the extent of the home
market
for corn must be in proportion to the general industry of
the
country where it grows, or to the number of those who produce
something
else, and therefore, have something else, or, what
comes
to the same thing, the price of something else, to give in
exchange
for corn. But in every country, the home market, as it
is the
nearest and most convenient, so is it likewise the
greatest
and most important market for corn. That rise in the
real
value of silver, therefore, which is the effect of lowering
the
average money price of corn, tends to enlarge the greatest
and
most important market for corn, and thereby to encourage,
instead
of discouraging its growth.
By the
22d of Charles II. c. 13, the importation of wheat,
whenever
the price in the home market did not exceed 53s:4d. the
quarter,
was subjected to a duty of 16s. the quarter; and to a
duty of
8s. whenever the price did not exceed £4. The former of
these
two prices has, for more than a century past, taken place
only in
times of very great scarcity ; and the latter has, so far
as I
know, not taken place at all. Yet, till wheat has risen
above
this latter price, it was, by this statute, subjected to a
very
high duty; and, till it had risen above the former, to a
duty
which amounted to a prohibition. The importation of other
sorts
of grain was restrained at rates and by duties, in
proportion
to the value of the grain, almost equally high. Before
the
13th of the present king, the following were the duties
payable
upon the importation of the different sorts of grain :
Grain. Duties. Duties
Duties.
Beans
to 28s. per qr. 19s:10d. after till
40s. 16s:8d. then 12d.
Barley
to 28s. - 19s:10d. - 32s. 16s. - 12d.
Malt is
prohibited by the annual malt-tax bill.
Oats to 16s.
- 5s:10d after - 9½d.
Pease to 40s.
- 16s: 0d.after - 9¾d.
Rye to 36s.
- 19s:10d. till 40s. 16s:8d - 12d.
Wheat
to 44s. - 21s: 9d. till 53s:4d.
17s. - 8s.
till £4, and after
that about 1s:4d.
Buck-wheat
to 32s. per qr. to pay 16s.
These
different duties were imposed, partly by the 22d of Charles
II. in
place of the old subsidy, partly by the new subsidy, by
the
one-third and two-thirds subsidy, and by the subsidy 1747.
Subsequent
laws still further increased those duties.
The
distress which, in years of scarcity, the strict execution of
those
laws might have brought upon the people, would probably
have
been very great ; but, upon such occasions, its execution
was
generally suspended by temporary statutes, which permitted,
for a
limited time, the importation of foreign corn. The
necessity
of these temporary statutes sufficiently demonstrates
the
impropriety of this general one.
These
restraints upon importation, though prior to the
establishment
of the bounty, were dictated by the same spirit, by
the
same principles, which afterwards enacted that regulation.
How
hurtful soever in themselves, these, or some other restraints
upon
importation, became necessary in consequence of that
regulation.
If, when wheat was either below 48s. the quarter, or
not
much above it, foreign corn could have been imported, either
duty
free, or upon paying only a small duty, it might have been
exported
again, with the benefit of the bounty, to the great loss
of the
public revenue, and to the entire perversion of the
institution,
of which the object was to extend the market for the
home
growth, not that for the growth of foreign countries.
III.
The trade of the merchant-exporter of corn for foreign
consumption,
certainly does not contribute directly to the
plentiful
supply of the home market. It does so, however,
indirectly.
From whatever source this supply maybe usually drawn,
whether
from home growth, or from foreign importation, unless
more
corn is either usually grown, or usually imported into the
country,
than what is usually consumed in it. the supply of the
home
market can never be very plentiful. But unless the surplus
can, in
all ordinary cases, be exported, the growers will be
careful
never to grow more, and the importers never to import
more,
than what the bare consumption of the home market requires.
That
market will very seldom be overstocked; but it will
generally
be understocked ; the people, whose business it is to
supply
it, being generally afraid lest their goods should be left
upon
their hands. The prohibition of exportation limits the
improvement
and cultivation of the country to what the supply of
its own
inhabitants require. The freedom of exportation enables
it to
extend cultivation for the supply of foreign nations.
By the
12th of Charles II. c.4, the exportation of corn was
permitted
whenever the price of wheat did not exceed 40s. the
quarter,
and that of other grain in proportion. By the 15th of
the
same prince, this liberty was extended till the price of
wheat
exceeded 48s. the quarter; and by the 22d, to all higher
prices.
A poundage, indeed, was to be paid to the king upon such
exportation;
but all grain was rated so low in the book of rates,
that
this poundage amounted only, upon wheat to 1s., upon oats to
4d.,
and upon all other grain to 6d. the quarter. By the 1st of
William
and Mary, the act which established this bounty, this
small
duty was virtually taken off whenever the price of wheat
did not
exceed 48s. the quarter; and by the 11th and 12th of
William
III. c. 20, it was expressly taken off at all higher
prices.
The
trade of the merchant-exporter was, in this manner, not only
encouraged
by a bounty, but rendered much more free than that of
the
inland dealer. By the last of these statutes, corn could be
engrossed
at any price for exportation ; but it could not be
engrossed
for inland sale, except when the price did not exceed
48s.
the quarter. The interest of the inland dealer, however, it
has
already been shown, can never be opposite to that of the
great
body of the people. That of the merchant-exporter may, and
in fact
sometimes is. If, while his own country labours under a
dearth,
a neighbouring country should be afflicted with a famine,
it
might be his interest to carry corn to the latter country, in
such
quantities as might very much aggravate the calamities of
the
dearth. The plentiful supply of the home market was not the
direct
object of those statutes; but, under the pretence of
encouraging
agriculture, to raise the money price of corn as high
as
possible, and thereby to occasion, as much as possible, a
constant
dearth in the home market. By the discouragement of
importation,
the supply of that market; even in times of great
scarcity,
was confined to the home growth ; and by the
encouragement
of exportation, when the price was so high as 48s.
the
quarter, that market was not, even in times of considerable
scarcity,
allowed to enjoy the whole of that growth. The
temporary
laws, prohibiting, for a limited time, the exportation
of
corn, and taking off, for a limited time, the duties upon its
importation,
expedients to which Great Britain has been obliged
so
frequently to have recourse, sufficiently demonstrate the
impropriety
of her general system. Had that system been good, she
would
not so frequently have been reduced to the necessity of
departing
from it.
Were
all nations to follow the liberal system of free exportation
and
free importation, the different states into which a great
continent
was divided, would so far resemble the different
provinces
of a great empire. As among the different provinces of
a great
empire, the freedmn of the inland trade appears, both
from
reason and experience, not only the best palliative of a
dearth,
but the most effectual preventive of a famine; so would
the
freedom of the exportation and importation trade be among the
different
states into which a great continent was divided. The
larger
the continent, the easier the communication through all
the
different parts of it, both by land and by water, the less
would
any one particular part of it ever be exposed to either of
these
calamities, the scarcity of any one country being more
likely
to be relieved by the plenty of some other. But very few
countries
have entirely adopted this liberal system. The freedom
of the
corn trade is almost everywhere more or less restrained,
and in
many countries is confined by such absurd regulations, as
frequently
aggravate the unavoidable misfortune of a dearth into
the
dreadful calamity of a famine. The demand of such countries
for
corn may frequently become so great and so urgent, that a
small
state in their neighbourhood, which happened at the same
time to
be labouring under some degree of dearth, could not
venture
to supply them without exposing itself to the like
dreadful
calamity. The very bad policy of one country may thus
render
it, in some measure, dangerous and imprudent to establish
what
would otherwise be the best policy in another. The unlimited
freedom
of exportation, however, would be much less dangerous in
great
states, in which the growth being much greater, the supply
could
seldom be much affected by any quantity or corn that was
likely
to he exported. In a Swiss canton, or in some of the
little
states in Italy, it may, perhaps, sometimes be necessary
to
restrain the exportation of corn. In such great countries as
France
or England, it scarce ever can. To hinder, besides, the
farmer
from sending his goods at all times to the best market, is
evidently
to sacrifice the ordinary laws of justice to an idea of
public
utility, to a sort of reasons of state ; an act or
legislative
authority which ought to be exercised only, which can
be
pardoned only, in cases of the most urgent necessity. The
price
at which exportation of corn is prohibited, if it is ever
to be
prohibited, ought always to be a very high price.
The
laws concerning corn may everywhere be compared to the laws
concerning
religion. The people feel themselves so much
interested
in what relates either to their subsistence in this
life,
or to their happiness in a life to come, that government
must
yield to their prejudices, and, in order to preserve the
public
tranquillity, establish that system which they approve of.
It is
upon this account, perhaps. that we so seldom find a
reasonable
system established with regard to either of those two
capital
objects.
IV. The
trade of the merchant-carrier, or of the importer of
foreign
corn, in order to export it again, contributes to the
plentiful
supply of the home market. It is not, indeed, the
direct
purpose of his trade to sell his corn there ; but he will
generally
be willing to do so, and even for a good deal less
money
than he might expect in a foreign market; because he saves
in this
manner the expense of loading and unloading, of freight
and
insurance. The inhabitants of the country which, by means of
the
carrying trade, becomes the magazine and storehouse for the
supply
of other countries, can very seldom be in want themselves.
Though
the carrying trade must thus contribute to reduce the
average
money price of corn in the home market, it would not
thereby
lower its real value; it would only raise somewhat the
real
value of silver.
The
carrying trade was in effect prohibited in Great Britain,
upon all
ordinary occasions, by the high duties upon the
importation
of foreign corn, of the greater part of which there
was no
drawback; and upon extraordinary occasions, when a
scarcity
made it necessary to suspend those duties by temporary
statutes,
exportation was always prohibited. By this system of
laws,
therefore, the carrying trade was in effect prohibited.
That
system of laws, therefore, which is connected with the
establishment
of the bounty, seems to deserve no part of the
praise
which has been bestowed upon it. The improvement and
prosperity
of Great Britain, which has been so often ascribed to
those
laws, may very easily be accounted for by other causes.
That
security which the laws in Great Britain give to every man,
that he
shall enjoy the fruits of his own labour, is alone
sufficient
to make any country flourish, notwithstanding these
and
twenty other absurd regulations of commerce ; and this
security
was perfected by the Revolution, much about the same
time
that the bounty was established. The natural effort of every
individual
to better his own condition, when suffered to exert
itself
with freedom and security, is so powerful a principle,
that it
is alone, and without any assistance, not only capable of
carrying
on the society to wealth and prosperity, but of
surmounting
a hundred impertinent obstructions, with which the
folly
of human laws too often encumbers its operations: though
the
effect of those obstructions is always, more or less, either
to
encroach upon its freedom, or to diminish its security. In
Great
Britain industry is perfectly secure; and though it is far
from
being perfectly free, it is as free or freer than in any
other
part of Europe.
Though
the period of the greatest prosperity and improvement of
Great
Britain has been posterior to that system of laws which is
connected
with the bounty, we must not upon that account, impute
it to
those laws. It has been posterior likewise to the national
debt ;
but the national debt has most assuredly not been the
cause
of it.
Though
the system of laws which is connected with the bounty, has
exactly
the same tendency with the practice of Spain and
Portugal,
to lower somewhat the value of the precious metals in
the
country where it takes place; yet Great Britain is certainly
one of
the richest countries in Europe, while Spain and Portugal
are
perhaps amongst the most beggarly. This difference of
situation,
however, may easily be accounted for from two
different
causes. First, the tax in Spain, the prohibition in
Portugal
of exporting gold and silver, and the vigilant police
which
watches over the execution of those laws, must, in two very
poor
countries, which between them import annually upwards of six
millions
sterling, operate not only more directly, but much more
forcibly,
in reducing the value of those metals there, than the
corn
laws can do in Great Britain. And, secondly, this bad policy
is not
in those countries counterbalanced by the general liberty
and
security of the people. Industry is there neither free nor
secure;
and the civil and ecclesiastical governments of both
Spain
and Portugal are such as would alone be sufficient to
perpetuate
their present state of poverty, even though their
regulations
of commerce were as wise as the greatest part of them
are
absurd and foolish.
The
13th of the present king, c. 43, seems to have established a
new
system with regard to the corn laws, in many respects better
than
the ancient one, but in one or two respects perhaps not
quite
so good.
By this
statute, the high duties upon importation for home
consumption
are taken off, so soon as the price of middling wheat
rises
to 48s. the quarter; that of middling rye, pease, or beans,
to
32s.; that of barley to 24s. ; and that of oats to 16s. ; and
instead
of them, a small duty is imposed of only 6d upon the
quarter
of wheat, and upon that or other grain in proportion.
With
regard to all those different sorts of grain, but
particularly
with regard to wheat, the home market is thus opened
to
foreign supplies, at prices considerably lower than before.
By the
same statute, the old bounty of 5s. upon the exportation
of
wheat, ceases so soon as the price rises to 44s. the quarter,
instead
of 48s. the price at which it ceased before; that of
2s:6d.
upon the exportation of barley, ceases so soon as the
price
rises to 22s. instead of 24s. the price at which it ceased
before
; that of 2s:6d. upon the exportation of oatmeal, ceases
so soon
as the price rises to 14s. instead of 15s. the price at
which
it ceased before. The bounty upon rye is reduced from
3s:6d.
to 3s. and it ceases so soon as the price rises to 28s.
instead
of 32s. the price at which it ceased before. If bounties
are as
improper as I have endeavoured to prove them to be, the
sooner
they cease, and the lower they are, so much the better.
The
same statute permits, at the lowest prices, the importation
of corn
in order to be exported again, duty free, provided it is
in the
mean time lodged in a warehouse under the joint locks of
the
king and the importer. This liberty, indeed, extends to no
more
than twenty-five of the different ports of Great Britain.
They
are, however, the principal ones; and there may not,
perhaps,
be warehouses proper for this purpose in the greater
part of
the others.
So far
this law seems evidently an improvement upon the ancient
system.
But by
the same law, a bounty of 2s. the quarter is given for the
exportation
of oats, whenever the price does not exceed fourteen
shillings.
No bounty had ever been given before for the
exportation
of this grain, no more than for that of pease or
beans.
By the
same law, too, the exportation of wheat is prohibited so
soon as
the price rises to forty-four shillings the quarter; that
of rye
so soon as it rises to twenty-eight shillings; that of
barley
so soon as it rises to twenty-two shillings ; and that of
oats so
soon as they rise to fourteen shillings. Those several
prices
seem all of them a good deal too low; and there seems to
be an
impropriety, besides, in prohibiting exportation altogether
at
those precise prices at which that bounty, which was given in
order
to force it, is withdrawn. The bounty ought certainly
either
to have been withdrawn at a much lower price, or
exportation
ought to have been allowed at a much higher.
So far,
therefore, this law seems to be inferior to the ancient
system.
With all its imperfections, however, we may perhaps say
of it
what was said of the laws of Solon, that though not the
best in
itself, it is the best which the interest, prejudices,
and
temper of the times, would admit of. It may perhaps in due
time
prepare the way for a better.
CHAPTER VI.
OF
TREATIES OF COMMERCE.
When a
nation binds itself by treaty, either to permit the entry
of
certain goods from one foreign country which it prohibits from
all
others, or to exempt the goods of one country from duties to
which
it subjects those of all others, the country, or at least
the
merchants and manufacturers of the country, whose commerce is
so
favoured, must necessarily derive great advantage from the
treaty.
Those merchants and manufacturers enjoy a sort of
monopoly
in the country which is so indulgent to them. That
country
becomes a market, both more extensive and more
advantageous
for their goods: more extensive, because the goods
of
other nations being either excluded or subjected to heavier
duties,
it takes off a greater quantity of theirs; more
advantageous,
because the merchants of the favoured country,
enjoying
a sort of monopoly there, will often sell their goods
for a
better price than if exposed to the free competition of all
other
nations.
Such
treaties, however, though they may be advantageous to the
merchants
and manufacturers of the favoured, are necessarily
disadvantageous
to those of the favouring country. A monopoly is
thus
granted against them to a foreign nation; and they must
frequently
buy the foreign goods they have occasion for, dearer
than if
the free competition of other nations was admitted. That
part of
its own produce with which such a nation purchases
foreign
goods, must consequently be sold cheaper; because, when
two
things are exchanged for one another, the cheapness of the
one is
a necessary consequence, or rather is the same thing, with
the
dearness of the other. The exchangeable value of its annual
produce,
therefore. is likely to be diminished by every such
treaty.
This diminution, however, can scarce amount to any
positive
loss, but only to a lessening of the gain which it might
otherwise
make. Though it sells its goods cheaper than it
otherwise
might do, it will not probably sell them for less than
they
cost; nor, as in the case of bounties, for a price which
will
not replace the capital employed in bringing them to market,
together
with the ordinary profits of stock. The trade could not
go on
long if it did. Even the favouring country, therefore, may
still
gain by the trade, though less than if there was a free
competition.
Some
treaties of commerce, however, have been supposed
advantageous,
upon principles very different from these; and a
commercial
country has sometimes granted a monopoly of this kind,
against
itself, to certain goods of a foreign nation, because it
expected,
that in the whole commerce between them, it would
annually
sell more than it would buy, and that a balance in gold
and
silver would be annually returned to it. It is upon this
principle
that the treaty of commerce between England and
Portugal,
concluded in 1703 by Mr Methuen, has been so much
commended.
The following is a literal translation of that treaty,
which
consists of three articles only.
ART. I.
His
sacred royal majesty of Portugal promises, both in his own
name
and that of his successors, to admit for ever hereafter,
into
Portugal, the woollen cloths, and the rest of the woollen
manufactures
of the British, as was accustomed, till they were
prohibited
by the law ; nevertheless upon this condition :
ART. II.
That is
to say, that her sacred royal majesty of Great Britain
shall,
in her own name, and that of her successors, be obliged,
for
ever hereafter, to admit the wines of the growth of Portugal
into
Britain; so that at no time, whether there shall be peace or
war
between the kingdoms of Britain and France, any thing more
shall
be demanded for these wines by the name of custom or duty,
or by
whatsoever other title, directly or indirectly, whether
they
shall be imported into Great Britain in pipes or hogsheads,
or
other casks, than what shall be demanded for the like quantity
or
measure of French wine, deducting or abating a third part of
the
custom or duty. But if, at any time, this deduction or
abatement
of customs, which is to be made as aforesaid, shall in
any
manner be attempted and prejudiced, it shall be just and
lawful
for his sacred royal majesty of Portugal, again to
prohibit
the woollen cloths, and the rest of the British woollen
manufactures.
ART. III.
The
most excellent lords the plenipotentiaries promise and take
upon themselves,
that their above named masters shall ratify this
treaty;
and within the space of two months the ratification shall
be
exchanged.
By this
treaty, the crown of Portugal becomes bound to admit the
English
woollens upon the same footing as before the prohibition;
that
is, not to raise the duties which had been paid before that
time.
But it does not become bound to admit them upon any better
terms
than those of any other nation, of France or Holland, for
example.
The crown of Great Britain, on the contrary, becomes
bound
to admit the wines of Portugal, upon paying only two-thirds
of the
duty which is paid for those of France, the wines most
likely
to come into competition with them. So far this treaty,
therefore,
is evidently advantageous to Portugal, and
disadvantageous
to Great Britain.
It has
been celebrated, however, as a masterpiece of the
commercial
policy of England. Portugal receives annually from the
Brazils
a greater quantity of gold than can be employed in its
domestic
commerce, whether in the shape of coin or of plate. The
surplus
is too valuable to be allowed to lie idle and locked up
in
coffers; and as it can find no advantageous market at home, it
must,
notwithstanding; any prohibition, be sent abroad, and
exchanged
for something for which there is a more advantageous
market
at home. A large share of it comes annually to England, in
return
either for English goods, or for those of other European
nations
that receive their returns through England. Mr Barretti
was
informed, that the weekly packet-boat from Lisbon brings, one
week
with another, more than £50,000 in gold to England. The sum
had
probably been exaggerated. It would amount to more than
£2,600,000
a. year, which is more than the Brazils are supposed
to
afford.
Our
merchants were, some years ago, out of humour with the crown
of
Portugal. Some privileges which had been granted them, not by
treaty,
but by the free grace of that crown, at the solicitation,
indeed,
it is probable, and in return for much greater favours,
defence
and protection from the crown of Great Britain, had been
either
infringed or revoked. The people, therefore, usually most
interested
in celebrating the Portugal trade, were then rather
disposed
to represent it as less advantageous than it had
commonly
been imagined. The far greater part, almost the whole,
they
pretended, of this annual importation of gold, was not on
account
of Great Britain, but of other European nations; the
fruits
and wines of Portugal annually imported into Great Britain
nearly
compensating the value of the British goods sent thither.
Let us
suppose, however, that the whole was on account of Great
Britain,
and that it amounted to a still greater sum than Mr
Barretti
seems to imagine ; this trade would not, upon that
account,
be more advantageous than any other, in which, for the
same
value sent out, we received an equal value of consumable
goods
in return.
It is
but a very small part of this importation which, it can be
supposed,
is employed as an annual addition, either to the plate
or to
the coin of the kingdom. The rest must all be sent abroad,
and
exchanged for consumable goods of some kind or other. But if
those
consumable goods were purchased directly with the produce
of
English industry, it would be more for the advantage of
England,
than first to purchase with that produce the gold of
Portugal,
and afterwards to purchase with that gold those
consumable
goods. A direct foreign trade of consumption is always
more
advantageous than a round-about one; and to bring the same
value
of foreign goods to the home market requires a much smaller
capital
in the one way than in the ether. If a smaller share of
its
industry, therefore, had been enmloyed in producing goods fit
for the
Portugal market, and a greater in producing those lit for
the
other markets, where those consumable goods for which there
is a
demand in Great Britain are to be had, it would have been
more
for the advantage of England. To procure both the gold which
it wants
for its own use, and the consumable goods, would, in
this
way, employ a much smaller capital than at present. There
would
be a spare capital, therefore, to be employed for other
purposes,
in exciting an additional quantity of industry, and in
raising
a greater annual produce.
Though
Britain were entirely excluded from the Portugal trade, it
could
find very little difficulty in procuring all the annual
supplies
of gold which it wants, either for the purposes of
plate,
or of coin, or of foreign trade. Gold, like every other
commodity,
is always somewhere or another to be got for its value
by
those who have that value to give for it. The annual surplus
of gold
in Portugal, besides, would still be sent abroad, and
though
not carried away by Great Britain, would be carried away
by some
other nation, which would be glad to sell it again for
its
price, in the same manner as Great Britain does at present.
In
buying gold of Portugal, indeed, we buy it at the first hand ;
whereas,
in buying it of any other nation, except Spain, we
should
buy it at the second, and might pay somewhat dearer. This
difference,
however, would surely be too insignificant to deserve
the
public attention.
Almost
all our gold, it is said, comes from Portugal. With other
nations,
the balance of trade is either against as, or not much
in our
favour. But we should remember, that the more gold we
import
from one country, the less we must necessarily import from
all
others. The effectual demand for gold, like that for every
other
commodity, is in every country limited to a certain
quantity.
If nine-tenths of this quantity are imported from one
country,
there remains a tenth only to be imported from all
others.
The more gold, besides, that is annually imported from
some
particular countries, over and above what is requisite for
plate
and for coin, the more must necessarily be exported to some
others:
and the more that most insignificant object of modern
policy,
the balance of trade, appears to be in our favour with
some
particular countries, the more it must necessarily appear to
be
against us with many others.
It was
upon this silly notion, however, that England could not
subsist
without the Portugal trade, that, towards the end of the
late
war, France and Spain, without pretending either offence or
provocation,
required the king of Portugal to exclude all British
ships
from his ports, and, for the security of this exclusion, to
receive
into them French or Spanish garrisons. Had the king of
Portugal
submitted to those ignominious terms which his
brother-in-law
the king of Spain proposed to him, Britain would
have
been freed from a much greater inconveniency than the loss
of the
Portugal trade, the burden of supporting a very weak ally,
so
unprovided of every thing for his own defence, that the whole
power
of England, had it been directed to that single purpose,
could
scarce, perhaps, have defended him for another campaign.
The
loss of the Portugal trade would, no doubt, have occasioned a
considerable
embarrassment to the merchants at that time engaged
in it,
who might not, perhaps, have found out, for a year or two,
any
other equally advantageous method of employing their
capitals;
and in this would probably have consisted all the
inconveniency
which England could have suffered from this notable
piece
of commercial policy.
The
great annual importation of gold and silver is neither for
the
purpose of plate nor of coin, but of foreign trade. A
round-about
foreign trade of consumption can be carried on more
advantageously
by means of these metals than of almost any other
goods.
As they are the universal instruments of commerce, they
are
more readily received in return for all commodities than any
other
goods ; and, on account of their small bulk and great
value,
it costs less to transport them backward and forward from
one
place to another than almost any other sort of merchandize,
and
they lose less of their value by being so transported. Of all
the
commodities, therefore, which are bought in one foreign
country,
for no other purpose but to be sold or exchanged again
for
some other goods in another, there are none so convenient as
gold
and silver. In facilitating all the different round-about
foreign
trades of consumption which are carried on in Great
Britain,
consists the principal advantage of the Portugal trade;
and
though it is not a capital advantage, it is, no doubt, a
considerable
one.
That
any annual addition which, it can reasonably be supposed, is
made
either to the plate or to the coin of the kingdom, could
require
but a very small annual importation of gold and silver,
seems
evident enough; and though we had no direct trade with
Portugal,
this small quantity could always, somewhere or another,
be very
easily got.
Though
the goldsmiths trade be very considerable in Great
Britain,
the far greater part of the new plate which they
annually
sell, is made from other old plate melted down ; so that
the
addition annually made to the whole plate of the kingdom
cannot
be very great, and could require but a very small annual
importation.
It is
the same case with the coin. Nobody imagines, I beileve,
that
even the greater part of the annual coinage, amounting, for
ten
years together, before the late reformation of the gold coin,
to
upwards of £800,000 a-year in gold, was an annual addition to
the
money before current in the kingdom. In a country where the
expense
of the coinage is defrayed by the government, the value
of the
coin, even when it contains its full standard weight of
gold
and silver, can never be much greater than that of an equal
quantity
of those metals uncoined, because it requires only the
trouble
of going to the mint, and the delay, perhaps, of a few
weeks,
to procure for any quantity of uncoined gold and silver an
equal
quantity of those metals in coin; but in every country the
greater
part of the current coin is almost always more or less
worn,
or otherwise degenerated from its standard. In Great
Britain
it was, before the late reformation, a good deal so, the
gold
being more than two per cent., and the silver more than
eight
per cent. below its standard weight. But if forty-four
guineas
and a-half, containing their full standard weight, a
pound
weight of gold, could purchase very little more than a
pound
weight of uncoined gold; forty-four guineas and a-half,
wanting
a part of their weight, could not purchase a pound
weight,
and something was to be added, in order to make up the
deficiency.
The current price of gold bullion at market,
therefore,
instead of being the same with the mint price, or
£46:14:6,
was then about £47:14s., and sometimes about £48. When
the
greater part of the coin, however, was in this degenerate
condition,
forty four guineas and a-half, fresh from the mint,
would
purchase no more goods in the market than any other
ordinary
guineas; because, when they came into the coffers of the
merchant,
being confounded with other money, they could not
afterwards
be distinguished without more trouble than the
difference
was worth. Like other guineas, they were worth no more
than
£46:14:6. If thrown into the melting pot, however, they
produced,
without any sensible loss, a pound weight of standard
gold,
which could be sold at any time for between £47:14s. and
£48,
either in gold or silver, as fit for all the purposes of
coin as
that which had been melted down. There was an evident
profit,
therefore, in melting down new-coined money; and it was
done so
instantaneously, that no precaution of government could
prevent
it. The operations of the mint were, upon this account,
somewhat
like the web of Penelope; the work that was done in the
day was
undone in the night. The mint was employed, not so much
in
making daily additions to the coin, as in replacing the very
best
part of it, which was daily melted down.
Were
the private people who carry their gold and silver to the
mint to
pay themselves for the coinage, it would add to the value
of
those metals, in the same manner as the fashion does to that
of plate.
Coined gold and silver would be more valuable than
uncoined.
The seignorage, if it was not exorbitant, would add to
the
bullion the whole value of the duty; because, the government
having
everywhere the exclusive privilege of coining, no coin can
come to
market cheaper than they think proper to afford it. If
the
duty was exorbitant, indeed, that is, if it was very much
above
the real value of the labour and expense requisite for
coinage,
false coiners, both at home and abroad, might be
encouraged,
by the great difference between the value of bullion
and
that of coin, to pour in so great a quantity of counterfeit
money
as might reduce the value of the government money. In
France,
however, though the seignorage is eight per cent., no
sensible
inconveniency of this kind is found to arise from it.
The
dangers to which a false coiner is everywhere exposed, if he
lives
in the country of which he counterfeits the coin, and to
which
his agents or correspondents are exposed, if he lives in a
foreign
country, are by far too great to be incurred for the sake
of a
profit of six or seven per cent.
The
seignorage in France raises the value of the coin higher than
in
proportion to the quantity of pure gold which it contains.
Thus,
by the edict of January 1726, the mint price of fine gold
of
twenty-four carats was fixed at seven hundred and forty livres
nine
sous and one denier one-eleventh the mark of eight Paris
ounces.
{See Dictionnaire des Monnoies, tom. ii. article
Seigneurage,
p. 439, par 81. Abbot de Bazinghen,
Conseiller-Commissaire
en la Cour des Monnoies à Paris.} The gold
coin of
France, making an allowance for the remedy of the mint,
contains
twenty-one carats and three-fourths of fine gold, and
two
carats one-fourth of alloy. The mark of standard gold,
therefore,
is worth no more than about six hundred and
seventy-one
livres ten deniers. But in France this mark of
standard
gold is coined into thirty louis d'ors of twenty-four
livres
each, or into seven hundred and twenty livres. The coin.
age,
therefore, increases the value of a mark of standard gold
bullion,
by the difference between six hundred and seventy-one
livres
ten deniers and seven hundred and twenty livres, or by
forty-eight
livres nineteen sous and two deniers.
A
seignorage will, in many cases, take away altogether, and will
in all
cases diminish, the profit of melting down the new coin.
This
profit always arises from the difference between the
quantity
of bullion which the common currency ought to contain
and
that which it actually does contain. If this difference is
less
than the seignorage, there will be loss instead of profit.
If it
is equal to the seignorage, there will be neither profit
nor
loss. If it is greater than the seignorage, there will,
indeed,
be some profit, but less than if there was no seignorage.
If,
before the late reformation of the gold coin, for example,
there
had been a seignorage of five per cent. upon the coinage,
there
would have been a loss of three per cent. upon the melting
down of
the gold coin. If the seignorage had been two per cent.,
there
would have been neither profit nor loss. If the seignorage
had
been one per cent., there would have been a profit but of one
per
cent. only, instead of two per cent. Wherever money is
received
by tale, therefore, and not by weight, a seignorage is
the
most effectual preventive of the melting down of the coin,
and,
for the same reason, of its exportaticn. It is the best and
heaviest
pieces that are commonly either melted down or exported,
because
it is upon such that the largest profits are made.
The law
for the encouragement of the coinage, by rendering it
duty-free,
was first enacted during the reign of Charles II. for
a
limited time, and afterwards continued, by different
prolongations,
till 1769, when it was rendered perpetual. The
bank of
England, in order to replenish their coffers with money,
are
frequently obliged to carry bullion to the mint ; and it was
more
for their interest, they probably imagined, that the coinage
should
be at the expense of the government than at their own. It
was
probably out of complaisance to this great company, that the
government
agreed to render this law perpetual. Should the custom
of
weighing gold, however, come to be disused, as it is very
likely
to be on account of its inconveniency ; should the gold
coin of
England come to be received by tale, as it was before the
late
recoinage this great company may, perhaps, find that they
have,
upon this, as upon some other occasions, mistaken their own
interest
not a little.
Before
the late recoinage, when the gold currency of England was
two per
cent. below its standard weight, as there was no
seignorage,
it was two per cent. below the value of that quantity
of
standard gold bullion which it ought to have contained. When
this
great company, therefore, bought gold bullion in order to
have it
coined, they were obliged to pay for it two per cent.
more
than it was worth after the coinage. But if there had been a
seignorage
of two per cent. upon the coinage, the common gold
currency,
though two per cent. below its standard weight, would,
notwithstanding,
have been equal in value to the quantity of
standard
gold which it ought to have contained ; the value of the
fashion
compensating in this case the diminution of the weight.
They
would, indeed, have had the seignorage to pay, which being
two per
cent., their loss upon the whole transaction would have
been
two per cent., exactly the same, but no greater than it
actually
was.
If the
seignorage had been five per cent. and the gold currency
only
two per cent. below its standard weight, the bank would, in
this
case, have gained three per cent. upon the price of the
bullion
; but as they would have had a seignorage of five per
cent.
to pay upon the coinage, their loss upon the whole
transaction
would, in the same manner, have been exactly two per
cent.
If the
seignorage had been only one per cent., and the gold
currency
two per cent. below its standard weight, the bank would,
in this
case, have lost only one per cent. upon the price of the
bullion;
but as they would likewise have had a seignorage of one
per
cent. to pay, their loss upon the whole transaction would
have
been exactly two per cent., in the same manner as in all
other
cases.
If
there was a reasonable seignorage, while at the same time the
coin
contained its full standard weight, as it has done very
nearly
since the late recoinage, whatever the bank might lose by
the
seignorage, they would gain upon the price of the bullion;
and
whatever they might gain upon the price of the bullion, they
would
lose by the seignorage. They would neither lose nor gain,
therefore,
upon the whole transaction, and they would in this, as
in all
the foregoing cases, be exactly in the same situation as
if
there was no seignorage.
When
the tax upon a commodity is so moderate as not to encourage
smuggling,
the merchant who deals in it, though he advances, does
not
properly pay the tax, as he gets it back in the price of the
commodity.
The tax is finally paid by the last purchaser or
consumer.
But money is a commodity, with regard to which every
man is
a merchant. Nobody buys it but in order to sell it again;
and
with regard to it there is, in ordinary cases, no last
purchaser
or consumer. When the tax upon coinage, therefore, is
so
moderate as not to encourage false coining, though every body
advances
the tax, nobody finally pays it; because every body gets
it back
in the advanced value of the coin.
A
moderate seignorage, therefore, would not, in any case, augment
the
expense of the bank, or of any other private persons who
carry
their bullion to the mint in order to be coined; and the
want of
a moderate seignonage does not in any case diminish it.
Whether
there is or is not a seignorage, if the currency contains
its
full standard weight, the coinage costs nothing to anybody ;
and if
it is short of that weight, the coinage must always cost
the
difference between the quantity of bullion which ought to be
contained
in it, and that which actually is contained in it.
The
government, therefore, when it defrays the expense of
coinage,
not only incurs some small expense, but loses some small
revenue
which it might get by a proper duty; and neither the
bank,
nor any other private persons, are in the smallest degree
benefited
by this useless piece of public generosity.
The
directors of the bank, however, would probably be unwilling
to
agree to the impositon of a seignorage upon the authority of a
speculation
which promises them no gain, but only pretends to
insure
them from any loss. In the present state of the gold coin,
and as
long as it continues to be received by weight, they
certainly
would gain nothing by such a change. But if the custom
of weighing
the gold coin should ever go into disuse, as it is
very
likely to do, and if the gold coin should ever fall into the
same
state of degradation in which it was before the late
recoinage,
the gain, or more properly the savings, of the bank,
inconsequence
of the imposition of a seignorage, would probably
be very
considerable. The bank of England is the only company
which
sends any considerable quantity of bullion to the mint, and
the
burden of the annual coinage falls entirely, or almost
entirely,
upon it. If this annual coinage had nothing to do but
to
repair the unavoidable losses and necessary wear and tear of
the
coin, it could seldom exceed fifty thousand, or at most a
hundred
thousand pounds. But when the coin is degraded below its
standard
weight, the annual coinage must, besides this, fill up
the
large vacuities which exportation and the melting pot are
continually
making in the current coin. It was upon this account,
that
during the ten or twelve years immediately preceding the
late
reformation of the gold coin, the annual coinage amounted,
at an
average, to more than £850,000. But if there had been a
seignorage
of four or five per cent. upon the gold coin, it would
probably,
even in the state in which things then were, have put
an
effectual stop to the business both of exportation and of the
melting
pot. The bank, instead of losing every year about two and
a half
per cent. upon the bullion which was to be coined into
more
than eight hundred and fifty thousand pounds, or incurring
an
annual loss of more than £21,250 pounds, would not probably
have
incurred the tenth part of that loss.
The
revenue allotted by parliament for defraying the expense of
the
coinage is but fourteen thousand pounds a-year; and the real
expense
which it costs the government, or the fees of the
officers
of the mint, do not, upon ordinary occasions, I am
assured,
exceed the half of that sum. The saving of so very small
a sum,
or even the gaining of another, which could not well be
much
larger, are objects too inconsiderable, it may be thought,
to
deserve the serious attention of government. But the saving of
eighteen
or twenty thousand pounds a-year, in case of an event
which
is not improbable, which has frequently happened before,
and
which is very likely to happen again, is surely an object
which
well deserves the serious attention, even of so great a
company
as the bank of England.
Some of
the foregoing reasonings and observations might, perhaps,
have
been more properly placed in those chapters of the first
book
which treat of the origin and use of money, and of the
difference
between the real and the nominal price of commodities.
But as
the law for the encouragement of coinage derives its
origin
from those vulgar prejudices which have been introduced by
the
mercantile system, I judged it more proper to reserve them
for
this chapter. Nothing could be more agreeable to the spirit
of that
system than a sort of bounty upon the production of
money,
the very thing which, it supposes, constitutes the wealth
of
every nation. It is one of its many admirable expedients for
enriching
the country.
CHAPTER VII.
OF
COLONIES.
PART I.
Of the
Motives for Establishing New Colonies.
The
interest which occasioned the first settlement of the
different
European colonies in America and the West Indies, was
not
altogether so plain and distinct as that which directed the
establishment
of those of ancient Greece and Rome.
All the
different states of ancient Greece possessed, each of
them,
but a very small territory; and when the people in anyone
of them
multiplied beyond what that territory could easily
maintain,
a part of them were sent in quest of a new habitation,
in some
remote and distant part of the world ; the warlike
neighbours
who surrounded them on all sides, rendering it
difficult
for any of them to enlarge very much its territory at
home.
The colonies of the Dorians resorted chiefly to Italy and
Sicily,
which, in the times preceding the foundation of Rome,
were
inhabited by barbarous and uncivilized nations; those of the
Ionians
and Aeolians, the two other great tribes of the Greeks,
to Asia
Minor and the islands of the Aegean sea, of which the
inhabitants
sewn at that time to have been pretty much in the
same
state as those of Sicily and Italy. The mother city, though
she
considered the colony as a child, at all times entitled to
great
favour and assistance, and owing in return much gratitude
and
respect, yet considered it as an emancipated child, over whom
she
pretended to claim no direct authority or jurisdiction. The
colony
settled its own form of government, enacted its own laws,
elected
its own magistrates, and made peace or war with its
neighbours,
as an independent state, which had no occasion to
wait
for the approbation or consent of the mother city. Nothing
can be
more plain and distinct than the interest which directed
every
such establishment.
Rome,
like most of the other ancient republics, was originally
founded
upon an agrarian law, which divided the public territory,
in a
certain proportion, among the different citizens who
composed
the state. The course of human affairs, by marriage, by
succession,
and by alienation, necessarily deranged this original
division,
and frequently threw the lands which had been allotted
for the
maintenance of many different families, into the
possession
of a single person. To remedy this
disorder, for
such it
was supposed to be, a law was made, restricting the
quantity
of land which any citizen could possess to five hundred
jugera;
about 350 English acres. This law, however, though we
read of
its having been executed upon one or two occasions, was
either
neglected or evaded, and the inequality of fortunes went
on
continually increasing. The greater part of the citizens had
no land
; and without it the manners and customs of those times
rendered
it difficult for a freeman to maintain his independency.
In the
present times, though a poor man has no land of his own,
if he
has a little stock, he may either farm the lands of
another,
or he may carry on some little retail trade ; and if he
has no
stock, he may find employment either as a country
labourer,
or as an artificer. But among the ancient Romans, the
lands
of the rich were all cultivated by slaves, who wrought
under
an overseer, who was likewise a slave; so that a poor
freeman
had little chance of being employed either as a farmer or
as a
labourer. All trades and manufactures, too, even the retail
trade,
were carried on by the slaves of the rich for the benefit
of
their masters, whose wealth, authority, and protection, made
it
difficult for a poor freeman to maintain the competition
against
them. The citizens, therefore, who had no land, had
scarce
any other means of subsistence but the bounties of the
candidates
at the annual elections. The tribunes, when they had a
mind to
animate the people against the rich and the great, put
them in
mind of the ancient divisions of lands, and represented
that
law which restricted this sort of private property as the
fundamental
law of the republic. The people became clamorous to
get
land, and the rich and the great, we may believe, were
perfectly
determined not to give them any part of theirs. To
satisfy
them in some measure, therefore, they frequently proposed
to send
out a new colony. But conquering Rome was, even upon such
occasions,
under no necessity of turning out her citizens to seek
their
fortune, if one may so, through the wide world, without
knowing
where they were to settle. She assigned them lands
generally
in the conquered provinces of Italy, where, being
within
the dominions of the republic, they could never form any
independent
state, but were at best but a sort of corporation,
which,
though it had the power of enacting bye-laws for its own
government,
was at all times subject to the correction,
jurisdiction,
and legislative authority of the mother city. The
sending
out a colony of this kind not only gave some satisfaction
to the
people, but often established a sort of garrison, too, in
a newly
conquered province, of which the obedience might
otherwise
have been doubtful. A Roman colony, therefore, whether
we
consider the nature of the establishment itself, or the
motives
for making it, was altogether different from a Greek one.
The
words, accordingly, which in the original languages denote
those
different establishments, have very different meanings. The
Latin
word (colonia) signifies simply a plantation. The Greek
word
(apoixia), on the contrary, signifies a separation of
dwelling,
a departure from home, a going out of the house. But
though
the Roman colonies were, in many respects, different from
the
Greek ones, the interest which prompted to establish them was
equally
plain and distinct. Both institutions derived their
origin,
either from irresistible necessity, or from clear and
evident
utility.
The
establishment of the European colonies in America and the
West
Indies arose from no necessity; and though the utility which
has
resulted from them has been very great, it is not altogether
so
clear and evident. It was not understood at their first
establishment,
and was not the motive, either of that
establishment,
or of the discoveries which gave occasion to it ;
and the
nature, extent, and limits of that utility, are not,
perhaps,
well understood at this day.
The
Venetians, during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries,
carried
on a very advantageous commerce in spiceries and other
East
India goods, which they distributed among the other nations
of
Europe. They purchased them chiefly in Egypt, at that time
under
the dominion of the Mamelukes, the enemies of the Turks, of
whom
the Venetians were the enemies ; and this union of interest,
assisted
by the money of Venice, formed such a connexion as gave
the
Venetians almost a monopoly of the trade.
The
great profits of the Venetians tempted the avidity of the
Portuguese.
They had been endeavouring, during the course of the
fifteenth
century, to find out by sea a way to the countries from
which
the Moors brought them ivory and gold dust across the
desert.
They discovered the Madeiras, the Canaries, the Azores,
the
Cape de Verd islands, the coast of Guinea, that of Loango,
Congo,
Angola, and Benguela, and, finally, the Cape of Good Hope.
They
had long wished to share in the profitable traffic of the
Venetians,
and this last discovery opened to them a probable
prospect
of doing so. In 1497, Vasco de Gamo sailed from the port
of
Lisbon with a fleet of four ships, and, after a navigation of
eleven
months, arrived upon the coast of Indostan ; and thus
completed
a course of discoveries which had been pursued with
great
steadiness, and with very little interruption, for near a
century
together.
Some
years before this, while the expectations of Europe were in
suspense
about the projects of the Portuguese, of which the
success
appeared yet to be doubtful, a Genoese pilot formed the
yet
more daring project of sailing to the East Indies by the
west.
The situation of those countries was at that time very
imperfectly
known in Europe. The few European travellers who had
been
there, had magnified the distance, perhaps through
simplicity
and ignorance ; what was really very great, appearing
almost
infinite to those who could not measure it; or, perhaps,
in
order to increase somewhat more the marvellous of their own
adventures
in visiting regions so immensely remote from Europe.
The
longer the way was by the east, Columbus very justly
concluded,
the shorter it would be by the west. He proposed,
therefore,
to take that way, as both the shortest and the surest,
and he
had the good fortune to convince Isabella of Castile of
the
probability of his project. He sailed from the port of Palos
in
August 1492, near five years before the expedition of Vasco de
Gamo
set out from Portugal; and, after a voyage of between two
and
three months, discovered first some of the small Bahama or
Lucyan
islands, and afterwards the great island of St. Domingo.
But the
countries which Columbus discovered, either in this or in
any of
his subsequent voyages, had no resemblance to those which
he had
gone in quest of. Instead of the wealth, cultivation, and
populousness
of China and Indostan, he found, in St. Domingo, and
in all
the other parts of the new world which he ever visited,
nothing
but a country quite covered with wood, uncultivated, and
inhabited
only by some tribes of naked and miserable savages. He
was not
very willing, however, to believe that they were not the
same
with some of the countries described by Marco Polo, the
first
European who had visited, or at least had left behind him
any
description of China or the East Indies ; and a very slight
resemblance,
such as that which he found between the name of
Cibao,
a mountaim in St. Domingo, and that of Cipange, mentioned
by
Marco Polo, was frequently sufficient to make him return to
this
favourite prepossession, though contrary to the clearest
evidence.
In his letters to Ferdinand and Isabella, he called the
countries
which he had discovered the Indies. He entertained no
doubt
but that they were the extremity of those which had been
described
by Marco Polo, and that they were not very distant from
the
Ganges, or from the countries which had been conquered by
Alexander.
Even when at last convinced that they were different,
be
still flattered himself that those rich countries were at no
great
distance; and in a subsequent voyage, accordingly, went in
quest
of them along the coast of Terra Firma, and towards the
Isthmus
of Darien.
In
consequence of this mistake of Columbus, the name of the
Indies
has stuck to those unfortunate countries ever since; and
when it
was at last clearly discovered that the new were
altogether
different from the old Indies, the former were called
the
West, in contradistinction to the latter, which were called
the
East Indies.
It was
of importance to Columbus, however, that the countries
which
he had discovered, whatever they were, should be
represented
to the court of Spain as of very great consequence ;
and, in
what constitutes the real riches of every country, the
animal
and vegetable productions of the soil, there was at that
time
nothing which could well justify such a representation of
them.
The
cori, something between a rat and a rabbit, and supposed by
Mr
Buffon to be the same with the aperea of Brazil, was the
largest
viviparous quadruped in St. Domingo. This species seems
never
to have been very nurnerous; and the dogs and cats of the
Spaniards
are said to have long ago almost entirely extirpated
it, as
well as some other tribes of a still smaller size. These,
however,
together with a pretty large lizard, called the ivana or
iguana,
constituted the principal part of the animal food which
the
land afforded.
The
vegetable food of the inhabitants, though, from their want of
industry,
not very abundant, was not altogether so scanty. It
consisted
in Indian corn, yams, potatoes, bananas, etc., plants
which
were then altogether unknown in Europe, and which have
never
since been very much esteemed in it, or supposed to yield a
sustenance
equal to what is drawn from the common sorts of grain
and
pulse, which have been cultivated in this part of the world
time
out of mind.
The
cotton plant, indeed, afforded the material of a very
important
manufacture, and was at that time, to Europeans,
undoubtedly
the most valuable of all the vegetable productions of
those
islands. But though, in the end of the fifteenth century,
the
muslins and other cotton goods of the East Indies were much
esteemed
in every part of Europe, the cotton manufacture itself
was not
cultivated in any part of it. Even this production,
therefore,
could not at that time appear in the eyes of Europeans
to be
of very great consequence.
Finding
nothing, either in the animals or vegetables of the newly
discovered
countries which could justify a very advantageous
representation
of them, Columbus turned his view towards their
minerals;
and in the richness of their productions of this third
kingdom,
he flattered himself he had found a full compensation
for the
insignificancy of those of the other two. The little bits
of gold
with which the inhabitants ornamented their dress, and
which,
he was informed, they frequently found in the rivulets and
torrents
which fell from the mountains, were sufficient to
satisfy
him that those mountains abounded with the richest gold
mines.
St. Domingo, therefore, was represented as a country
abounding
with gold, and upon that account (according to the
prejudices
not only of the present times, but of those times), an
inexhaustible
source of real wealth to the crown and kingdom of
Spain.
When Columbus, upon his return from his first voyage, was
introduced
with a sort of triumphal honours to the sovereigns of
Castile
and Arragon, the principal productions of the countries
which
he had discovered were carried in solemn procession before
him.
The only valuable part of them consisted in some little
fillets,
bracelets, and other ornaments of gold, and in some
bales
of cotton. The rest were mere objects of vulgar wonder and
curiosity
; some reeds of an extraordinary size, some birds of a
very
beautiful plumage, and some stuffed skins of the huge
alligator
and manati ; all of which were preceded by six or seven
of the
wretched natives, whose singular colour and appearance
added
greatly to the novelty of the show.
In
consequence of the representations of Columbus, the council of
Castile
determined to take possession of the countries of which
the inhabitants
were plainly incapable of defending themselves.
The
pious purpose of converting them to Christianity sanctified
the
injustice of the project. But the hope of finding treasures
of gold
there was the sole motive which prompted to undertake it;
and to
give this motive the greater weight, it was proposed by
Columbus,
that the half of all the gold and silver that should be
found
there, should belong to the crown. This proposal was
approved
of by the council.
As long
as the whole, or the greater part of the gold which the
first
adventurers imported into Europe was got by so very easy a
method
as the plundering of the defenceless natives, it was not
perhaps
very difficult to ,pay even this heavy tax ; but when the
natives
were once fairly stript of all that they had, which, in
St.
Domingo, and in all the other countries discovered by
Columbus,
was done completely in six or eight years, and when, in
order
to find more, it had become necessary to dig for it in the
mines,
there was no longer any possibility of paying this tax.
The
rigorous exaction of it, accordingly, first occasioned, it is
said,
the total abandoning of the mines of St. Domingo, which
have
never been wrought since. It was soon reduced, therefore, to
a
third; then to a fifth; afterwards to a tenth; and at last to a
twentieth
part of the gross produce of the gold mines. The tax
upon
silver continued for a long time to be a fifth of the gross
produce.
It was reduced to a tenth only in the course of the
present
century. But the first adventurers do not appear to have
been
much interested about silver. Nothing less precious than
gold
seemed worthy of their attention.
All the
other enterprizes of the Spaniards in the New World,
subsequent
to those of Columbus, seem to have been prompted by
the
same motive. It was the sacred thirst of gold that carried
Ovieda,
Nicuessa, and Vasco Nugnes de Balboa, to the Isthmus of
Darien
; that carried Cortes to Mexico, Almagro and Pizarro to
Chili
and Peru. When those adventurers arrived upon any unknown
coast,
their first inquiry was always if there was any gold to be
found
there ; and according to the information which they
received
concerning this particular, they determined either to
quit
the country or to settle in it.
Of all
those expensive and uncertain projects, however, which
bring
bankruptcy upon the greater part of the people who engage
in
them, there is none, perhaps, more perfectly ruinous than the
search
after new silver and gold mines. It is, perhaps, the most
disadvantageous
lottery in the world, or the one in which the
gain of
those who draw the prizes bears the least proportion to
the
loss of those who draw the blanks; for though the prizes are
few,
and the blanks many, the common price of a ticket is the
whole
fortune of a very rich man. Projects of mining, instead of
replacing
the capital employed in them, together with the
ordinary
profits of stock, commonly absorb both capital and
profit.
They are the projects, therefore, to which, of all
others,
a prudent lawgiver, who desired to increase the capital
of his
nation, would least choose to give any extraordinary
encouragement,
or to turn towards them a greater share of that
capital
than what would go to them of its own accord. Such, in
reality,
is the absurd confidence which almost all men have in
their
own good fortune, that wherever there is the least
probability
of success, too great a share of it is apt to go to
them of
its own accord.
But
though the judgment of sober reason and experience concerning
such
projects has always been extremely unfavourable, that of
human
avidity has commonly been quite otherwise. The same passion
which
has suggested to so many people the absurd idea of the
philosopher's
stone, has suggested to others the equally absurd
one of
immense rich mines of gold and silver. They did not
consider
that the value of those metals has, in all ages and
nations,
arisen chiefly from their scarcity, and that their
scarcity
has arisen from the very small quantities of them which
nature
has anywhere deposited in one place, from the hard and
intractable
substances with which she has almost everywhere
surrounded
those small quantities, and consequently from the
labour
and expense which are everywhere necessary in order to
penetrate,
and get at them. They flattered themselves that veins
of
those metals might in many places be found, as large and as
abundant
as those which are commonly found of lead, or copper, or
tin, or
iron. The dream of Sir Waiter Raleigh, concerning the
golden
city and country of El Dorado, may satisfy us, that even
wise
men are not always exempt from such strange delusions. More
than a
hundred years after the death of that great man, the
Jesuit
Gumila was still convinced of the reality of that
wonderful
country, and expressed, with great warmth, and, I dare
say,
with great sincerity, how happy he should be to carry the
light
of the gospel to a people who could so well reward the
pious
labours of their missionary.
In the
countries first discovered by the Spaniards, no gold and
silver
mines are at present known which are supposed to be worth
the
working. The quantities of those metals which the first
adventurers
are said to have found there, had probably been very
much
magnified, as well as the fertility of the mines which were
wrought
immediately after the first discovery. What those
adventurers
were reported to have found, however, was sufficient
to
inflame the avidity of all their countrymen. Every Spaniard
who
sailed to America expected to find an El Dorado. Fortune,
too,
did upon this what she has done upon very few other
occasions.
She realized in some measure the extravagant hopes of
her
votaries; and in the discovery and conquest of Mexico and
Peru
(of which the one happened about thirty, and the other about
forty,
years after the first expedition of Columbus), she
presented
them with something not very unlike that profusion of
the
precious metals which they sought for.
A
project of commerce to the East Indies, therefore, gave
occasion
to the first discovery of the West. A project of
conquest
gave occasion to all the establishments of the Spaniards
in
those newly discovered countries. The motive which excited
them to
this conquest was a project of gold and silver mines; and
a
course of accidents which no human wisdom could foresee,
rendered
this project much more successful than the undertakers
had any
reasonable grounds for expecting.
The
first adventurers of all the other nations of Europe who
attempted
to make settlements in America, were animated by the
like
chimerical views; but they were not equally successful. It
was
more than a hundred years after the first settlement of the
Brazils,
before any silver, gold, or diamond mines, were
discovered
there. In the English, French, Dutch, and Danish
colonies,
none have ever yet been discovered, at least none that
are at
present supposed to be worth the working. The first
English
settlers in North America, however, offered a fifth of
all the
gold and silver which should be found there to the king,
as a
motive for granting them their patents. In the patents of
Sir
Waiter Raleigh, to the London and Plymouth companies, to the
council
of Plymouth, etc. this fifth was accordingly reserved to
the
crown. To the expectation of finding gold and silver mines,
those
first settlers, too, joined that of discovering a
north-west
passage to the East Indies. They have hitherto been
disappointed
in both.
PART II.
Causes
of the Prosperity of New Colonies.
The
colony of a civilized nation which takes possession either of
a waste
country, or of one so thinly inhabited that the natives
easily
give place to the new settlers, advances more rapidly to
wealth
and greatness than any other human society.
The colonies
carry out with them a knowledge of agriculture and
of
other useful arts, superior to what can grow up of its own
accord,
in the course of many centuries, among savage and
barbarous
nations. They carry out with them, too, the habit of
subordination,
some notion of the regular government which takes
place
in their own country, of the system of laws which support
it, and
of a regular administration of justice; and they
naturally
establish something of the same kind in the new
settlement.
But among savage and barbarous nations, the natural
progress
of law and government is still slower than the natural
progress
of arts, after law and government have been so far
established
as is necessary for their protection. Every colonist
gets
more land than he can possibly cultivate. He has no rent,
and
scarce any taxes, to pay. No landlord shares with him in its
produce,
and, the share of the sovereign is commonly but a
trifle.
He has every motive to render as great as possible a
produce
which is thus to be almost entirely his own. But his land
is
commonly so extensive, that, with all his own industry, and
with
all the industry of other people whom he can get to employ,
he can
seldom make it produce the tenth part of what it is
capable
of producing. He is eager, therefore, to collect
labourers
from all quarters, and to reward them with the most
liberal
wages. But those liberal wages, joined to the plenty and
cheapness
of land, soon make those labourers leave him, in order
to
become landlords themselves, and to reward with equal
liberality
other labourers, who soon leave them for the same
reason
that they left their first master. The liberal reward of
labour
encourages marriage. The children, during the tender years
of
infancy, are well fed and properly taken care of ; and when
they
are grown up, the value of their labour greatly overpays
their
maintenance. When arrived at maturity, the high price of
labour,
and the low price of land, enable them to establish
themselves
in the same manner as their fathers did before them.
In
other countries, rent and profit eat up wages, and the two
superior
orders of people oppress the inferior one ; but in new
colonies,
the interest of the two superior orders obliges them to
treat
the inferior one with more generosity and humanity, at
least
where that inferior one is not in a state of slavery. Waste
lands,
of the greatest natural fertility, are to be had for a
trifle.
The increase of revenue which the proprietor, who is
always
the undertaker, expects from their improvement,
constitutes
his profit, which, in these circumstances, is
commonly
very great; but this great profit cannot be made,
without
employing the labour of other people in clearing and
cultivating
the land; and the disproportion between the great
extent
of the land and the small number of the people, which
commonly
takes place in new colonies, makes it difficult for him
to get
this labour. He does not, therefore, dispute about wages,
but is
willing to employ labour at any price. The high wages of
labour
encourage population. The cheapness and plenty of good
land
encourage improvement, and enable the proprietor to pay
those
high wages. In those wages consists almost the whole price
of the
land ; and though they are high, considered as the wages
of
labour, they are low, considered as the price of what is so
very
valuable. What encourages the progress of population and
improvement,
encourages that of real wealth and greatness.
The
progress of many of the ancient Greek colonies towards wealth
and
greatness seems accordingly to have been very rapid. In the
course
of a century or two, several of them appear to have
rivalled,
and even to have surpassed, their mother cities.
Syracuse
and Agrigentum in Sicily, Tarentum and Locri in Italy,
Ephesus
and Miletus in Lesser Asia, appear, by all accounts, to
have
been at least equal to any of the cities of ancient Greece.
Though
posterior in their establishment, yet all the arts of
refinement,
philosophy, poetry, and eloquence, seem to have been
cultivated
as early, and to have been improved as highly in them
as in
any part of the mother country The schools of the two
oldest
Greek philosophers, those of Thales and Pythagoras, were
established,
it is remarkable, not in ancient Greece, but the one
in an
Asiatic, the other in an Italian colony. All those colonies
had
established themselves in countries inhabited by savage and
barbarous
nations, who easily gave place to the new settlers.
They
had plenty of good land; and as they were altogether
independent
of the mother city, they were at liberty to manage
their
own affairs in the way that they judged was most suitable
to
their own interest.
The
history of the Roman colonies is by no means so brilliant.
Some of
them, indeed, such as Florence, have, in the course of
many
ages, and after the fall of the mother city, grown up to be
considerable
states. But the progress of no one of them seems
ever to
have been very rapid. They were all established in
conquered
provinces, which in most cases had been fully inhabited
before.
The quantity of land assigned to each colonist was seldom
very
considerable, and, as the colony was not independent, they
were
not always at liberty to manage their own affairs in the way
that
they judged was most suitable to their own interest.
In the
plenty of good land, the European colonies established in
America
and the West Indies resemble, and even greatly surpass,
those
of ancient Greece. In their dependency upon the mother
state,
they resemble those of ancient Rome; but their great
distance
from Europe has in all of them alleviated more or less
the
effects of this dependency. Their situation has placed them
less in
the view, and less in the power of their mother country.
In
pursuing their interest their own way, their conduct has upon
many
occasions been overlooked, either because not known or not
understood
in Europe; and upon some occasions it has been fairly
suffered
and submitted to, because their distance rendered it
difficult
to restrain it. Even the violent and arbitrary
government
of Spain has, upon many occasions, been obliged to
recall
or soften the orders which had been given for the
government
of her colonies, for fear of a general insurrection.
The
progress of all the European colonies in wealth, population,
and
improvement, has accordingly been very great.
The
crown of Spain, by its share of the gold and silver, derived
some
revenue from its colonies from the moment of their first
establishment.
It was a revenue, too, of a nature to excite in
human
avidity the most extravagant expectation of still greater
riches.
The Spanish colonies, therefore, from the moment of their
first
establishment, attracted very much the attention of their
mother
country; while those of the other European nations were
for a
long time in a great measure neglected. The former did not,
perhaps,
thrive the better in consequence of this attention, nor
the
latter the worse in consequence of this neglect. In
proportion
to the extent of the country which they in some
measure
possess, the Spanish colonies are considered as less
populous
and thriving than those of almost any other European
nation.
The progress even of the Spanish colonies, however, in
population
and improvement, has certainly been very rapid and
very
great. The city of Lima, founded since the conquest, is
represented
by Ulloa as containing fifty thousand inhabitants
near
thirty years ago. Quito, which had been but a miserable
hamlet
of Indians, is represented by the same author as in his
time
equally populous. Gemel i Carreri, a pretended traveller, it
is
said, indeed, but who seems everywhere to have written upon
extreme
good information, represents the city of Mexico as
containing
a hundred thousand inhabitants ; a number which, in
spite
of all the exaggerations of the Spanish writers, is
probably
more than five times greater than what it contained in
the
time of Montezuma. These numbers exceed greatly those of
Boston,
New York, and Philadelphia, the three greatest cities of
the
English colonies. Before the conquest of the Spaniards, there
were no
cattle fit for draught, either in Mexico or Peru. The
lama
was their only beast of burden, and its strength seems to
have
been a good deal inferior to that of a common ass. The
plough
was unknown among them. They were ignorant of the use of
iron.
They had no coined money, nor any established instrument of
commerce
of any kind. Their commerce was carried on by barter. A
sort of
wooden spade was their principal instrument of
agriculture.
Sharp stones served them for knives and hatchets to
cut
with; fish bones, and the hard sinews of certain animals,
served
them with needles to sew with; and these seem to have been
their
principal instruments of trade. In this state of things, it
seems
impossible that either of those empires could have been so
much
improved or so well cultivated as at present, when they are
plentifully
furnished with all sorts of European cattle, and when
the use
of iron, of the plough, and of many of the arts of
Europe,
have been introduced among them. But the populousness of
every
country must be in proportion to the degree of its
improvement
and cultivation. In spite of the cruel destruction of
the
natives which followed the conquest, these two great empires
are
probably more populous now than they ever were before; and
the
people are surely very different; for we must acknowledge, I
apprehend,
that the Spanish creoles are in many respects superior
to the
ancient Indians.
After the settlements of the Spaniards, that
of the Portuguese
in
Brazil is the oldest of any European nation in America. But as
for a
long time after the first discovery neither gold nor silver
mines
were found in it, and as it afforded upon that account
little
or no revenue to the crown, it was for a long time in a
great
measure neglected ; and during this state of neglect, it
grew up
to be a great and powerful colony. While Portugal was
under
the dominion of Spain, Brazil was attacked by the Dutch,
who got
possession of seven of the fourteen provinces into which
it is
divided. They expected soon to conquer the other seven,
when
Portugal recovered its independency by the elevation of the
family
of Braganza to the throne. The Dutch, then, as enemies to
the
Spaniards, became friends to the Portuguese, who were
likewise
the enemies of the Spaniards. They agreed, therefore, to
leave
that part of Brazil which they had not conquered to the
king of
Portugal, who agreed to leave that part which they had
conquered
to them, as a matter not worth disputing about, with
such
good allies. But the Dutch government soon began to oppress
the
Portuguese colonists, who, instead of amusing themselves with
complaints,
took arms against their new masters, and by their own
valour
and resolution, with the connivance, indeed, but without
any
avowed assistance from the mother country, drove them out of
Brazil.
The Dutch, therefore, finding it impossible to keep any
part of
the country to themselves, were contented that it should
be
entirely restored to the crown of Portugal. In this colony
there
are said to be more than six hundred thousand people,
either
Portuguese or descended from Portuguese, creoles,
mulattoes,
and a mixed race between Portuguese and Brazilians. No
one
colony in America is supposed to contain so great a number of
people
of European extraction.
Towards
the end of the fifteenth, and during the greater part of
the
sixteenth century, Spain and Portugal were the two great
naval
powers upon the ocean ; for though the commerce of Venice
extended
to every part of Europe, its fleet had scarce ever
sailed
beyond the Mediterranean. The Spaniards, in virtue of the
first
discovery, claimed all America as their own; and though
they
could not hinder so great a naval power as that of Portugal
from
settling in Brazil, such was at that time the terror of
their
name, that the greater part of the other nations of Europe
were
afraid to establish themselves in any other part of that
great
continent. The French, who attempted to settle in Florida,
were
all murdered by the Spaniards. But the declension of the
naval
power of this latter nation, in consequence of the defeat
or
miscarriage of what they called their invincible armada, which
happened
towards the end of the sixteenth century, put it out of
their
power to obstruct any longer the settlements of the other
European
nations. In the course of the seventeenth century,
therefore,
the English, French, Dutch, Danes, and Swedes, all the
great
nations who had any ports upon the ocean, attempted to make
some
settlements in the new world.
The
Swedes established themselves in New Jersey; and the number
of
Swedish families still to be found there sufficiently
demonstrates,
that this colony was very likely to prosper, had it
been
protected by the mother country. But being neglected by
Sweden,
it was soon swallowed up by the Dutch colony of New York,
which
again, in 1674, fell under the dominion of the English.
The
small islands of St. Thomas and Santa Cruz, are the only
countries
in the new world that have ever been possessed by the
Danes.
These little settlements, too, were under the government
of an
exclusive company, which had the sole right, both of
purchasing
the surplus produce of the colonies, and of supplying
them
with such goods of other countries as they wanted, and
which,
therefore, both in its purchases and sales, had not only
the
power of oppressing them, but the greatest temptation to do
so. The
government of an exclusive company of merchants is,
perhaps,
the worst of all governments for any country whatever.
It was
not, however, able to stop altogether the progress of
these
colonies, though it rendered it more slow and languid. The
late
king of Denmark dissolved this company, and since that time
the
prosperity of these colonies has been very great.
The
Dutch settlements in the West, as well as those in the East
Indies,
were originally put under the government of an exclusive
company.
The progress of some of them, therefore, though it has
been
considerable in comparison with that of almost any country
that
has been long peopled and established, has been languid and
slow in
comparison with that of the greater part of new colonies.
The
colony of Surinam, though very considerable, is still
inferior
to the greater part of the sugar colonies of the other
European
nations. The colony of Nova Belgia, now divided into the
two
provinces of New York and New Jersey, would probably have
soon
become considerable too, even though it had remained under
the
government of the Dutch. The plenty and cheapness of good
land
are such powerful causes of prosperity, that the very worst
government
is scarce capable of checking altogether the efficacy
of
their operation. The great distance, too, from the mother
country,
would enable the colonists to evade more or less, by
smuggling,
the monopoly which the company enjoyed against them.
At
present, the company allows all Dutch ships to trade to
Surinam,
upon paying two and a-half per cent. upon the value of
their
cargo for a license; and only reserves to itself
exclusively,
the direct trade from Africa to America, which
consists
almost entirely in the slave trade. This relaxation in
the
exclusive privileges of the company, is probably the
principal
cause of that degree of prosperity which that colony at
present
enjoys. Curacoa and Eustatia, the two principal islands
belonging
to the Dutch, are free ports, open to the ships of all
nations;
and this freedom, in the midst of better colonies, whose
ports
are open to those of one nation only, has been the great
cause
of the prosperity of those two barren islands.
The
French colony of Canada was, during the greater part of the
last
century, and some part of the present, under the government
of an
exclusive company. Under so unfavourable an administration,
its
progress was necessarily very slow, in comparison with that
of
other new colonies; but it became much more rapid when this
company
was dissolved, after the fall of what is called the
Mississippi
scheme. When the English got possession of this
country,
they found in it near double the number of inhabitants
which
father Charlevoix had assigned to it between twenty and
thirty
years before. That jesuit had
travelled over the whole
country,
and had no inclination to represent it as less
inconsiderable
than it really was.
The
French colony of St. Domingo was established by pirates and
freebooters,
who, for a long time, neither required the
protection,
nor acknowledged the authority of France; and when
that
race of banditti became so far citizens as to acknowledge
this
authority, it was for a long time necessary to exercise it
with
very great gentleness. During this period, the population
and
improvement of this colony increased very fast. Even the
oppression
of the exclusive company, to which it was for some
time
subjected with all the other colonies of France, though it
no
doubt retarded, had not been able to stop its progress
altogether.
The course of its prosperity returned as soon as it
was
relieved from that oppression. It is now the most important
of the
sugar colonies of the West Indies, and its produce is said
to be
greater than that of all the English sugar colonies put
together.
The other sugar colonies of France are in general all
very
thriving.
But
there are no colonies of which the progress has been more
rapid
than that of the English in North America.
Plenty
of good land, and liberty to manage their own affairs
their
own way, seem to be the two great causes of the prosperity
of all
new colonies.
In the
plenty of good land, the English colonies of North
America,
though no doubt very abundantly provided, are, however,
inferior
to those of the Spaniards and Portuguese, and not
superior
to some of those possessed by the French before the late
war.
But the political institutions of the English colonies have
been
more favourable to the improvement and cultivation of this
land,
than those of the other three nations.
First, The engrossing of uncultivated land, though it has by
no
means been prevented altogether, has been more restrained in
the
English colonies than in any other. The colony law, which
imposes
upon every proprietor the obligation of improving and
cultivating,
within a limited time, a certain proportion of his
lands,
and which, in case of failure, declares those neglected
lands
grantable to any other person; though it has not perhaps
been
very strictly executed, has, however, had some effect.
Secondly, In Pennsylvania there is no right of
primogeniture,
and
lands, like moveables, are divided equally among all the
children
of the family. In three of the provinces of New England,
the
oldest has only a double share, as in the Mosaical law.
Though
in those provinces, therefore, too great a quantity of
land
should sometimes be engrossed by a particular individual, it
is
likely, in the course of a generation or two, to be
sufficiently
divided again. In the other English colonies,
indeed,
the right of primogeniture takes place, as in the law of
England:
But in all the English colonies, the tenure of the
lands,
which are all held by free soccage, facilitates alienation
; and
the grantee of an extensive tract of land generally finds
it for
his interest to alienate, as fast as he can, the greater
part of
it, reserving only a small quit-rent. In the Spanish and
Portuguese
colonies, what is called the right of majorazzo takes
place
in the succession of all those great estates to which any
title
of honour is annexed. Such estates go all to one person,
and are
in effect entailed and unalienable. The French colonies,
indeed,
are subject to the custom of Paris, which, in the
inheritance
of land, is much more favourable to the younger
children
than the law of England. But, in the French colonies, if
any
part of an estate, held by the noble tenure of chivalry and
homage,
is alienated, it is, for a limited time, subject to the
right
of redemption, either by the heir of the superior, or by
the
heir of the family; and all the largest estates of the
country
are held by such noble tenures, which necessarily
embarrass
alienation. But, in a new colony, a great uncultivated
estate
is likely to be much more speedily divided by alienation
than by
succession. The plenty and cheapness of good land, it has
already
been observed, are the principal causes of the rapid
prosperity
of new colonies. The engrossing of land, in effect,
destroys
this plenty and cheapness. The engrossing of
uncultivated
land, besides, is the greatest obstruction to its
improvement
; but the labour that is employed in the improvement
and
cultivation of land affords the greatest and most valuable
produce
to the society. The produce of labour, in this case, pays
not
only its own wages and the profit of the stock which employs
it, but
the rent of the land too upon which it is employed. The
labour
of the English colonies, therefore, being more employed in
the
improvement and cultivation of land, is likely to afford a
greater
and more valuable produce than that of any of the other
three
nations, which, by the engrossing of land, is more or less
diverted
towards other employments.
Thirdly, The labour of the English colonists is not
only
likely
to afford a greater and more valuable produce, but, in
consequence
of the moderation of their taxes, a greater
proportion
of this produce belongs to themselves, which they may
store
up and employ in putting into motion a still greater
quantity
of labour. The Eng1ish colonists have never yet
contributed
any thing towards the defence of the mother country,
or
towards the support of its civil government. They themselves,
on the
contrary, have hitherto been defended almost entirely at
the
expense of the mother country ; but the expense of fleets and
armies
is out of all proportion greater than the necessary
expense
of civil government. The expense of their own civil
government
has always been very moderate. It has generally been
confined
to what was necessary for paying competent salaries to
the
governor, to the judges, and to some other officers of
police,
and for maintaining a few of the most useful public
works.
The expense of the civil establishment of Massachusetts
Bay,
before the commencement of the present disturbances, used to
be but
about £18;000 a-year ; that of New Hampshire and Rhode
Island,
£3500 each; that of Connecticut, £4000; that of New York
and
Pennsylvania, £4500 each; that of New Jersey, £1200; that of
Virginia
and South Carolina, £8000 each. The civil establishments
of Nova
Scotia and Georgia are partly supported by an annual
grant
of parliament; but Nova Scotia pays, besides, about £7000
a-year
towards the public expenses of the colony, and Georgia
about
£2500 a-year. All the different civil establishments in
North
America, in short, exclusive of those of Maryland and North
Carolina,
of which no exact account has been got, did not, before
the
commencement of the present disturbances, cost the
inhabitants
about £64,700 a-year; an ever memorable example, at
how
small an expense three millions of people may not only be
governed
but well governed. The most important part of the
expense
of government, indeed, that of defence and protection,
has
constantly fallen upon the mother country. The ceremonial,
too, of
the civil government in the colonies, upon the reception
of a
new governor, upon the opening of a new assembly, etc.
though
sufficiently decent, is not accompanied with any expensive
pomp or
parade. Their ecclesiastical government is conducted upon
a plan
equally frugal. Tithes are unknown among them; and their
clergy,
who are far from being numerous, are maintained either by
moderate
stipends, or by the voluntary contributions of the
people.
The power of Spain and Portugal, on the contrary, derives
some
support from the taxes levied upon their colonies. France,
indeed,
has never drawn any considerable revenue from its
colonies,
the taxes which it levies upon them being generally
spent
among them. But the colony government of all these three
nations
is conducted upon a much more extensive plan, and is
accompanied
with a much more expensive ceremonial. The sums spent
upon
the reception of a new viceroy of Peru, for example, have
frequently
been enormous. Such ceremonials are not only real
taxes
paid by the rich colonists upon those particular occasions,
but
they serve to introduce among them the habit of vanity and
expense
upon all other occasions. They are not only very grievous
occasional
taxes, but they contribute to establish perpetual
taxes,
of the same kind, still more grievous ; the ruinous taxes
of
private luxury and extravagance. In the colonies of all those
three
nations, too, the ecclesiastical government is extremely
oppressive.
Tithes take place in all of them, and are levied with
the
utmost rigour in those of Spain and Portugal. All of them,
besides,
are oppressed with a numerous race of mendicant friars,
whose
beggary being not only licensed but consecrated by
religion,
is a most grievous tax upon the poor people, who are
most
carefully taught that it is a duty to give, and a very great
sin to
refuse them their charity. Over and above all this, the
clergy
are, in all of them, the greatest engrossers of land.
Fourthly, In the disposal of their surplus produce,
or of
what is
over and above their own consumption, the English
colonies
have been more favoured, and have been allowed a more
extensive
market, than those of any other European nation. Every
European
nation has endeavoured, more or less, to monopolize to
itself
the commerce of its colonies, and, upon that account, has
prohibited
the ships of foreign nations from trading to them, and
has
prohibited them from importing European goods from any
foreign
nation. But the manner in which this monopoly has been
exercised
in different nations, has been very different.
Some
nations have given up the whole commerce of their colonies
to an
exclusive company, of whom the colonists were obliged to
buy all
such European goods as they wanted, and to whom they were
obliged
to sell the whole of their surplus produce. It was the
interest
of the company, therefore, not only to sell the former
as
dear, and to buy the latter as cheap as possible, but to buy
no more
of the latter, even at this low price, than what they
could
dipose of for a very high price in Europe. It was their
interest
not only to degrade in all cases the value of the
surplus
produce of the colony, but in many cases to discourage
and
keep down the natural increase of its quantity. Of all the
expedients
that can well be contrived to stunt the natural growth
of a
new colony, that of an exclusive company is undoubtedly the
most
effectual. This, however, has been the policy of Holland,
though
their company, in the course of the present century, has
given
up in many respects the exertion of their exclusive
privilege.
This, too, was the policy of Denmark, till the reign
of the
late king. It has occasionally been the policy of France ;
and of
late, since 1755, after it had been abandoned by all other
nations
on account of its absurdity, it has become the policy of
Portugal,
with regard at least to two of the principal provinces
of
Brazil, Pernambucco, and Marannon.
Other
nations, without establishing an exclusive company, have
confined
the whole commerce of their colonies to a particular
port of
the mother country, from whence no ship was allowed to
sail,
but either in a fleet and at a particular season, or, if
single,
in consequence of a particular license, which in most
cases
was very well paid for. This policy opened, indeed, the
trade
of the colonies to all the natives of the mother country,
provided
they traded from the proper port, at the proper season,
and in
the proper vessels. But as all the different merchants,
who
joined their stocks in order to fit out those licensed
vessels,
would find it for their interest to act in concert, the
trade
which was carried on in this manner would necessarily be
conducted
very nearly upon the same principles as that of an
exclusive
company. The profit of those merchants would be almost
equally
exorbitant and oppressive. The colonies would be ill
supplied,
and would be obliged both to buy very dear, and to sell
very
cheap. This, however, till within these few years, had
always
been the policy of Spain; and the price of all European
goods,
accordingly, is said to have been enormous in the Spanish
West
Indies. At Quito, we are told by Ulloa, a pound of iron sold
for
about 4s:6d., and a pound of steel for about 6s:9d. sterling.
But it
is chiefly in order to purchase European goods that the
colonies
part with their own produce. The more, therefore, they
pay for
the one, the less they really get for the other, and the
dearness
of the one is the same thing with the cheapness of the
other.
The policy of Portugal is, in this respect, the same as
the
ancient policy of Spain, with regard to all its colonies,
except
Pernambucco and Marannon; and with regard to these it has
lately
adopted a still worse.
Other
nations leave the trade of their colonies free to all their
subjects,
who may carry it on from all the different ports of the
mother
country, and who have occasion for no other license than
the
common despatches of the custom-house. In this case the
number
and dispersed situation of the different traders renders
it
impossible for them to enter into any general combination, and
their
competition is sufficient to hinder them from making very
exorbitant
profits. Under so liberal a policy, the colonies are
enabled
both to sell their own produce, and to buy the goods of
Europe
at a reasonable price; but since the dissolution of the
Plymouth
company, when our colonies were but in their infancy,
this
has always been the policy of England. It has generally,
too,
been that of France, and has been uniformly so since the
dissolution
of what in England is commonly called their
Mississippi
company. The profits of the trade, therefore, which
France
and England carry on with their colonies, though no doubt
somewhat
higher than if the competition were free to all other
nations,
are, however, by no means exorbitant ; and the price of
European
goods, accordingly, is not extravagantly high in the
greater
past of the colonies of either of those nations.
In the
exportation of their own surplus produce, too, it is only
with
regard to certain commodities that the colonies of Great
Britain
are confined to the market of the mother country. These
commodities
having been enumerated in the act of navigation, and
in some
other subsequent acts, have upon that account been called
enumerated
commodities. The rest are called non-enumerated, and
may be
exported directly to other countries, provided it is in
British
or plantation ships, of which the owners and three
fourths
of the mariners are British subjects
Among
the non-enumerated commodities are some of the most
important
productions of America and the West Indies, grain of
all
sorts, lumber, salt provisions, fish, sugar, and rum.
Grain
is naturally the first and principal object of the culture
of all
new colonies. By allowing them a very extensive market for
it, the
law encourages them to extend this culture much beyond
the
consumption of a thinly inhabited country, and thus to
provide
beforehand an ample subsistence for a continually
increasing
population.
In a
country quite covered with wood, where timber consequently
is of
little or no value, the expense of clearing the ground is
the
principal obstacle to improvement. By allowing the colonies a
very
extensive market for their lumber, the law endeavours to
facilitate
improvement by raising the price of a commodity which
would
otherwise be of little value, and thereby enabling them to
make
some profit of what would otherwise be mere expense.
In a
country neither half peopled nor half cultivated, cattle
naturally
multiply beyond the consumption of the inhabitants, and
are
often, upon that account, of little or no value. But it is
necessary,
it has already been shown, that the price of cattle
should
bear a certain proportion to that of corn, before the
greater
part of the lands of any country can be improved. By
allowing
to American cattle, in all shapes, dead and alive, a
very
extensive market, the law endeavours to raise the value of a
commodity,
of which the high price is so very essential to
improvement.
The good effects of this liberty, however, must be
somewhat
diminished by the 4th of Geo. III. c. 15, which puts
hides
and skins among the enumerated commodities, and thereby
tends
to reduce the value of American cattle.
To
increase the shipping and naval power of Great Britain by the
extension
of the fisheries of our colonies, is an object which
the
legizslature seems to have had almost constantly in view.
Those
fisheries, upon this account, have had all the
encouragement
which freedom can give them, and they have
flourished
accordingly. The New England fishery, in particular,
was,
before the late disturbances, one of the most important,
perhaps,
in the world. The whale fishery which, notwithstanding
an
extravagant bounty, is in Great Britain carried on to so
little
purpose, that in the opinion of many people ( which I do
not,
however, pretend to warrant), the whole produce does not
much
exceed the value of the bounties which are annually paid for
it, is
in New England carried on, without any bounty, to a very
great
extent. Fish is one of the principal articles with which
the
North Americans trade to Spain, Portugal, and the
Mediterranean.
Sugar
was originally an enumerated commodity, which could only be
exported
to Great Britain; but in 1751, upon a representation of
the
sugar-planters, its exportation was permitted to all parts of
the
world. The restrictions, however, with which this liberty was
granted,
joined to the high price of sugar in Great Britain, have
rendered
it in a great measure ineffectual. Great Britain and her
colonies
still continue to be almost the sole market for all
sugar
produced in the British plantations. Their consumption
increases
so fast, that, though in consequence of the increasing
improvement
of Jamaica, as well as of the ceded islands, the
importation
of sugar has increased very greatly within these
twenty
years, the exportation to foreign countries is said to be
not
much greater than before.
Rum is
a very important article in the trade which the Americans
carry
on to the coast of Africa, from which they bring back negro
slaves
in return.
If the
whole surplus produce of America, in grain of all sorts,
in salt
provisions, and in fish, had been put into the
enumeration,
and thereby forced into the market of Great Britain,
it
would have interferred too much with the produce of the
industry
of our own people. It was probably not so much from any
regard
to the interest of America, as from a jealousy of this
interference,
that those important commodities have not only been
kept
out of the enumeration, but that the importation into Great
Britain
of all grain, except rice, and of all salt provisions,
has, in
the ordinary state of the law, been prohibited.
The
non-enumerated commodities could originally be exported to
all
parts of the world. Lumber and rice having been once put into
the
enumeration, when they were afterwards taken out of it, were
confined,
as to the European market, to the countries that lie
south
of Cape Finisterre. By the 6th of George III. c. 52, all
non-enumerated
commodities were subjected to the like
restriction.
The parts of Europe which lie south of Cape
Finisterre
are not manufacturing countries, and we are less
jealous
of the colony ships carrying home from them any
manufactures
which could interfere with our own.
The
enumerated commodities are of two sorts ; first, such as are
either
the peculiar produce of America, or as cannot be produced,
or at
least are not produced in the mother country. Of this kind
are
molasses, coffee, cocoa-nuts, tobacco, pimento, ginger,
whalefins,
raw silk, cotton, wool, beaver, and other peltry of
America,
indigo, fustick, and other dyeing woods; secondly, such
as are
not the peculiar produce of America, but which are, and
may be
produced in the mother country, though not in such
quantities
as to supply the greater part of her demand, which is
principally
supplied from foreign countries. Of this kind are all
naval
stores, masts, yards, and bowsprits, tar, pitch, and
turpentine,
pig and bar iron, copper ore, hides and skins, pot
and
pearl ashes. The largest importation of commodities of the
first
kind could not discourage the growth, or interfere with the
sale,
of any part of the produce of the mother country. By
confining
them to the home market, our merchants, it was
expected,
would not only be enabled to buy them cheaper in the
plantations,
and consequently to sell them with a better profit
at home,
but to establish between the plantations and foreign
countries
an advantageous carrying trade, of which Great Britain
was
necessarily to be the centre or emporium, as the European
country
into which those commodities were first to be imported.
The importation
of commodities of the second kind might be so
managed
too, it was supposed, as to interfere, not with the sale
of
those of the same kind which were produced at home, but with
that of
those which were imported from foreign countries ;
because,
by means of proper duties, they might be rendered always
somewhat
dearer than the former, and yet a good deal cheaper than
the
latter. By confining such commodities to the home market,
therefore,
it was proposed to discourage the produce, not of
Great
Britain, but of some foreign countries with which the
balance
of trade was believed to be unfavourable to Great
Britain.
The prohibition of exporting from the
colonies to any other
country
but Great Britain, masts, yards, and bowsprits, tar,
pitch,
and turpentine, naturally tended to lower the price of
timber
in the colonies, and consequently to increase the expense
of
clearing their lands, the principal obstacle to their
improvement.
But about the beginning of the present century, in
1703,
the pitch and tar company of Sweden endeavoured to raise
the
price of their commodities to Great Britain, by prohibiting
their
exportation, except in their own ships, at their own price,
and in
such quantities as they thought proper. In order to
counteract
this notable piece of mercantile policy, and to render
herself
as much as possible independent, not only of Sweden, but
of all
the other northern powers, Great Britain gave a bounty
upon
the importation of naval stores from America; and the effect
of this
bounty was to raise the price of timber in America much
more
than the confinement to the home market could lower it; and
as both
regulations were enacted at the same time, their joint
effect
was rather to encourage than to discourage the clearing of
land in
America.
Though
pig and bar iron, too, have been put among the enumerated
commodities,
yet as, when imported from America, they are
exempted
from considerable duties to which they are subject when
imported
front any other country, the one part of the regulation
contributes
more to encourage the erection of furnaces in America
than
the other to discourage it. There is no manufacture which
occasions
so great a consumption of wood as a furnace, or which
can
contribute so much to the clearing of a country overgrown
with
it.
The
tendency of some of these regulations to raise the value of
timber
in America, and thereby to facilitate the clearing of the
land,
was neither, perhaps, intended nor understood by the
legislature.
Though their beneficial effects, however, have been
in this
respect accidental, they have not upon that account been
less
real.
The
most perfect freedom of trade is permitted between the
British
colonies of America and the West Indies, both in the
enumerated
and in the non-enumerated commodities Those colonies
are now
become so populous and thriving, that each of them finds
in some
of the others a great and extensive market for every part
of its
produce. All of them taken together, they make a great
internal
market for the produce of one another.
The
liberality of England, however, towards the trade of her
colonies,
has been confined chiefly to what concerns the market
for
their produce, either in its rude state, or in what may be
called
the very first stage of manufacture. The more advanced or
more
refined manufactures, even of the colony produce, the
merchants
and manufacturers of Great Britain chuse to reserve to
themselves,
and have prevailed upon the legislature to prevent
their
establishment in the colonies, sometimes by high duties,
and
sometimes by absolute prohibitions.
While,
for example, Muscovado sugars from the British plantations
pay,
upon importation, only 6s:4d. the hundred weight, white
sugars
pay £1:1:1; and refined, either double or single, in
loaves,
£4:2:5 8/20ths. When those high duties were imposed,
Great
Britain was the sole, and she still continues to be, the
principal
market, to which the sugars of the British colonies
could
be exported. They amounted, therefore, to a prohibition, at
first
of claying or refining sugar for any foreign market, and at
present
of claying or refining it for the market which takes off,
perhaps,
more than nine-tenths of the whole produce. The
manufacture
of claying or refining sugar, accordingly, though it
has
flourished in all the sugar colonies of France, has been
little
cultivated in any of those of England, except for the
market
of the colonies themselves. While Grenada was in the hands
of the
French, there was a refinery of sugar, by claying, at
least
upon almost every plantation. Since it fell into those of
the
English, almost all works of this kind have been given up;
and
there are at present (October 1773), I am assured, not above
two or
three remaining in the island. At present, however, by an
indulgence
of the custom-house, clayed or refined sugar, if
reduced
from loaves into powder, is commonly imported as
Muscovado.
While
Great Britain encourages in America the manufacturing of
pig and
bar iron, by exempting them from duties to which the like
commodities
are subject when imported from any other country, she
imposes
an absolute prohibition upon the erection of steel
furnaces
and slit-mills in any of her American plantations. She
will
not suffer her colonies to work in those more refined
manufactures,
even for their own consumption ; but insists upon
their
purchasing of her merchants and manufacturers all goods of
this
kind which they have occasion for.
She
prohibits the exportation from one province to another by
water,
and even the canriage by land upon horseback, or in a
cart,
of hats, of wools, and woollen goods, of the produce of
America;
a regulation which effectually prevents the
establishment
of any manufacture of such commodities for distant
sale,
and confines the industry of her colonists in this way to
such
coarse and household manufactures as a private family
commonly
makes for its own use, or for that of some of its
neighbours
in the same province.
To
prohibit a great people, however, from making all that they
can of
every part of their own produce, or from employing their
stock
and industry in the way that they judge most advantageous
to
themselves, is a manifest violation of the most sacred rights
of
mankind. Unjust, however, as such prohibitions may be, they
have
not hitherto been very hurtful to the colonies. Land is
still
so cheap, and, consequently, labour so dear among them,
that
they can import from the mother country almost all the more
refined
or more advanced manufactures cheaper than they could
make
them for themselves. Though they had not, therefore, been
prohibited
from establishing such manufactures, yet, in their
present
state of improvement, a regard to their own interest
would
probably have prevented them from doing so. In their
present
state of improvement, those prohibitions, perhaps,
without
cramping their industry, or restraining it from any
employment
to which it would have gone of its own accord, are
only
impertinent badges of slavery imposed upon them, without any
sufficient
reason, by the groundless jealousy of the merchants
and
manufacturers of the mother country. In a more advanced
state,
they might be really oppressive and insupportable.
Great
Britain, too, as she confines to her own market some of the
most
important productions of the colonies, so, in compensation,
she
gives to some of them an advantage in that market, sometimes
by
imposing higher duties upon the like productions when imported
from
other countries, and sometimes by giving bounties upon their
importation
from the colonies. In the first way, she gives an
advantage
in the home market to the sugar, tobacco, and iron of
her own
colonies; and, in the second, to their raw silk, to their
hemp
and flax, to their indigo, to their naval stores, and to
their
building timber. This second way of encouraging the colony
produce,
by bounties upon importation, is, so far as I have been
able to
learn, peculiar to Great Britain: the first is not.
Portugal
does not content herself with imposing higher duties
upon
the importation of tobacco from any other country, but
prohibits
it under the severest penalties.
With
regard to the importation of goods from Europe, England has
likewise
dealt more liberally with her colonies than any other
nation.
Great
Britain allows a part, almost always the half, generally a
larger
portion, and sometimes the whole, of the duty which is
paid
upon the importation of foreign goods, to be drawn back upon
their
exportation to any foreign country. No independent foreign
country,
it was easy to foresee, would receive them, if they came
to it
loaded with the heavy duties to which almost all foreign
goods
are subjected on their importation into Great Britain.
Unless,
therefore, some part of those duties was drawn back upon
exportation,
there was an end of the carrying trade; a trade so
much
favoured by the mercantile system.
Our
colonies, however, are by no means independent foreign
countries;
and Great Britain having assumed to herself the
exclusive
right of supplying them with all goods from Europe,
might
have forced them (in the same manner as other countries
have
done their colonies) to receive such goods loaded with all
the
same duties which they paid in the mother country. But, on
the
contrary, till 1763, the same drawbacks were paid upon the
exportation
of the greater part of foreign goods to our colonies,
as to
any independent foreign country. In 1763, indeed, by the
4th of
Geo. III. c. 15, this indulgence was a good deal abated,
and it
was enacted, " That no part of the duty called the old
subsidy
should be drawn back for any goods of the growth,
production,
or manufacture of Europe or the East Indies, which
should
be exported from this kingdom to any British colony or
plantation
in America; wines, white calicoes, and muslins,
excepted."
Before this law, many different sorts of foreign goods
might
have been bought cheaper in the plantations than in the
mother
country, and some may still.
Of the
greater part of the regulations concerning the colony
trade,
the merchants who carry it on, it must be observed, have
been
the principal advisers. We must not wonder, therefore, if,
in a
great part of them, their interest has been more considered
than
either that of the colonies or that of the mother country.
In
their exclusive privilege of supplying the colonies with all
the
goods which they wanted from Europe, and of purchasing all
such
parts of their surplus produce as could not interfere with
any of
the trades which they themselves carried on at home, the
interest
of the colonies was sacrificed to the interest of those
merchants.
In allowing the same drawbacks upon the re-exportation
of the
greater part of European and East India goods to the
colonies,
as upon their re-exportation to any independent
country,
the interest of the mother country was sacrificed to it,
even
according to the mercantile ideas of that interest. It was
for the
interest of the merchants to pay as little as possible
for the
foreign goods which they sent to the colonies, and,
consequently,
to get back as much as possible of the duties which
they
advanced upon their importation into Great Britain. They
might
thereby be enabled to sell in the colonies, either the same
quantity
of goods with a greater profit, or a greater quantity
with
the same profit, and, consequently, to gain something either
in the
one way or the other. It was likewise for the interest of
the
colonies to get all such goods as cheap, and in as great
abundance
as possible. But this might not always be for the
interest
of the mother country. She might frequently suffer, both
in her
revenue, by giving back a great part of the duties which
had
been paid upon the importation of such goods; and in her
manufactures,
by being undersold in the colony market, in
consequence
of the easy terms upon which foreign manufactures
could
be carried thither by means of those drawbacks. The
progress
of the linen manufacture of Great Britain, it is
commonly
said, has been a good deal retarded by the drawbacks
upon
the re-exportation of German linen to the American colonies.
But
though the policy of Great Britain, with regard to the trade
of her
colonies, has been dictated by the same mercantile spirit
as that
of other nations, it has, however, upon the whole, been
less
illiberal and oppressive than that of any of them.
In
every thing except their foreign trade, the liberty of the
English
colonists to manage their own affairs their own way, is
complete.
It is in every respect equal to that of their
fellow-citizens
at home, and is secured in the same manner, by an
assembly
of the representatives of the people, who claim the sole
right
of imposing taxes for the support of the colony government.
The
authority of this assembly overawes the executive power ; and
neither
the meanest nor the most obnoxious colonist, as long as
he
obeys the law, has any thing to fear from the resentment,
either
of the governor, or of any other civil or military officer
in the
province. The colony assemblies, though, like the house of
commons
in England, they are not always a very equal
representation
of the people, yet they approach more nearly to
that
character ; and as the executive power either has not the
means
to corrupt them, or, on account of the support which it
receives
from the mother country, is not under the necessity of
doing
so, they are, perhaps, in general more influenced by the
inclinations
of their constituents. The councils, which, in the
colony
legislatures, correspond to the house of lords in Great
Britain,
are not composed of a hereditary nobility. In some of
the
colonies, as in three of the governments of New England,
those
councils are not appointed by the king, but chosen by the
representatives
of the people. In none of the English colonies is
there
any hereditary nobility. In all of them, indeed, as in all
other
free countries, the descendant of an old colony family is
more
respected than an upstart of equal merit and fortune; but he
is only
more respected, and he has no privileges by which he can
be
troublesome to his neighbours. Before the commencement of the
present
disturbances, the colony assemblies had not only the
legislative,
but a part of the executive power. In Connecticut
and
Rhode Island, they elected the governor. In the other
colonies,
they appointed the revenue officers, who collected the
taxes
imposed by those respective assemblies, to whom those
officers
were immediately responsible. There is more equality,
therefore,
among the English colonists than among the inhabitants
of the
mother country. Their manners are more re publican; and
their
governments, those of three of the provinces of New England
in
particular, have hitherto been more republican too.
The
absolute governments of Spain, Portugal, and France, on the
contrary,
take place in their colonies; and the discretionary
powers
which such governments commonly delegate to all their
inferior
officers are, on account of the great distance,
naturally
exercised there with more than ordinary violence. Under
all
absolute governments, there is more liberty in the capital
than in
any other part of the country. The sovereign himself can
never
have either interest or inclination to pervert the order of
justice,
or to oppress the great body of the people. In the
capital,
his presence overawes, more or less, all his inferior
officers,
who, in the remoter provinces, from whence the
complaints
of the people are less likely to reach him, can
exercise
their tyranny with much more safety. But the European
colonies
in America are more remote than the most distant
provinces
of the greatest empires which had ever been known
before.
The government of the English colonies is, perhaps, the
only
one which, since the world began, could give perfect
security
to the inhabitants of so very distant a province. The
administration
of the French colonies, however, has always been
conducted
with much more gentleness and moderation than that of
the
Spanish and Portuguese. This superiority of conduct is
suitable
both to the character of the French nation, and to what
forms
the character of every nation, the nature of their
government,
which, though arbitrary and violent in comparison
with
that of Great Britain, is legal and free in comparison with
those
of Spain and Portugal.
It is
in the progress of the North American colonies, however,
that
the superiority of the English policy chiefly appears. The
progress
of the sugar colonies of France has been at least equal,
perhaps
superior, to that of the greater part of those of
England;
and yet the sugar colonies of England enjoy a free
government,
nearly of the same kind with that which takes place
in her
colonies of North America. But the sugar colonies of
France
are not discouraged, like those of England, from refining
their
own sugar; and what is still of greater importance, the
genius
of their government naturally introduces a better
management
of their negro slaves.
In all
European colonies, the culture of the sugar-cane is
carried
on by negro slaves. The constitution of those who have
been
born in the temperate climate of Europe could not, it is
supposed,
support the labour of digging the ground under the
burning
sun of the West Indies ; and the culture of the
sugar-cane,
as it is managed at present, is all hand labour ;
though,
in the opinion of many, the drill plough might be
introduced
into it with great advantage. But, as the profit and
success
of the cultivation which is carried on by means of
cattle,
depend very much upon the good management of those cattle
; so
the profit and success of that which is carried on by slaves
must
depend equally upon the good management of those slaves ;
and in
the good management of their slaves the French planters, I
think
it is generally allowed, are superior to the English. The
law, so
far as it gives some weak protection to the slave against
the
violence of his master, is likely to be better executed in a
colony
where the government is in a great measure arbitrary, than
in one
where it is altogether free. In ever country where the
unfortunate
law of slavery is established, the magistrate, when
he
protects the slave, intermeddles in some measure in the
management
of the private property of the master ; and, in a free
country,
where the master is, perhaps, either a member of the
colony
assembly, or an elector of such a member, he dares not do
this
but with the greatest caution and circumspection. The
respect
which he is obliged to pay to the master, renders it more
difficult
for him to protect the slave. But in a country where
the
government is in a great measure arbitrary, where it is usual
for the
magistrate to intermeddle even in the management of the
private
property of individuals, and to send them, perhaps, a
lettre
de cachet, if they do not manage it according to his
liking,
it is much easier for him to give some protection to the
slave;
and common humanity naturally disposes him to do so. The
protection
of the magistrate renders the slave less contemptible
in the
eyes of his master, who is thereby induced to consider him
with
more regard, and to treat him with more gentleness. Gentle
usage
renders the slave not only more faithful, but more
intelligent,
and, therefore, upon a double account, more useful.
He
approaches more to the condition of a free servant, and may
possess
some degree of integrity and attachment to his master's
interest
; virtues which frequently belong to free servants, but
which
never can belong to a slave, who is treated as slaves
commonly
are in countries where the master is perfectly free and
secure.
That
the condition of a slave is better under an arbitrary than
under a
free government, is, I believe, supported by the history
of all
ages and nations. In the Roman history, the first time we
read of
the magistrate interposing to protect the slave from the
violence
of his master, is under the emperors. When Vidius
Pollio,
in the presence of Augustus, ordered one of his slaves,
who had
committed a slight fault, to be cut into pieces and
thrown
into his fish-pond, in order to feed his fishes, the
emperor
commanded him, with indignation, to emancipate
immediately,
not only that slave, but all the others that
belonged
to him. Under the republic no magistrate could have had
authority
enough to protect the slave, much less to punish the
master.
The
stock, it is to be observed, which has improved the sugar
colonies
of France, particularly the great colony of St Domingo,
has
been raised almost entirely from the gradual improvement and
cultivation
of those colonies. It has been almost altogether the
produce
of the soil and of the industry of the colonists, or,
what
comes to the same thing, the price of that produce,
gradually
accumulated by good management, and employed in raising
a still
greater produce. But the stock which has improved and
cultivated
the sugar colonies of England, has, a great part of
it,
been sent out from England, and has by no means been
altogether
the produce of the soil and industry of the colonists.
The
prosperity of the English sugar colonies has been in a great
measure
owing to the great riches of England, of which a part has
overflowed,
if one may say so, upon these colonies. But the
prosperity
of the sugar colonies of France has been entirely
owing
to the good conduct of the colonists, which must therefore
have
had some superiority over that of the English; and this
superiority
has been remarked in nothing so much as in the good
management
of their slaves.
Such
have been the general outlines of the policy of the
different
European nations with regard to their colonies.
The
policy of Europe, therefore, has very little to boast of,
either
in the original establishment, or, so far as concerns
their
internal government, in the subsequent prosperity of the
colonies
of America.
Folly
and injustice seem to have been the principles which
presided
over and directed the first project of establishing
those
colonies; the folly of hunting after gold and silver mines,
and the
injustice of coveting the possession of a country whose
harmless
natives, far from having ever injured the people of
Europe,
had received the first adventurers with every mark of
kindness
and hospitality.
The
adventurers, indeed, who formed some of the latter
establishments,
joined to the chimerical project of finding gold
and
silver mines, other motives more reasonable and more
laudable;
but even these motives do very little honour to the
policy
of Europe.
The
English puritans, restrained at home, fled for freedom to
America,
and established there the four governments of New
England.
The English catholics, treated with much greater
injustice,
established that of Maryland ; the quakers, that of
Pennsylvania.
The Portuguese Jews, persecuted by the inquisition,
stript
of their fortunes, and banished to Brazil, introduced, by
their
example, some sort of order and industry among the
transported
felons and strumpets by whom that colony was
originally
peopled, and taught them the culture of the
sugar-cane.
Upon all these different occasions, it was not the
wisdom
and policy, but the disorder and injustice of the European
governments,
which peopled and cultivated America.
In
effectuation some of the most important of these
establishments,
the different governments of Europe had as little
merit
as in projecting them. The conquest of Mexico was the
project,
not of the council of Spain, but of a governor of Cuba ;
and it
was effectuated by the spirit of the bold adventurer to
whom it
was entrusted, in spite of every thing which that
governor,
who soon repented of having trusted such a person,
could
do to thwart it. The conquerors of Chili and Peru, and of
almost
all the other Spanish settlements upon the continent of
America,
carried out with them no other public encouragement, but
a
general permission to make settlements and conquests in the
name of
the king of Spain. Those adventures were all at the
private
risk and expense of the adventurers. The government of
Spain
contributed scarce any thing to any of them. That of
England
contributed as little towards effectuating the
establishment
of some of its most important colonies in North
America.
When
those establishments were effectuated, and had become so
considerable
as to attract the attention of the mother country,
the
first regulations which she made with regard to them, had
always
in view to secure to herself the monopoly of their
commerce;
to confine their market, and to enlarge her own at
their
expense, and, consequently, rather to damp and discourage,
than to
quicken and forward the course of their prosperity. In
the
different ways in which this monopoly has been exercised,
consists
one of the most essential differences in the policy of
the
different European nations with regard to their colonies. The
best of
them all, that of England, is only somewhat less
illiberal
and oppressive than that of any of the rest.
In what
way, therefore, has the policy of Europe contributed
either
to the first establishment, or to the present grandeur of
the
colonies of America ? In one way, and in one way only, it has
contributed
a good deal. Magna virum mater! It bred and formed
the men
who were capable of achieving such great actions, and of
laying
the foundation of so great an empire ; and there is no
other
quarter of the world; of which the policy is capable of
forming,
or has ever actually, and in fact, formed such men. The
colonies
owe to the policy of Europe the education and great
views
of their active and enterprizing founders; and some of the
greatest
and most important of them, so far as concerns their
internal
government, owe to it scarce anything else.
PART III.
Of the
Advantages which Europe has derived From the Discovery of
America,
and from that of a Passage to the East Indies by the
Cape of
Good Hope.
Such
are the advantages which the colonies of America have
derived
from the policy of Europe.
What
are those which Europe has derived from the discovery and
colonization
of America?
Those
advantages may be divided, first, into the general
advantages
which Europe, considered as one great country, has
derived
from those great events; and, secondly, into the
particular
advantages which each colonizing country has derived
from
the colonies which particularly belong to it, in consequence
of the
authority or dominion which it exercises over them.
The
general advantages which Europe, considered as one great
country,
has derived from the discovery and colonization of
America,
consist, first, in the increase of its enjoyments ; and,
secondly,
in the augmentation of its industry.
The
surplus produce of America imported into Europe, furnishes
the
inhabitants of this great continent with a variety of
commodities
which they could not otherwise have possessed ; some
for
conveniency and use, some for pleasure, and some for ornament
; and
thereby contributes to increase their enjoyments.
The
discovery and colonization of America, it will readily be
allowed,
have contributed to augment the industry, first, of all
the
countries which trade to it directly, such as Spain,
Portugal,
France, and England; and, secondly, of all those which,
without
trading to it directly, send, through the medium of other
countries,
goods to it of their own produce, such as Austrian
Flanders,
and some provinces of Germany, which, through the
medium
of the countries before mentioned, send to it a
considerable
quantity of linen and other goods. All such
countries
have evidently gained a more extensive market for their
surplus
produce, and must consequently have been encouraged to
increase
its quantity.
But
that those great events should likewise have contributed to
encourage
the industry of countries such as Hungary and Poland,
which
may never, perhaps, have sent a single commodity of their
own
produce to America, is not, perhaps, altogether so evident.
That
those events have done so, however, cannot be doubted. Some
part of
the produce of America is consumed in Hungary and Poland,
and
there is some demand there for the sugar, chocolate. and
tobacco,
of that new quarter of the world. But those commodities
must be
purchased with something which is either the produce of
the
industry of Hungary and Poland, or with something which had
been
purchased with some part of that produce. Those commodities
of
America are new values, new equivalents, introduced into
Hungary
and Poland, to be exchanged there for the surplus produce
of
these countries. By being carried thither, they create a new
and
more extensive market for that surplus produce. They raise
its
value, and thereby contribute to encourage its increase.
Though
no part of it may ever be carried to America, it may be
carried
to other countries, which purchase it with a part of
their
share of the surplus produce of America, and it may find a
market
by means of the circulation of that trade which was
originally
put into motion by the surplus produce of America.
Those
great events may even have contributed to increase the
enjoyments,
and to augment the industry, of countries which not
only
never sent any commodities to America, but never received
any
from it. Even such countries may have received a greater
abundance
of other commodities from countries, of which the
surplus
produce had been augmented by means of the American
trade.
This greater abundance, as it must necessarily have
increased
their enjoyments, so it must likewise have augmented
their
industry. A greater number of new equivalents, of some kind
or
other, must have been presented to them to be exchanged for
the
surplus produce of that industry. A more extensive market
must
have been created for that surplus produce, so as to raise
its
value, and thereby encourage its increase. The mass of
commodities
annually thrown into the great circle of European
commerce,
and by its various revolutions annually distributed
among
all the different nations comprehended within it, must have
been
augmented by the whole surplus produce of America. A greater
share
of this greater mass, therefore, is likely to have fallen
to each
of those nations, to have increased their enjoyments, and
augmented
their industry.
The
exclusive trade of the mother countries tends to diminish, or
at
least to keep down below what they would otherwise rise to,
both
the enjoyments and industry of all those nations in general,
and of
the American colonies in particular. It is a dead weight
upon
the action of one of the great springs which puts into
motion
a great part of the business of mankind. By rendering the
colony
produce dearer in all other countries, it lessens its
consumption,
and thereby cramps the industry of the colonies, and
both
the enjoyments and the industry of all other countries,
which
both enjoy less when they pay more for what they enjoy, and
produce
less when they get less for what they produce. By
rendering
the produce of all other countries dearer in the
colonies,
it cramps in the same manner the industry of all other
colonies,
and both the enjoyments and the industry of the
colonies.
It is a clog which, for the supposed benefit of some
particular
countries, embarrasses the pleasures and encumbers the
industry
of all other countries, but of the colonies more than of
any
other. It not only excludes as much as possible all other
countries
from one particular market, but it confines as much as
possible
the colonies to one particular market; and the
difference
is very great between being excluded from one
particular
market when all others are open, and being confined to
one particular
market when all others are shut up. The surplus
produce
of the colonies, however, is the original source of all
that
increase of enjoyments and industry which Europe derives
from
the discovery and colonization of America, and the exclusive
trade
of the mother countries tends to render this source much
less
abundant than it otherwise would be.
The
particular advantages which each colonizing country derives
from
the colonies which particularly belong to it, are of two
different
kinds ; first, those common advantages which every
empire
derives from the provinces subject to its dominion ; and,
secondly,
those peculiar advantages which are supposed to result
from
provinces of so very peculiar a nature as the European
colonies
of America.
The
common advantages which every empire derives from the
provinces
subject to its dominion consist, first, in the military
force
which they furnish for its defence; and, secondly, in the
revenue
which they furnish for the support of its civil
government.
The Roman colonies furnished occasionally both the
one and
the other. The Greek colonies sometimes furnished a
military
force, but seldom any revenue. They seldom acknowledged
themselves
subject to the dominion of the mother city. They were
generally
her allies in war, but very seldom her subjects in
peace.
The
European colonies of America have never yet furnished any
military
force for the defence of the mother country. The
military
force has never yet been sufficient for their own
defence;
and in the different wars in which the mother countries
have
been engaged, the defence of their colonies has generally
occasioned
a very considerable distraction of the military force
of
those countries. In this respect, therefore, all the European
colonies
have, without exception, been a cause rather of weakness
than of
strength to their respective mother countries.
The
colonies of Spain and Portugal only have contributed any
revenue
towards the defence of the mother country, or the support
of her
civil government. The taxes which have been levied upon
those
of other European nations, upon those of England in
particular,
have seldom been equal to the expense laid out upon
them in
time of peace, and never sufficient to defray that which
they occasioned
in time of war. Such colonies, therefore, have
been a
source of expense, and not of revenue, to their respective
mother
countries.
The
advantages of such colonies to their respective mother
countries,
consist altogether in those peculiar advantages which
are
supposed to result from provinces of so very peculiar a
nature
as the European colonies of America; and the exclusive
trade,
it is acknowledged, is the sole source of all those
peculiar
advantages.
In
consequence of this exclusive trade, all that part of the
surplus
produce of the English colonies, for example, which
consists
in what are called enumerated commodities, can be sent
to no
other country but England. Other countries must afterwards
buy it
of her. It must be cheaper, therefore, in England than it
can be
in any other country, and must contribute more to increase
the
enjoyments of England than those of any other country. It
must
likewise contribute more to encourage her industry. For all
those
parts of her own surplus produce which England exchanges
for
those enumerated commodities, she must get a better price
than
any other countries can get for the like parts of theirs,
when
they exchange them for the same commodities. The
manufactures
of England, for example, will purchase a greater
quantity
of the sugar and tobacco of her own colonies than the
like
manufactures of other countries can purchase of that sugar
and
tobacco. So far, therefore, as the
manufactures of England
and
those of other countries are both to be exchanged for the
sugar
and tobacco of the English colonies, this superiority of
price
gives an encouragement to the former beyond what the latter
can, in
these circumstances, enjoy. The exclusive trade of the
colonies,
therefore, as it diminishes, or at least keeps down
below
what they would otherwise rise to, both the enjoyments and
the
industry of the countries which do not possess it, so it
gives
an evident advantage to the countries which do possess it
over
those other countries.
This
advantage, however, will, perhaps, be found to be rather
what
may be called a relative than an absolute advantage, and to
give a
superiority to the country which enjoys it, rather by
depressing
the industry and produce of other countries, than by
raising
those of that particular country above what they would
naturally
rise to in the case of a free trade.
The
tobacco of Maryland and Virginia, for example, by means of
the
monopoly which England enjoys of it, certainly comes cheaper
to
England than it can do to France to whom England commonly
sells a
considerable part of it. But had France and all other
European
countries been at all times allowed a free trade to
Maryland
and Virginia, the tobacco of those colonies might by
this
time have come cheaper than it actually does, not only to
all
those other countries, but likewise to England. The produce
of
tobacco, in consequcnce of a market so much more extensive
than
any which it has hitherto enjoyed, might, and probably
would,
by this time have been so much increased as to reduce the
profits
of a tobacco plantation to their natural level with those
of a
corn plantation, which it is supposed they are still
somewhat
above. The price of tobacco might, and probably would,
by this
time have fallen somewhat lower than it is at present. An
equal
quantity of the commodities, either of England or of those
other
countries, might have purchased in Maryland and Virginia a
greater
quantity of tobacco than it can do at present, and
consequently
have been sold there for so much a better price. So
far as
that weed, therefore, can, by its cheapness and abundance,
increase
the enjoyments, or augment the industry, either of
England
or of any other country, it would probably, in the case
of a
free trade, have produced both these effects in somewhat a
greater
degree than it can do at present. England, indeed, would
not, in
this case, have had any advantage over other countries.
She
might have bought the tobacco of her colonies somewhat
cheaper,
and consequently have sold some of her own commodities
somewhat
dearer, than she actually does ; but she could neither
have
bought the one cheaper, nor sold the other dearer, than any
other
country might have done. She might, perhaps, have gained an
absolute,
but she would certainly have lost a relative advantage.
In
order, however, to obtain this relative advantage in the
colony
trade, in order to execute the invidious and malignant
project
of excluding, as much as possible, other nations from any
share in
it, England, there are very probable reasons for
believing,
has not only sacrificed a part of the absolute
advantage
which she, as well as every other nation, might have
derived
from that trade, but has subjected herself both to an
absolute
and to a relative disadvantage in almost every other
branch
of trade.
When,
by the act of navigation, England assumed to herself the
monopoly
of the colony trade, the foreign capitals which had
before
been employed in it, were necessarily withdrawn from it.
The
English capital, which had before carried on but a part of
it, was
now to carry on the whole. The capital which had before
supplied
the colonies with but a part of the goods which they
wanted
from Europe, was now all that was employed to supply them
with
the whole. But it could not supply
them with the whole;
and the
goods with which it did supply them were necessarily sold
very
dear. The capital which had before bought but a part of the
surplus
produce of the colonies, was now all that was employed to
buy the
whole. But it could not buy the whole at any thing near
the old
price ; and therefore, whatever it did buy, it
necessarily
bought very cheap. But in an employment of capital,
in
which the merchant sold very dear, and bought very cheap, the
profit
must have been very great, and much above the ordinary
level
of profit in other branches of trade.
This superiority of
profit
in the colony trade could not fail to draw from other
branches
of trade a part of the capital which had before been
employed
in them. But this revulsion of capital, as it must have
gradually
increased the competition of capitals in the colony
trade,
so it must have gradually diminished that competition in
all
those other branches of trade ; as it must have gradually
lowered
the profits of the one, so it must have gradually raised
those
of the other, till the profits of all came to a new level,
different
from, and somewhat higher, than that at which they had
been
before.
This
double effect of drawing capital from all other trades, and
of
raising the rate of profit somewhat higher than it otherwise
would
have been in all trades, was not only produced by this
monopoly
upon its first establishment, but has continued to be
produced
by it ever since.
First, This monopoly has been continually drawing
capital from
all
other trades, to be employed in that of the colonies.
Though
the wealth of Great Britain has increased very much since
the
establishment of the act of navigation, it certainly has not
increased
in the same proportion as that or the colonies. But the
foreign
trade of every country naturally increases in proportion
to its
wealth, its surplus produce in proportion to its whole
produce;
and Great Britain having engrossed to herself almost the
whole
of what may be called the foreign trade of the colonies,
and her
capital not having increased in the same proportion as
the
extent of that trade, she could not carry it on without
continually
withdrawing from other branches of trade some part of
the
capital which had before been employed in them, as well as
withholding
from them a great deal more which would otherwise
have
gone to them. Since the
establishment of the act of
navigation,
accordingly, the colony trade has been continually
increasing,
while many other branches of foreign trade,
particularly
of that to other parts of Europe, have been
continually
decaying. Our manufactures for foreign sale, instead
of
being suited, as before the act of navigation, to the
neighbouring
market of Europe, or to the more distant one of the
countries
which lie round the Mediterranean sea, have the greater
part of
them, been accommodated to the still more distant one of
the
colonies; to the market in which they have the monopoly,
rather than
to that in which they have many competitors. The
causes
of decay in other branches of foreign trade, which, by Sir
Matthew
Decker and other writers, have been sought for in the
excess
and improper mode of taxation, in the high price of
labour,
in the increase of luxury, etc. may all be found in the
overgrowth
of the colony trade. The mercantile capital of Great
Britain,
though very great, yet not being infinite, and though
greatly
increased since the act of navigation, yet not being
increased
in the same proportion as the colony trade, that trade
could
not possibly be carried on without withdrawing some part of
that
capital from other branches of trade, nor consequently
without
some decay of those other branches.
England,
it must be observed, was a great trading country, her
mercantile
capital was very great, and likely to become still
greater
and greater every day, not only before the act of
navigation
had established the monopoly of the corn trade, but
before
that trade was very considerable. In the Dutch war, during
the
government of Cromwell, her navy was superior to that of
Holland
; and in that which broke out in the beginning of the
reign
of Charles II., it was at least equal, perhaps superior to
the
united navies of France and Holland. Its superiority,
perhaps,
would scarce appear greater in the present times, at
least
if the Dutch navy were to bear the same proportion to the
Dutch
commerce now which it did then. But
this great naval
power
could not, in either of those wars, be owing to the act of
navigation.
During the first of them, the plan of that act had
been
but just formed; and though, before the breaking out of the
second,
it had been fully enacted by legal authority, yet no part
of it
could have had time to produce any considerable effect, and
least
of all that part which established the exclusive trade to
the
colonies. Both the colonies and their trade were
inconsiderable
then, in comparison of what they are how. The
island
of Jamaica was an unwholesome desert, little inhabited,
and
less cultivated. New York and New Jersey were in the
possession
of the Dutch, the half of St. Christopher's in that of
the
French. The island of Antigua, the two Carolinas,
Pennsylvania,
Georgia, and Nova Scotia, were not planted.
Virginia,
Maryland, and New England were planted; and though they
were
very thriving colonies, yet there was not perhaps at that
time,
either in Europe or America, a single person who foresaw,
or even
suspected, the rapid progress which they have since made
in
wealth, population, and improvement. The island of Barbadoes,
in
short, was the only British colony of any consequence, of
which
the condition at that time bore any resemblance to what it
is at
present. The trade of the colonies, of which England, even
for
some time after the act of navigation, enjoyed but a part
(for
the act of navigation was not very strictly executed till
several
years after it was enacted), could not at that time be
the
cause of the great trade of England, nor of the great naval
power
which was supported by that trade. The trade which at that
time
supported that great naval power was the trade of Europe,
and of
the countries which lie round the Mediterranean sea. But
the
share which Great Britain at present enjoys of that trade
could
not support any such great naval power. Had the growing
trade
of the colonies been left free to all nations, whatever
share
of it might have fallen to Great Britain, and a very
considerable
share would probably have fallen to her, must have
been
all an addition to this great trade of which she was before
in
possession. In consequence of the monopoly, the increase of
the
colony trade has not so much occasioned an addition to the
trade
which Great Britain had before, as a total change in its
direction.
Secondly,
This monopoly has necessarily contributed to keep up
the
rate of profit, in all the different branches of British
trade,
higher than it naturally would have been, had all nations
been
allowed a free trade to the British colonies.
The
monopoly of the colony trade, as it necessarily drew towards
that
trade a greater proportion of the capital of Great Britain
than
what would have gone to it of its own accord, so, by the
expulsion
of all foreign capitals, it necessarily reduced the
whole
quantity of capital employed in that trade below what it
naturally
would have been in the case of a free trade. But, by
lessening
the competition of capitals in that branch of trade, it
necessarily
raised the rate of profit in that branch. By
lessening,
too, the competition of British capitals in all other
branches
of trade, it necessarily raised the rate of British
profit
in all those other branches. Whatever may have been, at
any
particular period since the establishment of the act of
navigation,
the state or extent of the mercantile capital of
Great
Britain, the monopoly of the colony trade must, during the
continuance
of that state, have raised the ordinary rate of
British
profit higher than it otherwise would have been, both in
that
and in all the other branches of British trade. If, since
the
establishment of the act of navigation, the ordinary rate of
British
profit has fallen considerably. as it certainly has, it
must
have fallen still lower, had not the monopoly established by
that
act contributed to keep it up.
But
whatever raises, in any country, the ordinary rate of profit
higher
than it otherwise would be, necessarily subjects that
country
both to an absolute, and to a relative disadvantage in
every
branch of trade of which she has not the monopoly.
It
subjects her to an absolute disadvantage ; because, in such
branches
of trade, her merchants cannot get this greater profit
without
selling dearer than they otherwise would do, both the
goods
of foreign countries which they import into their own, and
the
goods of their own country which they export to foreign
countries.
Their own country must both buy dearer and sell
dearer;
must both buy less, and sell less; must both enjoy less
and
produce less, than she otherwise would do.
It
subjects her to a relative disadvantage; because, in such
branches
of trade, it sets other countries, which are not subject
to the
same absolute disadvantage, either more above her or less
below
her, than they otherwise would be. It enables them both to
enjoy
more and to produce more, in proportion to what she enjoys
and
produces. It renders their superiority greater, or their
inferiority
less, than it otherwise would be. By raising the
price
of her produce above what it otherwise would be, it enables
the
merchants of other countries to undersell her in foreign
markets,
and thereby to justle her out of almost all those
branches
of trade, of which she has not the monopoly.
Our
merchants frequently complain of the high wages of British
labour,
as the cause of their manufactures being undersold in
foreign
markets; but they are silent about the high profits of
stock.
They complain of the extravagant gain of other people; but
they
say nothing of their own. The high profits of British stock,
however,
may contribute towards raising the price of British
manufactures,
in many cases, as much, and in some perhaps more,
than
the high wages of British labour.
It is
in this manner that the capital of Great Britain, one may
justly
say, has partly been drawn and partly been driven from the
greater
part of the different branches of trade of which she has
not the
monopoly ; from the trade of Europe, in particular, and
from
that of the countries which lie round the Mediterranean sea.
It has
partly been drawn from those branches of trade, by the
attraction
of superior profit in the colony trade, in consequence
of the
continual increase of that trade, and of the continual
insufficiency
of the capital which had carried it on one year to
carry
it on the next.
It has
partly been driven from them, by the advantage which the
high
rate of profit established in Great Britain gives to other
countries,
in all the different branches of trade of which Great
Britain
has not the monopoly.
As the
monopoly of the colony trade has drawn from those other
branches
a part of the British capital, which would otherwise
have
been employed in them, so it has forced into them many
foreign
capitals which would never have gone to them, had they
not
been expelled from the colony trade. In those other branches
of
trade, it has diminished the competition of British capitals,
and
thereby raised the rate of British profit higher than it
otherwise
would have been. On the contrary, it has increased the
competition
of foreign capitals, and thereby sunk the rate of
foreign
profit lower than it otherwise would have been. Both in
the one
way and in the other, it must evidently have subjected
Great
Britain to a relative disadvantage in all those other
branches
of trade.
The
colony trade, however, it may perhaps be said, is more
advantageous
to Great Britain than any other; and the monopoly,
by
forcing into that trade a greater proportion of the capital of
Great
Britain than what would otherwise have gone to it, has
turned
that capital into an employment, more advantageous to the
country
than any other which it could have found.
The
most advantageous employment of any capital to the country to
which
it belongs, is that which maintains there the greatest
quantity
of productive labour, and increases the most the annual
produce
of the land and labour of that country. But the quantity
of
productive labour which any capital employed in the foreign
trade
of consumption can maintain, is exactly in proportion, it
has
been shown in the second book, to the frequency of its
returns.
A capital of a thousand pounds, for example, employed in
a
foreign trade of consumption, of which the returns are made
regularly
once in the year, can keep in constant employment, in
the
country to which it belongs, a quantity of productive labour,
equal
to what a thousand pounds can maintain there for a year. If
the
returns are made twice or thrice in the year, it can keep in
constant
employment a quantity of productive labour, equal to
what
two or three thousand pounds can maintain there for a year.
A
foreign trade of consumption carried on with a neighbouring,
is,
upon that account, in general, more advantageous than one
carried
on with a distant country ; and, for the same reason, a
direct
foreign trade of consumption, as it has likewise been
shown
in the second book, is in general more advantageous than a
round-about
one.
But the
monopoly of the colony trade, so far as it has operated
upon
the employment of the capital of Great Britain, has, in all
cases,
forced some part of it from a foreign trade of consumption
carried
on with a neighbouring, to one carried on with a more
distant
country, and in many cases from a direct foreign trade of
consumption
to a round-about one.
First, The monopoly of the colony trade has, in
all cases,
forced
some part of the capital of Great Britain from a foreign
trade
of consumption carried on with a neighbouring, to one
carried
on with a more distant country.
It has,
in all cases, forced some part of that capital from the
trade
with Europe, and with the countries which lie round the
Mediterranean
sea, to that with the more distant regions of
America
and the West Indies ; from which the returns are
necessarily
less frequent, not only on account of the greater
distance,
but on account of the peculiar circumstances of those
countries.
New colonies, it has already been observed, are always
understocked.
Their capital is always much less than what they
could
employ with great profit and advantage in the improvement
and
cultivation of their land. They have a constant demand,
therefore,
for more capital than they have of their own ; and, in
order
to supply the deficiency of their own, they endeavour to
borrow
as much as they can of the mother country, to whom they
are,
therefore, always in debt. The most common way in which the
colonies
contract this debt, is not by borrowing upon bond of the
rich
people of the mother country, though they sometimes do this
too,
but by running as much in arrear to their correspondents,
who
supply them with goods from Europe, as those correspondents
will
allow them. Their annual returns frequently do not amount to
more
than a third, and sometimes not to so great a proportion of
what
they owe. The whole capital, therefore, which their
correspondents
advance to them, is seldom returned to Britain in
less
than three, and sometimes not in less than four or five
years.
But a British capital of a thousand pounds, for example,
which
is returned to Great Britain only once in five years, can
keep in
constant employment only one-fifth part of the British
industry
which it could maintain, if the whole was returned once
in the
year; and, instead of the quantity of industry which a
thousand
pounds could maintain for a year, can keep in constant
employment
the quantity only which two hundred pounds can
maintain
for a year. The planter, no doubt, by the high price
which
he pays for the goods from Europe, by the interest upon the
bills
which he grants at distant dates, and by the commission
upon
the renewal of those which he grants at near dates, makes
up, and
probably more than makes up, all the loss which his
correspondent
can sustain by this delay. But, though he make up
the
loss of his correspondent, he cannot make up that of Great
Britain.
In a trade of which the returns are very distant, the
profit
of the merchant may be as great or greater than in one in
which
they are very frequent and near ; but the advantage of the
country
in which he resides, the quantity of productive labour
constantly
maintained there, the annual produce of the land and
labour,
must always be much less. That the returns of the trade
to
America, and still more those of that to the West Indies, are,
in
general, not only more distant, but more irregular and more
uncertain,
too, than those of the trade to any part of Europe, or
even of
the countries which lie round the Mediterranean sea, will
readily
he allowed, I imagine, by everybody who has any
experience
of those different branches of trade.
Secondly, The monopoly of the colony trade, has, in
many
cases,
forced some part of the capital of Great Britain from a
direct
foreign trade of consumption, into a round-about one.
Among
the enumerated commodities which can be sent to no other
market
but Great Britain, there are several of which the quantity
exceeds
very much the consumption of Great Britain, and of which,
a part,
therefore, must be exported to other countries. But this
cannot
be done without forcing some part of the capital of Great
Britain
into a round-about foreign trade of consumption.
Maryland,
and Virginia, for example, send annually to Great
Britain
upwards of ninety-six thousand hogsheads of tobacco, and
the
consumption of Great Britain is said not to exceed fourteen
thousand. Upwards of eighty-two thousand hogsheads,
therefore,
must be exported to other countries, to France, to
Holland,
and, to the countries which lie round the Baltic and
Mediterranean
seas. But that part of the capital
of Great
Britain
which brings those eighty-two thousand hogsheads to Great
Britain,
which re-exports them from thence to those other
countries,
and which brings back from those other countries to
Great
Britain either goods or money in return, is employed in a
round-about
foreign trade of consumption; and is necessarily
forced
into this employment, in order to dispose of this great
surplus.
If we would compute in how many years the whole of this
capital
is likely to come back to Great Britain, we must add to
the
distance of the American returns that of the returns from
those
other countries. If, in the direct
foreign trade of
consumption
which we carry on with America, the whole capital
employed
frequently does not come back in less than three or four
years,
the whole capital employed in this round-about one is not
likely
to come back in less than four or five. If the one can
keep in
constant employment but a third or a fourth part of the
domestic
industry which could be maintained by a capital returned
once in
the year, the other can keep in constant employment but a
fourth
or a fifth part of that industry. At some of the outports
a
credit is commonly given to those foreign correspondents to
whom
they export them tobacco. At the port of London, indeed, it
is
commonly sold for ready money: the rule is Weigh and pay. At
the
port of London, therefore, the final returns of the whole
round-about
trade are more distant than the returns from America,
by the
time only which the goods may lie unsold in the warehouse;
where,
however, they may sometimes lie long enough. But, had not
the
colonies been confined to the market of Great Britain for the
sale of
their tobacco, very little more of it would probably have
come to
us than what was necessary for the home consumption. The
goods
which Great Britain purchases at present for her own
consumption
with the great surplus of tobacco which she exports
to
other countries, she would, in this case, probably have
purchased
with the immediate produce of her own industry, or with
some
part of her own manufactures. That produce, those
manufactures,
instead of being almost entirely suited to one
great
market, as at present, would probably have been fitted to a
great
number of smaller markets. Instead of one great round-about
foreign
trade of consumption, Great Britain would probably have
carried
on a great number of small direct foreign trades of the
same
kind. On account of the frequency of the returns, a part,
and
probably but a small part, perhaps not above a third or a
fourth
of the capital which at present carries on this great
round-about
trade, might have been sufficient to carry on all
those
small direct ones; might have kept inconstant employment an
equal
quantity of British industry ; and have equally supported
the
annual produce of the land and labour of Great Britain. All
the
purposes of this trade being, in this manner, answered by a
much
smaller capital, there would have been a large spare capital
to
apply to other purposes; to improve the lands, to increase the
manufactures,
and to extend the commerce of Great Britain; to
come
into competition at least with the other British capitals
employed
in all those different ways, to reduce the rate of
profit
in them all, and thereby to give to Great Britain, in all
of
them, a superiority over other countries, still greater than
what
she at present enjoys.
The
monopoly of the colony trade, too, has forced some part of
the
capital of Great Britain from all foreign trade of
consumption
to a carrying trade; and, consequently from
supporting
more or less the industry of Great Britain, to be
employed
altogether in supporting partly that of the colonies,
and partly
that of some other countries.
The
goods, for example, which are annually purchased with the
great
surplus of eighty-two thousand hogsheads of tobacco
annually
re-exported from Great Britain, are not all consumed in
Great
Britain. Part of them, linen from Germany and Holland, for
example,
is returned to the colonies for their particular
consumption.
But that part of the capital of Great Britain which
buys
the tobacco with which this linen is afterwards bought, is
necessarily
withdrawn from supporting the industry of Great
Britain,
to be employed altogether in supporting, partly that of
the
colonies, and partly that of the particular countries who pay
for
this tobacco with the produce of their own industry.
The
monopoly of the colony trade, besides, by forcing towards it
a much
greater proportion of the capital of Great Britain than
what
would naturally have gone to it, seems to have broken
altogether
that natural balance which would otherwise have taken
place
among all the different branches of British industry. The
industry
of Great Britain, instead of being accommodated to a
great
number of small markets, has been principally suited to one
great
market. Her commerce, instead of running in a great number
of
small channels, has been taught to run principally in one
great
channel. But the whole system of her industry and commerce
has
thereby been rendered less secure; the whole state of her
body
politic less healthful than it otherwise would have been. In
her
present condition, Great Britain resembles one of those
unwholesome
bodies in which some of the vital parts are
overgrown,
and which, upon that account, are liable to many
dangerous
disorders, scarce incident to those in which all the
parts
are more properly proportioned. A small stop in that great
blood-vessel,
which has been artificially swelled beyond its
natural
dimensions, and through which an unnatural proportion of
the
industry and commerce of the country has been forced to
circulate,
is very likely to bring on the most dangerous
disorders
upon the whole body politic. The expectation of a
rupture
with the colonies, accordingly, has struck the people of
Great
Britain with more terror than they ever felt for a Spanish
armada,
or a French invasion. It was this terror, whether well or
ill
grounded, which rendered the repeal of the stamp act, among
the
merchants at least, a popular measure.
In the total
exclusion
from the colony market, was it to last only for a few
years,
the greater part of our merchants used to fancy that they
foresaw
an entire stop to their trade; the greater part of our
master
manufacturers, the entire ruin of their business; and the
greater
part of our workmen, an end of their employment. A
rupture
with any of our neighbours upon the continent, though
likely,
too, to occasion some stop or interruption in the
employments
of some of all these different orders of people, is
foreseen,
however, without any such general emotion. The blood,
of
which the circulation is stopt in some of the smaller vessels,
easily
disgorges itself into the greater, without occasioning any
dangerous
disorder; but, when it is stopt in any of the greater
vessels,
convulsions, apoplexy, or death, are the immediate and
unavoidable
consequences. If but one of those
overgrown
manufactures,
which, by means either of bounties or of the
monopoly
of the home and colony markets, have been artificially
raised
up to any unnatural height, finds some small stop or
interruption
in its employment, it frequently occasions a mutiny
and
disorder alarming to government, and embarrassing even to the
deliberations
of the legislature. How great, therefore, would be
the
disorder and confusion, it was thought, which must
necessarily
be occasioned by a sudden and entire stop in the
employment
of so great a proportion of our principal
manufacturers?
Some
moderate and gradual relaxation of the laws which give to
Great
Britain the exclusive trade to the colonies, till it is
rendered
in a great measure free, seems to be the only expedient
which
can, in all future times, deliver her from this danger ;
which
can enable her, or even force her, to withdraw some part of
her
capital from this overgrown employment, and to turn it,
though
with less profit, towards other employments; and which, by
gradually
diminishing one branch of her industry, and gradually
increasing
all the rest, can, by degrees, restore all the
different
branches of it to that natural, healthful, and proper
proportion,
which perfect liberty necessarily establishes, and
which
perfect liberty can alone preserve. To open the colony
trade
all at once to all nations, might not only occasion some
transitory
inconveniency, but a great permanent loss, to the
greater
part of those whose industry or capital is at present
engaged
in it. The sudden loss of the employment, even of the
ships
which import the eighty-two thousand hogsheads of tobacco,
which
are over and above the consumption of Great Britain, might
alone
be felt very sensibly. Such are the unfortunate effects of
all the
regulations of the mercantile system. They not only
introduce
very dangerous disorders into the state of the body
politic,
but disorders which it is often difficult to remedy,
without
occasioning, for a time at least, still greater
disorders.
In what manner, therefore, the colony trade ought
gradually
to be opened ; what are the restraints which ought
first,
and what are those which ought last, to be taken away ; or
in what
manner the natural system of perfect liberty and justice
ought
gradually to be restored, we must leave to the wisdom of
future
statesmen and legislators to determine.
Five
different events, unforeseen and unthought of, have very
fortunately
concurred to hinder Great Britain from feeling, so
sensibly
as it was generally expected she would, the total
exclusion
which has now taken place for more than a year (from
the
first of December 1774) from a very important branch of the
colony
trade, that of the twelve associated provinces of North
America.
First, those colonies, in preparing themselves for their
non-importation
agreement, drained Great Britain completely of
all the
commodities which were fit for their market ; secondly,
the
extra ordinary demand of the Spanish flota has, this year,
drained
Germany and the north of many commodities, linen in
particular,
which used to come into competition, even in the
British
market, with the manufactures of Great Britain; thirdly,
the
peace between Russia and Turkey has occasioned an
extraordinary
demand from the Turkey market, which, during the
distress
of the country, and while a Russian fleet was cruizing
in the
Archipelago, had been very poorly supplied ; fourthly, the
demand
of the north of Europe for the manufactures of Great
Britain
has been increasing from year to year, for some time
past;
and, fifthly, the late partition, and consequential
pacification
of Poland, by opening the market of that great
country,
have, this year, added an extraordinary demand from
thence
to the increasing demand of the north. These events are
all,
except the fourth, in their nature transitory and
accidental;
and the exclusion from so important a branch of the
colony
trade, if unfortunately it should continue much longer,
may
still occasion some degree of distress. This distress,
however,
as it will come on gradually, will be felt much less
severely
than if it had come on all at once ; and, in the mean
time,
the industry and capital of the country may find a new
employment
and direction, so as to prevent this distress from
ever
rising to any considerable height.
The
monopoly of the colony trade, therefore, so far as it has
turned
towards that trade a greater proportion of the capital of
Great
Britain than what would otherwise have gone to it, has in
all
cases turned it, from a foreign trade of consumption with a
neighbouring,
into one with a more distant country ; in many
cases
from a direct foreign trade of consumption into a
round-about
one; and, in some cases, from all foreign trade of
consumption
into a carrying trade. It has, in all cases,
therefore,
turned it from a direction in which it would have
maintained
a greater quantity of productive labour, into one in
which
it can maintain a much smaller quantity. By suiting,
besides,
to one particular market only, so great a part of the
industry
and commerce of Great Britain, it has rendered the whole
state
of that industry and commerce more precarious and less
secure,
than if their produce had been accommodated to a greater
variety
of markets.
We must
carefully distinguish between the effects of the colony
trade
and those of the monopoly of that trade. The former are
always
and necessarily beneficial ; the latter always and
necessarily
hurtful. But the former are so beneficial, that the
colony
trade, though subject to a monopoly, and, notwithstanding
the
hurtful effects of that monopoly, is still, upon the whole,
beneficial,
and greatly beneficial, though a good deal less so
than it
otherwise would be.
The
effect of the colony trade, in its natural and free state, is
to open
a great though distant market, for such parts of the
produce
of British industry as may exceed the demand of the
markets
nearer home, of those of Europe, and of the countries
which
lie round the Mediterranean sea. In its natural and free
state,
the colony trade, without drawing from those markets any
part of
the produce which had ever been sent to them, encourages
Great
Britain to increase the surplus continually, by continually
presenting
new equivalents to be exchanged for it. In its natural
and
free state, the colony trade tends to increase the quantity
of
productive labour in Great Britain, but without altering in
any
respect the direction of that which had been employed there
before.
In the natural and free state of the colony trade, the
competition
of all other nations would hinder the rate of profit
from
rising above the common level, either in the new market, or
in the
new employment. The new market, without drawing any thing
from
the old one, would create, if one may say so, a new produce
for its
own supply ; and that new produce would constitute a new
capital
for carrying on the new employment, which, in the same
manner,
would draw nothing from the old one.
The
monopoly of the colony trade, on the contrary, by excluding
the
competition of other nations, and thereby raising the rate of
profit,
both in the new market and in the new employment, draws
produce
from the old market, and capital from the old employment.
To augment
our share of the colony trade beyond what it otherwise
would
be, is the avowed purpose of the monopoly. If our share of
that
trade were to be no greater with, than it would have been
without
the monopoly, there could have been no reason for
establishing
the monopoly. But whatever forces into a branch of
trade,
of which the returns are slower and more distant than
those
of the greater part of other trades, a greater proportion
of the
capital of any country, than what of its own accord would
go to
that branch, necessarily renders the whole quantity of
productive
labour annually maintained there, the whole annual
produce
of the land and labour of that country, less than they
otherwise
would be. It keeps down the revenue of the inhabitants
of that
country below what it would naturally rise to, and
thereby
diminishes their power of accumulation. It not only
hinders,
at all times, their capital from maintaining so great a
quantity
of productive labour as it would otherwise maintain, but
it hinders
it from increasing so fast as it would otherwise
increase,
and, consequently, from maintaining a still greater
quantity
of productive labour.
The
natural good effects of the colony trade, however, more than
counterbalance
to Great Britain the bad effects of the monopoly ;
so
that, monopoly and altogether, that trade, even as it is
carried
on at present, is not only advantageous, but greatly
advantageous.
The new market and the new employment which are
opened
by the colony trade, are of much greater extent than that
portion
of the old market and of the old employment which is lost
by the
monopoly. The new produce and the new capital which has
been
created, if one may say so, by the colony trade, maintain in
Great
Britain a greater quantity of productive labour than what
can
have been thrown out of employment by the revulsion of
capital
from other trades of which the returns are more frequent.
If the
colony trade, however, even as it is carried on at
present,
is advantageous to Great Britain, it is not by means of
the
monopoly, but in spite of the monopoly.
It is
rather for the manufactured than for the rude produce of
Europe,
that the colony trade opens a new market. Agriculture is
the
proper business of all new colonies; a business which the
cheapness
of land renders more advantageous than any other. They
abound,
therefore, in the rude produce of land ; and instead of
importing
it from other countries, they have generally a large
surplus
to export. In new colonies,
agriculture either draws
hands
from all other employments, or keeps them from going to any
other
employment. There are few hands to spare for the necessary,
and
none for the ornamental manufactures. The greater part of the
manufactures
of both kinds they find it cheaper to purchase of
other
countries than to make for themselves. It is chiefly by
encouraging
the manufactures of Europe, that the colony trade
indirectly
encourages its agriculture. The manufacturers of
Europe,
to whom that trade gives employment, constitute a new
market
for the produce of the land, and the most advantageous of
all
markets ; the home market for the corn and cattle, for the
bread
and butcher's meat of Europe, is thus greatly extended by
means
of the trade to America.
But that
the monopoly of the trade of populous and thriving
colonies
is not alone sufficient to establish, or even to
maintain,
manufactures in any country, the examples of Spain and
Portugal
sufficiently demonstrate. Spain and Portugal were
manufacturing
countries before they had any considerable
colonies. Since they had the richest and most
fertile in the
world,
they have both ceased to be so.
In
Spain and Portugal, the bad effects of the monopoly,
aggravated
by other causes, have, perhaps, nearly overbalanced
the
natural good effects of the colony trade. These causes seem
to be
other monopolies of different kinds: the degradation of the
value
of gold and silver below what it is in most other countries
; the
exclusion from foreign markets by improper taxes upon
exportation,
and the narrowing of the home market, by still more
improper
taxes upon the transportation of goods from one part of
the
country to another ; but above all, that irregular and
partial
administration of justice which often protects the rich
and
powerful debtor from the pursuit of his injured creditor, and
which
makes the industrious part of the nation afraid to prepare
goods
for the consumption of those haughty and great men, to whom
they
dare not refuse to sell upon credit, and from whom they are
altogether
uncertain of repayment.
In
England, on the contrary, the natural good effects of the
colony
trade, assisted by other causes, have in a great measure
conquered
the bad effects of the monopoly. These causes seem to
be, the
general liberty of trade, which, notwithstanding some
restraints,
is at least equal, perhaps superior, to what it is in
any
other country ; the liberty of exporting, duty free, almost
all
sorts of goods which are the produce of domestic industry, to
almost
any foreign country; and what, perhaps, is of still
greater
importance, the unbounded liberty of transporting them
from
one part of our own country to any other, without being
obliged
to give any account to any public office, without being
liable
to question or examination of any kind; but, above all,
that
equal and impartial administration of justice, which renders
the
rights of the meanest British subject respectable to the
greatest,
and which, by securing to every man the fruits of his
own
industry, gives the greatest and most effectual encouragement
to
every sort of industry.
If the
manufactures of Great Britain, however, have been
advanced,
as they certainly have, by the colony trade, it has not
been by
means of the monopoly of that trade, but in spite of the
monopoly. The effect of the monopoly has been, not
to augment
the
quantity, but to alter the quality and shape of a part of the
manufactures
of Great Britain, and to accommodate to a market,
from
which the returns are slow and distant, what would otherwise
have
been accommodated to one from which the returns are frequent
and
near. Its effect has consequently been, to turn a part of the
capital
of Great Britain from an employment in which it would
have
maintained a greater quantity of manufacturing industry, to
one in
which it maintains a much smaller, and thereby to
diminish,
instead of increasing, the whole quantity of
manufacturing
industry maintained in Great Britain.
The
monopoly of the colony trade, therefore, like all the other
mean
and malignant expedients of the mercantile system, depresses
the
industry of all other countries, but chiefly that of the
colonies,
without in the least increasing, but on the contrary
diminishing,
that of the country in whose favour it is
established.
The
monopoly hinders the capital of that country, whatever may,
at any
particular time, be the extent of that capital, from
maintaining
so great a quantity of productive labour as it would
otherwise
maintain, and from affording so great a revenue to the
industrious
inhabitants as it would otherwise afford. But as
capital
can be increased only by savings from revenue, the
monopoly,
by hindering it from affording so great a revenue as it
would
otherwise afford, necessarily hinders it from increasing so
fast as
it would otherwise increase, and consequently from
maintaining
a still greater quantity of productive labour, and
affording
a still greater revenue to the industrious inhabitants
of that
country. One great original source of revenue, therefore,
the
wages of labour, the monopoly must necessarily have rendered,
at all
times, less abundant than it otherwise would have been.
By
raising the rate of mercantile profit, the monopoly
discourages
the improvement of land. The profit of improvement
depends
upon the difference between what the land actually
produces,
and what, by the application of a certain capital, it
can be
made to produce. If this difference affords a greater
profit
than what can be drawn from an equal capital in any
mercantile
employment, the improvement of land will draw capital
from
all mercantile employments. If the profit is less,
mercantile
employments will draw capital from the improvement of
land.
Whatever, therefore, raises the rate of mercantile profit,
either
lessens the superiority, or increases the inferiority of
the
profit of improvement : and, in the one case, hinders capital
from
going to improvement, and in the other draws capital from
it; but
by discouraging improvement, the monopoly necessarily
retards
the natural increase of another great original source of
revenue,
the rent of land. By raising the
rate of profit,
too,
the monopoly necessarily keeps up the market rate of
interest
higher than it otherwise would be. But the price of
land,
in proportion to the rent which it affords, the number of
years
purchase which is commonly paid for it, necessarily falls
as the
rate of interest rises, and rises as the rate of interest
falls. The monopoly, therefore, hurts the
interest of the
landlord
two different ways, by retarding the natural increase,
first,
of his rent, and, secondly, of the price which he would
get for
his land, in proportion to the rent which it affords.
The
monopoly, indeed, raises the rate of mercantile profit and
thereby
augments somewhat the gain of our merchants. But as it
obstructs
the natural increase of capital, it tends rather to
diminish
than to increase the sum total of the revenue which the
inhabitants
of the country derive from the profits of stock ; a
small
profit upon a great capital generally affording a greater
revenue
than a great profit upon a small one. The monopoly raises
the
rate of profit, but it hinders the sum of profit from rising
so high
as it otherwise would do.
All the
original sources of revenue, the wages of labour, the
rent of
land, and the profits of stock, the monopoly renders much
less
abundant than they otherwise would be. To promote the little
interest
of one little order of men in one country, it hurts the
interest
of all other orders of men in that country, and of all
the men
in all other countries.
It is
solely by raising the ordinary rate of profit, that the
monopoly
either has proved, or could prove, advantageous to any
one particular
order of men. But besides all the
bad effects
to the
country in general, which have already been mentioned as
necessarily
resulting from a higher rate of profit, there is one
more
fatal, perhaps, than all these put together, but which, if
we may
judge from experience, is inseparably connected with it.
The
high rate of profit seems everywhere to destroy that
parsimony
which, in other circumstances, is natural to the
character
of the merchant. When profits are high, that sober
virtue
seems to be superfluous, and expensive luxury to suit
better
the affluence of his situation. But the
owners of the
great
mercantile capitals are necessarily the leaders and
conductors
of the whole industry of every nation; and their
example
has a much greater influence upon the manners of the
whole
industrious part of it than that of any other order of men.
If his
employer is attentive and parsimonious, the workman is
very
likely to be so too; but if the master is dissolute and
disorderly,
the servant, who shapes his work according to the
pattern
which his master prescribes to him, will shape his life,
too,
according to the example which he sets him. Accumulation is
thus
prevented in the hands of all those who are naturally the
most
disposed to accumulate; and the funds destined for the
maintenance
of productive labour, receive no augmentation from
the
revenue of those who ought naturally to augment them the
most. The capital of the country, instead of
increasing,
gradually
dwindles away, and the quantity of productive labour
maintained
in it grows every day less and less. Have the
exorbitant
profits of the merchants of Cadiz and Lisbon augmented
the
capital of Spain and Portugal ? Have they alleviated the
poverty,
have they promoted the industry, of those two beggarly
countries?
Such has been the tone of mercantile expense in those
two
trading cities, that those exorbitant profits, far from
augmenting
the general capital of the country, seem scarce to
have
been sufficient to keep up the capitals upon which they were
made.
Foreign capitals are every day intruding themselves, if I
may say
so, more and more into the trade of Cadiz and Lisbon. It
is to
expel those foreign capitals from a trade which their own
grows
every day more and more insufficient for carrying on, that
the
Spaniards and Portuguese endeavour every day to straiten more
and
more the galling bands of their absurd monopoly. Compare the
mercantile
manners of Cadiz and Lisbon with those of Amsterdam,
and you
will be sensible how differently the conduct and
character
of merchants are affected by the high and by the low
profits
of stock. The merchants of London, indeed, have not yet
generally
become such magnificent lords as those of Cadiz and
Lisbon;
but neither are they in general such attetitive and
parsimonious
burghers as those of Amsterdam. They are supposed,
however,
many of them, to be a good deal richer than the greater
part of
the former, and not quire so rich as many of the latter:
but the
rate of their profit is commonly much lower than that of
the
former, and a good deal higher than that of the latter. Light
come,
light go, says the proverb ; and the ordinary tone of
expense
seems everywhere to be regulated, not so much according
to the
real ability of spending, as to the supposed facility of
getting
money to spend.
It is
thus that the single advantage which the monopoly procures
to a
single order of men, is in many different ways hurtful to
the
general interest of the country.
To
found a great empire for the sole purpose of raising up a
people
of customers, may at first sight, appear a project fit
only
for a nation of shopkeepers. It is, however, a project
altogether
unfit for a nation of shopkeepers, but extremely fit
for a
nation whose government is influenced by shopkeepers. Such
statesmen,
and such statesmen only, are capable of fancying that
they
will find some advantage in employing the blood and treasure
of
their fellow-citizens, to found and maintain such an empire.
Say to
a shopkeeper, Buy me a good estate, and I shall always buy
my
clothes at your shop, even though I should pay somewhat dearer
than
what I can have them for at other shops ; and you will not
find
him very forward to embrace your proposal.
But should
any other
person buy you such an estate, the shopkeeper will be
much
obliged to your benefactor if he would enjoin you to buy all
your
clothes at his shop. England purchased for some of her
subjects,
who found themselves uneasy at home, a great estate in
a
distant country. The price, indeed, was very small, and instead
of
thirty years purchase, the ordinary price of land in the
present
times, it amounted to little more than the expense of the
different
equipments which made the first discovery, reconoitered
the
coast, and took a fictitious possession of the country. The
land
was good, and of great extent; and the cultivators having
plenty
of good ground to work upon, and being for some time at
liberty
to sell their produce where they pleased, became, in the
course
of little more than thirty or forty years (between 1620
and
1660), so numerous and thriving a people, that the
shopkeepers
and other traders of England wished to secure to
themselves
the monopoly of their custom.
Without pretending,
therefore,
that they had paid any part, either of the original
purchase
money, or of the subsequent expense of improvement, they
petitioned
the parliament, that the cultivators of America might
for the
future be confined to their shop; first, for buying all
the
goods which they wanted from Europe; and, secondly, for
selling
all such parts of their own produce as those traders
might
find it convenient to buy. For they did not find it
convenient
to buy every part of it. Some parts of it imported
into England,
might have interfered with some of the trades which
they
themselves carried on at home. Those particular parts of it,
therefore,
they were willing that the colonists should sell where
they
could; the farther off the better; and upon that account
proposed
that their market should be confined to the countries
south
of Cape Finisterre. A clause in the famous act of
navigation
established this truly shopkeeper proposal into a law.
The
maintenance of this monopoly has hitherto been the principal,
or more
properly, perhaps, the sole end and purpose of the
dominion
which Great Britain assumes over her colonies. In the
exclusive
trade, it is supposed, consists the great advantage of
provinces,
which have never yet afforded either revenue or
military
force for the support of the civil government, or the
defence
of the mother country. The monopoly is the principal
badge
of their dependency, and it is the sole fruit which has
hitherto
been gathered from that dependency. Whatever expense
Great Britain
has hitherto laid out in maintaining this
dependency,
has really been laid out in order to support this
monopoly.
The expense of the ordinary peace establishment of the
colonies
amounted, before the commencement of the present
disturbances
to the pay of twenty regiments of foot ; to the
expense
of the artillery, stores, and extraordinary provisions,
with
which it was necessary to supply them ; and to the expense
of a
very considerable naval force, which was constantly kept up,
in
order to guard from the smuggling vessels of other nations,
the
immense coast of North America, and that of our West Indian
islands.
The whole expense of this peace establishment was a
charge
upon the revenue of Great Britain, and was, at the same
time,
the smallest part of what the dominion of the colonies has
cost
the mother country. If we would know the amount of the
whole,
we must add to the annual expense of this peace
establishment,
the interest of the sums which, in consequence of
their
considering her colonies as provinces subject to her
dominion,
Great Britain has, upon different occasions, laid out
upon
their defence. We must add to it, in particular, the whole
expense
of the late war, and a great part of that of the war
which
preceded it. The late war was altogether a colony quarrel ;
and the
whole expense of it, in whatever part of the world it
might
have been laid out, whether in Germany or the East Indies,
ought
justly to be stated to the account of the colonies. It
amounted
to more than ninety millions sterling, including not
only
the new debt which was contracted, but the two shillings in
the
pound additional land tax, and the sums which were every year
borrowed
from the sinking fund. The Spanish war which began in
1739
was principally a colony quarrel. Its principal object was
to
prevent the search of the colony ships, which carried on a
contraband
trade with the Spanish Main. This whole expense is, in
reality,
a bounty which has been given in order to support a
monopoly.
The pretended purpose of it was to encourage the
manufactures,
and to increase the commerce of Great Britain. But
its
real effect has been to raise the rate of mercantile profit,
and to
enable our merchants to turn into a branch of trade, of
which
the returns are more slow and distant than those of the
greater
part of other trades, a greater proportion of their
capital
than they otherwise would have done; two events which, if
a
bounty could have prevented, it might perhaps have been very
well
worth while to give such a bounty.
Under
the present system of management, therefore, Great Britain
derives
nothing but loss from the dominion which she assumes over
her
colonies.
To
propose that Great Britain should voluntarily give up all
authority
over her colonies, and leave them to elect their own
magistrates,
to enact their own laws, and to make peace and war,
as they
might think proper, would be to propose such a measure as
never
was, and never will be, adopted by any nation in the world.
No
nation ever voluntarily gave up the dominion of any province,
how
troublesome soever it might be to govern it, and how small
soever
the revenue which it afforded might be in proportion to
the
expense which it occasioned. Such sacrifices, though they
might
frequently be agreeable to the interest, are always
mortifying
to the pride of every nation; and, what is perhaps of
still
greater consequence, they are always contrary to the
private
interest of the governing part of it, who would thereby
be
deprived of the disposal of many places of trust and profit,
of many
opportunities of acquiring wealth and distinction, which
the
possession of the most turbulent, and, to the great body of
the
people, the most unprofitable province, seldom fails to
afford.
The most visionary enthusiasts would scarce be capable of
proposing
such a measure, with any serious hopes at least of its
ever
being adopted. If it was adopted, however, Great Britain
would
not only be immediately freed from the whole annual expense
of the
peace establishment of the colonies, but might settle with
them
such a treaty of commerce as would effectually secure to her
a free
trade, more advantageous to the great body of the people,
though
less so to the merchants, than the monopoly which she at
present
enjoys. By thus parting good friends, the natural
affection
of the colonies to the mother country, which, perhaps,
our
late dissensions have well nigh extinguished, would quickly
revive.
It might dispose them not only to respect, for whole
centuries
together, that treaty of commerce which they had
concluded
with us at parting, but to favour us in war as well as
in
trade, and instead of turbulent and factious subjects, to
become
our most faithful, affectionate, and generous allies; and
the
same sort of parental affection on the one side, and filial
respect
on the other, might revive between Great Britain and her
colonies,
which used to subsist between those of ancient Greece
and the
mother city from which they descended.
In
order to render any province advantageous to the empire to
which
it belongs, it ought to afford, in time of peace, a revenue
to the
public, sufficient not only for defraying the whole
expense
of its own peace establishment, but for contributing its
proportion
to the support of the general government of the
empire.
Every province necessarily contributes, more or less, to
increase
the expense of that general government. If any
particular
province, therefore, does not contribute its share
towards
defraying this expense, an unequal burden must be thrown
upon
some other part of the empire. The extraordinary revenue,
too,
which every province affords to the public in time of war,
ought,
from parity of reason, to bear the same proportion to the
extraordinary
revenue of the whole empire, which its ordinary
revenue
does in time of peace. That neither the ordinary nor
extraordinary
revenue which Great Britain derives from her
colonies,
bears this proportion to the whole revenue of the
British
empire, will readily be allowed. The monopoly, it has
been
supposed, indeed, by increasing the private revenue of the
people
of Great Britain, and thereby enabling them to pay greater
taxes,
compensates the deficiency of the public revenue of the
colonies.
But this monopoly, I have endeavoured to show, though a
very
grievous tax upon the colonies, and though it may increase
the
revenue of a particular order of men in Great Britain,
diminishes,
instead of increasing, that of the great body of the
people,
and consequently diminishes, instead of increasing, the
ability
of the great body of the people to pay taxes. The men,
too,
whose revenue the monopoly increases, constitute a
particular
order, which it is both absolutely impossible to tax
beyond
the proportion of other orders, and extremely impolitic
even to
attempt to tax beyond that proportion, as I shall
endeavour
to show in the following book. No particular resource,
therefore,
can be drawn from this particular order.
The
colonies may be taxed either by their own assemblies, or by
the
parliament of Great Britain.
That
the colony assemblies can never be so managed as to levy
upon
their constituents a public revenue, sufficient, not only to
maintain
at all times their own civil and military establishment,
but to
pay their proper proportion of the expense of the general
government
of the British empire, seems not very probable. It was
a long
time before even the parliament of England, though placed
immediately
under the eye of the sovereign, could be brought
under
such a system of management, or could be rendered
sufficiently
liberal in their grants for supporting the civil and
military
establishments even of their own country. It was only by
distributing
among the particular members of parliament a great
part
either of the offices, or of the disposal of the offices
arising
from this civil and military establishment, that such a
system
of management could be established, even with regard to
the
parliament of England. But the distance of the colony
assemblies
from the eye of the sovereign, their number, their
dispersed
situation, and their various constitutions, would
render
it very difficult to manage them in the same manner, even
though
the sovereign had the same means of doing it; and those
means
are wanting. It would be absolutely impossible to
distribute
among all the leading members of all the colony
assemblies
such a share, either of the offices, or of the
disposal
of the offices, arising from the general government of
the
British empire, as to dispose them to give up their
popularity
at home, and to tax their constituents for the support
of that
general government, of which almost the whole emoluments
were to
be divided among people who were strangers to them. The
unavoidable
ignorance of administration, besides, concerning the
relative
importance of the different members of those different
assemblies,
the offences which must frequently be given, the
blunders
which must constantly be committed, in attempting to
manage
them in this manner, seems to render such a system of
management
altogether impracticable with regard to them.
The
colony assemblies, besides, cannot be supposed the proper
judges
of what is necessary for the defence and support of the
whole
empire. The care of that defence and support is not
entrusted
to them. It is not their business, and they have no
regular
means of information concerning it. The assembly of a
province,
like the vestry of a parish, may judge very properly
concerning
the affairs of its own particular district, but can
have no
proper means of judging concerning those of the whole
empire.
It cannot even judge properly concerning the proportion
which
its own province bears to the whole empire, or concerning
the
relative degree of its wealth and importance, compared with
the
other provinces; because those other provinces are not under
the
inspection and superintendency of the assembly of a
particular
province. What is necessary for the defence and
support
of the whole empire, and in what proportion each part
ought
to contribute, can be judged of only by that assembly which
inspects
and super-intends the affairs of the whole empire.
It has
been proposed, accordingly, that the colonies should be
taxed
by requisition, the parliament of Great Britain determining
the sum
which each colony ought to pay, and the provincial
assembly
assessing and levying it in the way that suited best the
circumstances
of the province. What concerned the whole empire
would
in this way be determined by the assembly which inspects
and
superintends the affairs of the whole empire ; and the
provincial
affairs of each colony might still be regulated by its
own
assembly. Though the colonies should, in this case, have no
representatives
in the British parliament, yet, if we may judge
by
experience, there is no probability that the parliamentary
requisition
would be unreasonable. The parliament of England has
not,
upon any occasion, shewn the smallest disposition to
overburden
those parts of the empire which are not represented in
parliament.
The islands of Guernsey and Jersey, without any means
of
resisting the authority of parliament, are more lightly taxed
than
any part of Great Britain. Parliament, in attempting to
exercise
its supposed right, whether well or ill grounded, of
taxing
the colonies, has never hitherto demanded of them anything
which
even approached to a just proportion to what was paid by
their
fellow subjects at home. If the contribution of the
colonies,
besides, was to rise or fall in proportion to the rise
or fall
of the land-tax, parliament could not tax them without
taxing,
at the same time, its own constituents, and the colonies
might,
in this case, be considered as virtually represented in
parliament.
Examples
are not wanting of empires in which all the different
provinces
are not taxed, if I may be allowed the expression, in
one
mass ; but in which the sovereign regulates the sum which
each
province ought to pay, and in some provinces assesses and
levies
it as he thinks proper ; while in others he leaves it to
be
assessed and levied as the respective states of each province
shall
determine. In some provinces of France, the king not only
imposes
what taxes he thinks proper, but assesses and levies them
in the
way he thinks proper. From others he demands a certain
sum,
but leaves it to the states of each province to assess and
levy
that sum as they think proper. According to the scheme of
taxing
by requisition, the parliament of Great Britain would
stand
nearly in the same situation towards the colony assemblies,
as the
king of France does towards the states of those provinces
which
still enjoy the privilege of having states of their own,
the
provinces of France which are supposed to be the best
governed.
But
though, according to this scheme, the colonies could have no
just
reason to fear that their share of the public burdens should
ever
exceed the proper proportion to that of their
fellow-citizens
at home, Great Britain might have just reason to
fear
that it never would amount to that proper proportion. The
parliament
of Great Britain has not, for some time past, had the
same
established authority in the colonies, which the French king
has in
those provinces of France which still enjoy the privilege
of
having states of their own. The colony assemblies, if they
were
not very favourably disposed (and unless more skilfully
managed
than they ever have been hitherto, they are not very
likely
to be so), might still find many pretences for evading or
rejecting
the most reasonable requisitions of parliament. A
French
war breaks out, we shall suppose; ten millions must
immediately
be raised, in order to defend the seat of the empire.
This
sum must be borrowed upon the credit of some parliamentary
fund
mortgaged for paying the interest. Part of this fund
parliament
proposes to raise by a tax to be levied in Great
Britain
; and part of it by a requisition to all the different
colony
assemblies of America and the West Indies. Would people
readily
advance their money upon the credit of a fund which
partly
depended upon the good humour of all those assemblies, far
distant
from the seat of the war, and sometimes, perhaps,
thinking
themselves not much concerned in the event of it ? Upon
such a
fund, no more money would probably be advanced than what
the tax
to be levied in Great Britain might be supposed to answer
for.
The whole burden of the debt contracted on account of the
war
would in this manner fall, as it always has done hitherto,
upon
Great Britain; upon a part of the empire, and not upon the
whole
empire. Great Britain is, perhaps, since the world began,
the
only state which, as it has extended its empire, has only
increased
its expense, without once augmenting its resources.
Other
states have generally disburdened themselves, upon their
subject
and subordinate provinces, of the most considerable part
of the
expense of defending the empire. Great Britain has
hitherto
suffered her subject and subordinate provinces to
disburden
themselves upon her of almost this whole expense. In
order
to put Great Britain upon a footing of equality with her
own
colonies, which the law has hitherto supposed to be subject
and
subordinate, it seems necessary, upon the scheme of taxing
them by
parliamentary requisition, that parliament should have
some
means of rendering its requisitions immediately effectual,
in case
the colony assemblies should attempt to evade or reject
them;
and what those means are, it is not very easy to conceive,
and it
has not yet been explained.
Should
the parliament of Great Britain, at the same time, be ever
fully
established in the right of taxing the colonies, even
independent
of the consent of their own assemblies, the
importance
of those assemblies would, from that moment, be at an
end,
and with it, that of all the leading men of British America.
Men
desire to have some share in the management of public
affairs,
chiefly on account of the importance which it gives
them.
Upon the power which the greater part of the leading men,
the
natural aristocracy of every country, have of preserving or
defending
their respective importance, depends the stability and
duration
of every system of free government. In the attacks which
those
leading men are continually making upon the importance of
one
another, and in the defence of their own, consists the whole
play of
domestic faction and ambition. The leading men of
America,
like those of all other countries, desire to preserve
their
own importance. They feel, or imagine, that if their
assemblies,
which they are fond of calling parliaments, and of
considering
as equal in authority to the parliament of Great
Britain,
should be so far degraded as to become the humble
ministers
and executive officers of that parliament, the greater
part of
their own importance would be at an end. They have
rejected,
therefore, the proposal of being taxed by parliamentary
requisition,
and, like other ambitious and high-spirited men,
have
rather chosen to draw the sword in defence of their own
importance.
Towards
the declension of the Roman republic, the allies of Rome,
who had
borne the principal burden of defending the state and
extending
the empire, demanded to be admitted to all the
privileges
of Roman citizens. Upon being refused, the social war
broke
out. During the course of that war, Rome granted those
privileges
to the greater part of them, one by one, and in
proportion
as they detached themselves from the general
confederacy.
The parliament of Great Britain insists upon taxing
the
colonies ; and they refuse to be taxed by a parliament in
which
they are not represented. If to each colony which should
detach
itself from the general confederacy, Great Britain should
allow
such a number of representatives as suited the proportion
of what
it contributed to the public revenue of the empire, in
consequence
of its being subjected to the same taxes. and in
compensation
admitted to the same freedom of trade with its
fellow-subjects
at home; the number of its representatives to be
augmented
as the proportion of its contribution might afterwards
augment
; a new method of acquiring importance, a new and more
dazzling
object of ambition, would be presented to the leading
men of
each colony. Instead of piddling for the little prizes
which
are to be found in what may be called the paltry raffle of
colony
faction, they might then hope, from the presumption which
men
naturally have in their own ability and good fortune, to draw
some of
the great prizes which sometimes come from the wheel of
the
great state lottery of British politics. Unless this or some
other
method is fallen upon, and there seems to be none more
ubvious
than this, of preserving the importance and of gratifying
the
ambition of the leading men of America, it is not very
probable
that they will ever voluntarily submit to us; and we
ought
to consider, that the blood which must be shed in forcing
them to
do so, is, every drop of it, the blood either of those
who
are, or of those whom we wish to have for our fellow
citizens.
They are very weak who flatter themselves that, in the
state
to which things have come, our colonies will be easily
conquered
by force alone. The persons who now govern the
resolutions
of what they call their continental congress, feel in
themselves
at this moment a degree of importance which, perhaps,
the
greatest subjects in Europe scarce feel. From shopkeepers,
trades
men, and attorneys, they are become statesmen and
legislators,
and are employed in contriving a new form of
government
for an extensive empire, which, they flatter
themselves,
will become, and which, indeed, seems very likely to
become,
one of the greatest and most formidable that ever was in
the
world. Five hundred different people, perhaps, who, in
different
ways, act immediately under the continental congress,
and
five hundred thousand, perhaps, who act under those five
hundred,
all feel, in the same manner, a proportionable rise in
their
own importance. Almost every individual of the governing
party
in America fills, at present, in his own fancy, a station
superior,
not only to what he had ever filled before, but to what
he had
ever expected to fill; and unless some new object of
ambition
is presented either to him or to his leaders, if he has
the
ordinary spirit of a man, he will die in defence of that
station.
It is a
remark of the President Heynaut, that we now read with
pleasure
the account of many little transactions of the Ligue,
which,
when they happened, were not, perhaps, considered as very
important
pieces of news. But everyman then, says he, fancied
himself
of some importance ; and the innumerable memoirs which
have
come down to us from those times, were the greater part of
them
written by people who took pleasure in recording and
magnifying
events, in which they flattered themselves they had
been
considerable actors. How obstinately the city of Paris, upon
that
occasion, defended itself, what a dreadful famine it
supported,
rather than submit to the best, and afterwards the
most
beloved of all the French kings, is well known. The greater
part of
the citizens, or those who governed the greater part of
them,
fought in defence of their own importance, which, they
foresaw,
was to be at an end whenever the ancient government
should
be re-established. Our colonies, unless they can be
induced
to consent to a union, are very likely to defend
themselves,
against the best of all mother countries, as
obstinately
as the city of Paris did against one of the best of
kings.
The
idea of representation was unknown in ancient times. When the
people
of one state were admitted to the right of citizenship in
another,
they had no other means of exercising that right, but by
coming
in a body to vote and deliberate with the people of that
other
state. The admission of the greater part of the inhabitants
of
Italy to the privileges of Roman citizens, completely ruined
the
Roman republic. It was no longer possible to distinguish
between
who was, and who was not, a Roman citizen. No tribe could
know
its own members. A rabble of any kind could be introduced
into
the assemblies of the people, could drive out the real
citizens,
and decide upon the affairs of the republic, as if they
themselves
had been such. But though America were to send fifty
or
sixty new representatives to parlimnent, the door-keeper of
the
house of commons could not find any great difficulty in
distinguishing
between who was and who was not a member. Though
the
Roman constitution, therefore, was necessarily ruined by the
union
of Rome with the allied states of Italy, there is not the
least
probability that the British constitution would be hurt by
the
union of Great Britain with her colonies.
That
constitution,
on the contrary, would be completed by it, and
seems
to be imperfect without it. The assembly which deliberates
and
decides concerning the affairs of every part of the empire,
in
order to be properly informed, ought certainly to have
representatives
from every part of it. That this union, however,
could
be easily effectuated, or that difficulties, and great
difficulties,
might not occur in the execution, I do not pretend.
I have
yet heard of none, however, which appear insurmountable.
The
principal, perhaps, arise, not from the nature of things, but
from
the prejudices and opinions of the people, both on this and
on the
other side of the Atlantic.
We on
this side the water are afraid lest the multitude of
American
representatives should overturn the balance of the
constitution,
and increase too much either the influence of the
crown
on the one hand, or the force of the democracy on the
other.
But if the number of American representatives were to be
in
proportion to the produce of American taxation, the number of
people
to be managed would increase exactly in proportion to the
means
of managing them, and the means of managing to the number
of
people to be managed. The monarchical and democratical parts
of the
constitution would, after the union, stand exactly in the
same
degree of relative force with regard to one another as they
had
done before.
The
people on the other side of the water are afraid lest their
distance
from the seat of government might expose them to many
oppressions
; but their representatives in parliament, of which
the
number ought from the first to be considerable, would easily
be able
to protect them from all oppression. The distance could
not
much weaken the dependency of the representative upon the
constituent,
and the former would still feel that he owed his
seat in
parliament, and all the consequence which he derived from
it, to
the good-will of the latter. It would be the interest of
the
former, therefore, to cultivate that good-will, by
complaining,
with all the authority of a member of the
legislature,
of every outrage which any civil or military officer
might
be guilty of in those remote parts of the empire. The
distance
of America from the seat of government, besides, the
natives
of that country might flatter themselves, with some
appearance
of reason too, would not be of very long continuance.
Such
has hitherto been the rapid progress of that country in
wealth,
population, and improvement, that in the course of little
more
than a century, perhaps, the produce of the American might
exceed
that of the British taxation. The seat of the empire would
then
naturally remove itself to that part of the empire which
contributed
most to the general defence and support of the whole.
The
discovery of America, and that of a passage to the East
Indies
by the Cape of Good Hope, are the two greatest and most
important
events recorded in the history of mankind. Their
consequences
have already been great; but, in the short period of
between
two and three centuries which has elapsed since these
discoveries
were made, it is impossible that the whole extent of
their
consequences can have been seen. What benefits or what
misfortunes
to mankind may hereafter result from those great
events,
no human wisdom can foresee. By uniting in some measure
the
most distant parts of the world, by enabling them to relieve
one
another's wants, to increase one another's enjoyments, and to
encourage
one another's industry, their general tendency would
seem to
be beneficial. To the natives, however, both of the East
and
West Indies, all the commercial benefits which can have
resulted
from those events have been sunk and lost in the
dreadful
misfortunes which they have occasioned. These
misfortunes,
however, seem to have arisen rather from accident
than
from any thing in the nature of those events themselves. At
the
particular time when these discoveries were made, the
superiority
of force happened to be so great on the side of the
Europeans,
that they were enabled to commit with impunity every
sort of
injustice in those remote countries. Hereafter, perhaps,
the
natives of those countries may grow stronger, or those of
Europe
may grow weaker ; and the inhabitants of all the different
quarters
of the world may arrive at that equality of courage and
force
which, by inspiring mutual fear, can alone overawe the
injustice
of independent nations into some sort of respect for
the
rights of one another. But nothing seems more likely to
establish
this equality of force, than that mutual communication
of knowledge,
and of all sorts of improvements, which an
extensive
commerce from all countries to all countries naturally,
or
rather necessarily, carries along with it.
In the
mean time, one of the principal effects of those
discoveries
has been, to raise the mercantile system to a degree
of
splendour and glory which it could never otherwise have
attained
to. It is the object of that system to enrich a great
nation,
rather by trade and manufactures than by the improvement
and
cultivation of land, rather by the industry of the towns than
by that
of the country. But in consequence of those discoveries,
the
commercial towns of Europe, instead of being the
manufacturers
and carriers for but a very small part of the world
(that
part of Europe which is washed by the Atlantic ocean, and
the
countries which lie round the Baltic and Mediterranean seas),
have
now become the manufacturers for the numerous and thriving
cultivators
of America, and the carriers, and in some respects
the
manufacturers too, for almost all the different nations of
Asia,
Africa, and America. Two new worlds have been opened to
their
industry, each of them much greater and more extensive than
the old
one, and the market of one of them growing still greater
and
greater every day.
The
countries which possess the colonies of America, and which
trade
directly to the East Indies, enjoy indeed the whole show
and
splendour of this great commerce. Other countries, however,
notwithstanding
all the invidious restraints by which it is meant
to
exclude them, frequently enjoy a greater share of the real
benefit
of it. The colonies of Spain and. Portugal, for example,
give
more real encouragement to the industry of other countries
than to
that of Spain and Portugal. In the single article of
linen
alone, the consumption of those colonies amounts, it is
said
(but I do not pretend to warrant the quantity ), to more
than
three millions sterling a-year. But this great consumption
is
almost entirely supplied by France, Flanders, Holland, and
Germany.
Spain and Portugal furnish but a small part of it. The
capital
which supplies the colonies with this great quantity of
linen,
is annually distributed among, and furnishes a revenue to,
the
inhabitants of those other countries. The profits of it only
are
spent in Spain and Portugal, where they help to support the
sumptuous
profusion of the merchants of Cadiz and Lisbon.
Even
the regulations by which each nation endeavours to secure to
itself
the exclusive trade of its own colonies, are frequently
more
hurtful to the countries in favour of which they are
established,
than to those against which they are established.
The
unjust oppression of the industry of other countries falls
back,
if I may say so, upon the heads of the oppressors, and
crushes
their industry more than it does that of those other
countries.
By those regulations, for example, the merchant of
Hamburg
must send the linen which he destines for the American
market
to London, and he must bring back from thence the tobacco
which
be destines for the German market; because he can neither
send
the one directly to America, nor bring the other directly
from
thence. By this restraint he is probably obliged to sell the
one
somewhat cheaper, and to buy the other somewhat dearer, than
he
otherwise might have done; and his profits are probably
somewhat
abridged by means of it. In this trade, however, between
Hamburg
and London, he certainly receives the returns of his
capital
much more quickly than he could possibly have done in the
direct
trade to America, even though we should suppose, what is
by no
means the case, that the payments of America were as
punctual
as those of London. In the trade,
therefore, to
which
those regulations confine the merchant of Hamburg, his
capital
can keep in constant employment a much greater quantity
of
German industry than he possibly could have done in the trade
from
which he is excluded. Though the one employment, therefore,
may to
him perhaps be less profitable than the other, it cannot
be less
advantageous to his country. It is quite otherwise with
the
employment into which the monpoly naturally attracts, if I
may say
so, the capital of the London merchant. That employment
may,
perhaps, be more profitable to him than the greater part of
other
employments; but on account of the slowness of the returns,
it
cannot be more advantageous to his country.
After
all the unjust attempts, therefore, of every country in
Europe
to engross to itself the whole advantage of the trade of
its own
colonies, no country has yet been able to engross to
itself
any thing but the expense of supporting in time of peace,
and of
defending in time of war, the oppressive authority which
it
assumes over them. The inconveniencies resulting from the
possession
of its colonies, every country has engrossed to itself
completely. The advantages resulting from their
trade, it
has
been obliged to share with many other countries.
At
first sight, no doubt, the monopoly of the great commerce of
America
naturally seems to be an acquisition of the highest
value.
To the undiscerning eye of giddy ambition it naturally
presents
itself, amidst the confused scramble of politics and
war, as
a very dazzling object to fight for. The dazzling
splendour
of the object, however, the immense greatness of the
commerce,
is the very quality which renders the monopoly of it
hurtful,
or which makes one employment, in its own nature
necessarily
less advantageous to the country than the greater
part of
other employments, absorb a much greater proportion of
the
capital of the country than what would otherwise have gone to
it.
The
mercantile stock of every country, it has been shown in the
second
book, naturally seeks, if one may say so, the employment
most
advantageous to that country. If it is employed in the
carrying
trade, the country to which it belongs becomes the
emporium
of the goods of all the countries whose trade that stock
carries
on. But the owner of that stock necessarily wishes to
dispose
of as great a part of those goods as he can at home. He
thereby
saves himself the trouble, risk, and expense of
exportation
; and he will upon that account be glad to sell them
at
home, not only for a much smaller price, but with somewhat a
smaller
profit, than he might expect to make by sending them
abroad.
He naturally, therefore, endeavours as much as he can to
turn
his carrying trade into a foreign trade of consumption, If
his
stock, again, is employed in a foreign trade of consumption,
he
will, for the same reason, be glad to dispose of, at home, as
great a
part as he can of the home goods which he collects in
order
to export to some foreign market, and he will thus
endeavour,
as much as he can, to turn his foreign trade of
consumption
into a home trade. The mercantile stock of every
country
naturally courts in this manner the near, and shuns the
distant
employment : naturally courts the employment in which the
returns
are frequent, and shuns that in which they are distant
and
slow; naturally courts the employment in which it can
maintain
the greatest quantity of productive labour in the
country
to which it belongs, or in which its owner resides, and
shuns
that in which it can maintain there the smallest quantity.
It
naturally courts the employment which in ordinary cases is
most
advantageous, and shuns that which in ordinary cases is
least
advantageous to that country.
But if,
in any one of those distant employments, which in
ordinary
cases are less advantageous to the country, the profit
should
happen to rise somewhat higher than what is sufficient to
balance
the natural preference which is given to nearer
employments,
this superiority of profit will draw stock from
those
nearer employments, till the profits of all return to their
proper
level. This superiority of profit, however, is a proof
that,
in the actual circumstances of the society, those distant
employments
are somewhat understocked in proportion to other
employments,
and that the stock of the society is not distributed
in the
properest manner among all the different employments
carried
on in it. It is a proof that something is either bought
cheaper
or sold dearer than it ought to be, and that some
particular
class of citizens is more or less oppressed, either by
paying
more, or by getting less than what is suitable to that
equality
which ought to take place, and which naturally does take
place,
among all the different classes of them. Though the same
capital
never will maintain the same quantity of productive
labour
in a distant as in a near employment, yet a distant
employment
maybe as necessary for the welfare of the society as a
near
one; the goods which the distant employment deals in being
necessary,
perhaps, for carrying on many of the nearer
employments.
But if the profits of those who deal in such goods
are
above their proper level, those goods will be sold dearer
than
they ought to be, or somewhat above their natural price, and
all
those engaged in the nearer employments will be more or less
oppressed
by this high price. Their interest, therefore, in this
case,
requires, that some stock should be withdrawn from those
nearer
employments, and turned towards that distant one, in order
to
reduce its profits to their proper level, and the price of the
goods
which it deals in to their natural price.
In this
extraordinary
case, the public interest requires that some stock
should
be withdrawn from those employments which, in ordinary
cases,
are more advantageous, and turned towards one which, in
ordinary
cases, is less advantageous to the public; and, in this
extraordinary
case, the natural interests and inclinations of men
coincide
as exactly with the public interests as in all other
ordinary
cases, and lead them to withdraw stock from the near,
and to
turn it towards the distant employments.
It is
thus that the private interests and passions of individuals
naturally
dispose them to turn their stock towards the
employments
which in ordinary cases, are most advantagenus to the
society.
But if from this natural preference they should turn too
much of
it towards those employments, the fall of profit in them,
and the
rise of it in all others, immediately dispose them to
alter
this faulty distribution. Without any intervention of law,
therefore,
the private interests and passions of men naturally
lead
them to divide and distribute the stock of every society
among
all the different employments carried on in it; as nearly
as
possible in the proportion which is most agreeable to the
interest
of the whole society.
All the
different regulations of the mercantile system
necessarily
derange more or less this natural and most
advantageous
distribution of stock. But those which concern the
trade
to America and the East Indies derange it, perhaps, more
than
any other ; because the trade to those two great continents
absorbs
a greater quantity of stock than any two other branches
of
trade. The regulations, however, by which this derangement is
effected
in those two different branches of trade, are not
altogether
the same. Monopoly is the great engine of both ; but
it is a
different sort of monopoly. Monopoly of one kind or
another,
indeed, seems to be the sole engine of the mercantile
system.
In the
trade to America, every nation endeavours to engross as
much as
possible the whole market of its own colonies, by fairly
excluding
all other nations from any direct trade to them. During
the
greater part of the sixteenth century, the Portuguese
endeavoured
to manage the trade to the East Indies in the same
manner,
by claiming the sole right of sailing in the Indian seas,
on
account of the merit of having first found out the road to
them.
The Dutch still continue to exclude all other European
nations
from any direct trade to their spice islands. Monopolies
of this
kind are evidently established against all other European
nations,
who are thereby not only excluded from a trade to which
it
might be convenient for them to turn some part of their stock,
but are
obliged to buy the goods which that trade deals in,
somewhat
dearer than if they could import them themselves
directly
from the countries which produced them.
But
since the fall of the power of Portugal, no European nation
has
claimed the exclusive right of sailing in the Indian seas, of
which
the principal ports are now open to the ships of all
European
nations. Except in Portugal, however, and within these
few
years in France, the trade to the East Indies has, in every
European
country, been subjected to an exclusive company.
Monopolies
of this kind are properly established against the very
nation
which erects them. The greater part of that nation are
thereby
not only excluded from a trade to which it might be
convenient
for them to turn some part of their stock, but are
obliged
to buy the goods which that trade deals in somewhat
dearer
than if it was open and free to all their countrymen.
Since
the establishment of the English East India company, for
example,
the other inhabitants of England, over and above being
excluded
from the trade, must have paid, in the price of the East
India
goods which they have consumed, not only for all the
extraordinary
profits which the company may have made upon those
goods
in consequence of their monopoly, but for all the
extraordinary
waste which the fraud and abuse inseparable from
the
management of the affairs of so great a company must
necessarily
have occasioned. The absurdity of this second kind of
monopoly,
therefore, is much more manifest than that of the
first.
Both
these kinds of monopolies derange more or less the natural
distribution
of the stock of the society ; but they do not always
derange
it in the same way.
Monopolies
of the first kind always attract to the particular
trade
in which they are established a greater proportion of the
stock
of the society than what would go to that trade of its own
accord.
Monopolies
of the second kind may sometimes attract stock towards
the
particular trade in which they are established, and sometimes
repel
it from that trade, according to different circumstances.
In poor
countries, they naturally attract towards that trade more
stock
than would otherwise go to it. In rich countries, they
naturally
repel from it a good deal of stock which would
otherwise
go to it.
Such
poor countries as Sweden and Denmark, for example, would
probably
have never sent a single ship to the East Indies, had
not the
trade been subjected to an exclusive company. The
establishment
of such a conpany necessarily encourages
adventurers.
Their monopoly secures them against all competitors
in the
home market, and they have the same chance for foreign
markets
with the traders of other nations. Their monopoly shows
them
the certainty of a great profit upon a considerable quantity
of
goods, and the chance of a considerable profit upon a great
quantity.
Without such extraordinary encouragement, the poor
traders
of such poor countries would probably never have thought
of
hazarding their small capitals in so very distant and
uncertain
an adventure as the trade to the East Indies must
naturally
have appeared to them.
Such a
rich country as Holland, on the contrary, would probably,
in the
case of a free trade, send many more ships to the East
Indies
than it actually does. The limited stock of the Dutch East
India
company probably repels from that trade many great
mercantile
capitals which would otherwise go to it. The
mercantile
capital of Holland is so great, that it is, as it
were,
continually overflowing, sometimes into the public funds of
foreign
countries, sometimes into loans to private traders and
adventurers
of foreign countries, sometimes into the most
round-about
foreign trades of consumption, and sometimes into the
carrying
trade. All near employments being completely filled up,
all the
capital which can be placed in them with any tolerable
profit
being already placed in them, the capital of Holland
necessarily
flows towards the most distant employments. The trade
to the
East Indies, if it were altogether free, would probably
absorb
the greater part of this redundant capital. The East
Indies
offer a market both for the manufactures of Europe, and
for the
gold and silver, as well as for the several other
productions
of America, greater and more extensive than both
Europe
and America put together.
Every
derangement of the natural distribution of stock is
necessarily
hurtful to the society in which it takes place;
whether
it be by repelling from a particular trade the stock
which
would otherwise go to it, or by attracting towards a
particular
trade that which would not otherwise come to it. If,
without
any exclusive company, the trade of Holland to the East
Indies
would be greater than it actually is, that country must
suffer
a considerable loss, by part of its capital being excluded
from
the employment most convenient for that port. And, in the
same
manner, if, without an exclusive company, the trade of
Sweden
and Denmark to the East Indies would be less than it
actually
is, or, what perhaps is more probable, would not exist
at all,
those two countries must likewise suffer a considerable
loss,
by part of their capital being drawn into an employment
which
must be more or less unsuitable to their present
circumstances.
Better for them, perhaps, in the present
circumstances,
to buy East India goods of other nations, even
though
they should pay somewhat dearer, than to turn so great a
part of
their small capital to so very distant a trade, in which
the
returns are so very slow, in which that capital can maintain
so
small a quantity of productive labour at home, where
productive
labour is so much wanted, where so little is done, and
where
so much is to do.
Though
without an exclusive company, therefore, a particular
country
should not be able to carry on any direct trade to the
East
Indies, it will not from thence follow, that such a company
ought
to be established there, but only that such a country ought
not, in
these circumstances, to trade directly to the East
Indies.
That such companies are not in general necessary for
carrying
on the East India trade, is sufficiently demonstrated by
the
experience of the Portuguese, who enjoyed almost the whole of
it for
more than a century together, without any exclusive
company.
No private
merchant, it has been said, could well have capital
sufficient
to maintain factors and agents in the different ports
of the
East Indies, in order to provide goods for the ships which
he
might occasionally send thither; and yet, unless he was able
to do
this, the difficulty of finding a cargo might frequently
make
his ships lose the season for returning; and the expense of
so long
a delay would not only eat up the whole profit of the
adventure,
but frequently occasion a very considerable loss. This
argument,
however, if it proved any thing at all, would prove
that no
one great branch of trade could be carried on without an
exclusive
company, which is contrary to the experience of all
nations.
There is no great branch of trade, in which the capital
of any
one private merchant is sufficient for carrying on all the
subordinate
branches which must be carried on, in order to carry
on the
principal one. But when a nation is ripe for any great
branch
of trade, some merchants naturally turn their capitals
towards
the principal, and some towards the subordinate branches
of it;
and though all the different branches of it are in this
manner
carried on, yet it very seldom happens that they are all
carried
on by the capital of one private merchant. If a nation,
therefore,
is ripe for the East India trade, a certain portion of
its
capital will naturally divide itself among all the different
branches
of that trade. Some of its merchants will find it for
their
interest to reside in the East Indies, and to employ their
capitals
there in providing goods for the ships which are to be
sent
out by other merchants who reside in Europe. The settlements
which
different European nations have obtained in the East
Indies,
if they were taken from the exclusive companies to which
they at
present belong, and put under the immediate protection of
the
sovereign, would render this residence both safe and easy, at
least
to the merchants of the particular nations to whom those
settlements
belong. If, at any particular time, that part of the
capital
of any country which of its own accord tended and
inclined,
if I may say so, towards the East India trade, was not
sufficient
for carrying on all those different branches of it, it
would
be a proof that, at that particular time, that country was
not
ripe for that trade, and that it would do better to buy for
some
time, even at a higher price, from other European nations,
the
East India goods it had occasion for, than to import them
itself
directly from the East Indies. What it might lose by the
high
price of those goods, could seldom be equal to the loss
which
it would sustain by the distraction of a large portion of
its
capital from other employments more necessary, or more
useful,
or more suitable to its circumstances and situation, than
a
direct trade to the East Indies.
Though
the Europeans possess many considerable settlements both
upon
the coast of Africa and in the East Indies, they have not
yet
established, in either of those countries, such numerous and
thriving
colonies as those in the islands and continent of
America.
Africa, however, as well as several of the countries
comprehended
under the general name of the East Indies, is
inhabited
by barbarous nations. But those nations were by no
means
so weak and defenceless as the miserable and helpless
Americans
; and in proportion to the natural fertility of the
countries
which they inhabited, they were, besides, much more
populous.
The most barbarous nations either of Africa or of the
East Indies,
were shepherds; even the Hottentots were so. But the
natives
of every part of America, except Mexico and Peru, were
only
hunters and the difference is very great between the number
of
shepherds and that of hunters whom the same extent of equally
fertile
territory can maintain. In Africa and the East Indies,
therefore,
it was more difficult to displace the natives, and to
extend
the European plantations over the greater part of the
lands
of the original inhabitants. The
genius of exclusive
companies,
besides, is unfavourable, it has already been
observed,
to the growth of new colonies, and has probably been
the
principal cause of the little progress which they have made
in the
East Indies. The Portuguese carried on the trade both to
Africa
and the East Indies, without any exclusive companies; and
their
settlements at Congo, Angola, and Benguela, on the coast of
Africa,
and at Goa in the East Indies though much depressed by
superstition
and every sort of bad government, yet bear some
resemblance
to the colonies of America, and are partly inhabited
by
Portuguese who have been established there for several
generations.
The Dutch settlmnents at the Cape of Good Hope and
at
Batavia, are at present the most considerable colonies which
the
Europeans have established, either in Africa or in the East
Indies;
and both those settlements an peculiarly fortunate in
their
situation. The Cape of Good Hope was inhabited by a race of
people
almost as barbarous, and quite as incapable of defending
themselves,
as the natives of America. It is, besides, the
half-way
house, if one may say so, between Europe and the East
Indies,
at which almost every European ship makes some stay, both
in
going and returning. The supplying of those ships with every
sort of
fresh provisions, with fruit, and sometimes with wine,
affords
alone a very extensive market for the surplus produce of
the
colonies. What the Cape of Good Hope is between Europe and
every
part of the East Indies, Batavia is between the principal
countries
of the East Indies. It lies upon the most frequented
road
from Indostan to China and Japan, and is nearly about
mid-way
upon that road. Almost all the ships too, that sail
between
Europe and China, touch at Batavia; and it is, over and
above
all this, the centre and principal mart of what is called
the
country trade of the East Indies; not only of that part of it
which
is carried on by Europeans, but of that which is carried on
by the
native Indians; and vessels navigated by the inhabitants
of
China and Japan, of Tonquin, Malacca, Cochin-China, and the
island
of Celebes, are frequently to be seen in its port. Such
advantageous
situations have enabled those two colonies to
surmount
all the obstacles which the oppressive genius of an
exclusive
company may have occasionally opposed to their growth.
They
have enabled Batavia to surmount the additional disadvantage
of
perhaps the most unwholesome climate in the world.
The
English and Dutch companies, though they have established no
considerable
colonies, except the two above mentioned, have both
made
considerable conquests in the East Indies. But in the manner
in
which they both govern their new subjects, the natural genius
of an
exclusive company has shewn itself most distinctly. In the
spice
islands, the Dutch are said to burn all the spiceries which
a
fertile season produces, beyond what they expect to dispose of
in
Europe with such a profit as they think sufficient. In the
islands
where they have no settlements, they give a premium to
those
who collect the young blossoms and green leaves of the
clove
and nutmeg trees, which naturally grow there, but which
this
savage policy has now, it is said. almost completely
extirpated.
Even in the islands where they have settlements, they
have
very much reduced, it is said, the number of those trees. If
the
produce even of their own islands was much greater than what
suited
their market, the natives, they suspect, might find means
to
convey some part of it to other nations; and the best way,
they
imagine, to secure their own monopoly, is to take care that
no more
shall grow than what they themselves carry to market. By
different
arts of oppression, they have reduced the population of
several
of the Moluccas nearly to the number which is sufficient
to
supply with fresh provisions, and other necessaries of life,
their
own insignificant garrisons, and such of their ships as
occasionally
come there for a cargo of spices. Under the
government
even of the Portuguese, however, those islands are
said to
have been tolerably well inhabited. The English company
have
not yet had time to establish in Bengal so perfectly
destructive
a system. The plan of their government, however, has
had
exactly the same tendency. It has not been uncommon, I am
well
assured, for the chief, that is, the first clerk or a
factory,
to order a peasant to plough up a rich field of poppies,
and sow
it with rice, or some other grain. The pretence was, to
prevent
a scarcity of provisions; but the real reason, to give
the
chief an opportunity of selling at a better price a large
quantity
of opium which he happened then to have upon hand. Upon
other
occasions, the order has been reversed ; and a rich field
of rice
or other grain has been ploughed up, in order to make
room
for a plantation of poppies, when the chief foresaw that
extraordinary
profit was likely to be made by opium. The servants
of the
company have, upon several occasions, attempted to
establish
in their own favour the monopoly of some of the most
important
branches, not only of the foreign, but of the inland
trade
of the country. Had they been allowed to go on, it is
impossible
that they should not, at some time or another, have
attempted
to restrain the production of the particular articles
of
which they had thus usurped the monopoly, not only to the
quantity
which they themselves could purchase, but to that which
they
could expect to sell with such a profit as they might think
sufficient.
In the course of a century or two, the policy of the
English
company would, in this manner, have probably proved as
completely
destructive as that of the Dutch.
Nothing,
however, can be more directly contrary to the real
interest
of those companies, considered as the sovereigns of the
countries
which they have conquered, than this destructive plan.
In
almost all countries, the revenue of the sovereign is drawn
from
that of the people. The greater the revenue of the people,
therefore,
the greater the annual produce of their land and
labour,
the more they can afford to the sovereign. It is his
interest,
therefore, to increase as much as possible that annual
produce.
But if this is the interest of every sovereign, it is
peculiarly
so of one whose revenue, like that of the sovereign of
Bengal,
arises chiefly from a land-rent. That rent must
necessarily
be in proportion to the quantity and value of the
produce;
and both the one and the other must depend upon the
extent
of the market. The quantity will always be suited, with
more or
less exactness, to the consumption of those who can
afford
to pay for it; and the price which they will pay will
always
be in proportion to the eagerness of their competition. It
is the
interest of such a sovereign, therefore, to open the most
extensive
market for the produce of his country, to allow the
most
perfect freedom of commerce, in order to increase as much as
possible
the number and competition of buyers ; and upon this
account
to abolish, not only all monopolies, but all restraints
upon the
transportation of the home produce from one part of the
country
to mother, upon its exportation to foreign countries, or
upon
the importation of goods of' any kind for which it can be
exchanged.
He is in this manner most likely to increase both the
quantity
and value of that produce, and consequently of his own
share
of it, or of his own revenue.
But a
company of merchants, are, it seems, incapable of
considering
themselves as sovereigns, even after they have become
such.
Trade, or buying in order to sell again, they still
consider
as their principal business, and by a strange absurdity,
regard
the character of the sovereign as but an appendix to that
of the
merchant ; as something which ought to be made subservient
to it,
or by means of which they may be enabled to buy cheaper in
India,
and thereby to sell with a better profit in Europe. They
endeavour,
for this purpose, to keep out as much as possible all
competitors
from the market of the countries which are subject to
their
government, and consequently to reduce, at least, some part
of the
surplus produce of those countries to what is barely
sufficient
for supplying their own demand, or to what they can
expect
to sell in Europe, with such a profit as they may think
reasonable.
Their mercantile habits draw them in this manner,
almost
necessarily, though perhaps insensibly, to prefer, upon
all
ordinary occasions, the little and transitory profit of the
monopolist
to the great and permanent revenue of the sovereign;
and
would gradually lead them to treat the countries subject to
their
government nearly as the Dutch treat the Moluccas. It is
the
interest of the East India company, considered as sovereigns,
that
the European goods which are carried to their Indian
dominions
should be sold there as cheap as possible; and that the
Indian
goods which are brought from thence should bring there as
good a
price, or should be sold there as dear as possible. But
the
reverse of this is their interest as merchants. As
sovereigns,
their interest is exactly the same with that of the
country
which they govern. As merchants, their interest is
directly
opposite to that interest.
But if
the genius of such a government, even as to what concerns
its
direction in Earope, is in this manner essentially, and
perhaps
incurably faulty, that of its administration in India is
still
more so. That administration is necessarily composed of a
council
of merchants, a profession no doubt extremely
respectable,
but which in no country in the world carries along
with it
that sort of authority which naturally overawes the
people,
and without force commands their willing obedience. Such
a
council can command obedience only by the military force with
which
they are accompanied ; and their government is, therefore,
necessarily
military and despotical. Their proper business,
however,
is that of merchants. It is to sell, upon their master's
account,
the European goods consigned to them, and to buy, in
return,
Indian goods for the European market. It is to sell the
one as
dear, and to buy the other as cheap as possible, and
consequently
to exclude, as much as possible, all rivals from the
particular
market where they keep their shop. The genius of the
administration,
therefore, so far as concerns the trade of the
company,
is the same as that of the direction. It tends to make
government
subservient to the interest of monopoly, and
consequently
to stunt the natural growth of some parts, at least,
of the
surplus produce of the country, to what is barely
sufficient
for answering the demand of the company,
All the
members of the administration besides, trade more or less
upon
their own account; and it is in vain to prohibit them from
doing
so. Nothing can be more completely foolish than to expect
that
the clerk of a great counting-house, at ten thousand miles
distance,
and consequently almost quite out of sight, should,
upon a
simple order from their master, give up at once doing any
sort of
business upon their own account abandon for ever all
hopes
of making a fortune, of which they have the means in their
hands;
and content themselves with the moderate salaries which
those
masters allow them, and which, moderate as they are, can
seldom
be augmented, being commonly as large as the real profits
of the
company trade can afford. In such circumstances, to
prohibit
the servants of the company from trading upon their own
account,
can have scarce any other effect than to enable its
superior
servants, under pretence of executing their master's
order,
to oppress such of the inferior ones as have had the
misfortune
to fall under their displeasure.
The servants
naturally
endeavour to establish the same monopoly in favour of
their
own private trade as of the public trade of the company. If
they
are suffered to act as they could wish, they will establish
this
monopoly openly and directly, by fairly prohibiting all
other
people from trading in the articles in which they choose to
deal;
and this, perhaps, is the best and least oppressive way of
establishing
it. But if, by an order from Europe, they are
prohibited
from doing this, they will, notwithstanding, endeavour
to
establish a monopoly of the same kind secretly and indirectly,
in a
way that is much more destructive to the country. They will
employ
the whole authority of government, and pervert the
administration
of Justice, in order to harass and ruin those who
interfere
with them in any branch of commerce, which by means of
agents,
either concealed, or at least not publicly avowed, they
may
choose to carry on. But the private trade of the servants
will
naturally extend to a much greater variety of articles than
the
public trade of the company. The public trade of the company
extends
no further than the trade with Europe, and comprehends a
part
only of the foreign trade of the country. But the private
trade
of the servants may extend to all the different branches
both of
its inland and foreign trade. The monopoly of the company
can
tend only to stunt the natural growth of that part of the
surplus
produce which, in the case of a free trade, would be
exported
to Europe. That of the servants tends to stunt the
natural
growth of every part of the produce in which they choose
to
deal; of what is destined for home consumption, as well as of
what is
destined for exportation; and consequently to degrade the
cultivation
of the whole country, and to reduce the number of its
inhabitants.
It tends to reduce the quantity of every sort of
produce,
even that of the necessaries of life, whenever the
servants
of the country choose to deal in them, to what those
servants
can both afford to buy and expect to sell with such a
profit
as pleases them.
From
the nature of their situation, too, the servants must be
more
disposed to support with rigourous severity their own
interest,
against that of the country which they govern, than
their
masters can be to support theirs. The country belongs to
their
masters, who cannot avoid having some regard for the
interest
of what belongs to them; but it does not belong to the
servants.
The real interest of their masters, if they were
capable
of understanding it, is the same with that of the
country;
{The interest of every proprietor of India stock,
however,
is by no means the same with that of the country in the
government
of which his vote gives him some influence. - See book
v,
chap. 1, part ii.}and it is from ignorance chiefly, and the
meanness
of mercantile prejudice, that they ever oppress it. But
the
real interest of the servants is by no means the same with
that of
the country, and the most perfect information would not
necessarily
put an end to their oppressions. The regulations,
accordingly,
which have been sent out from Europe, though they
have
been frequently weak, have upon most occasions been well
meaning.
More intelligence, and perhaps less good meaning, has
sometimes
appeared in those established by the servants in India.
It is a
very singular government in which every member of the
administration
wishes to get out of the country, and consequently
to have
done with the government, as soon as he can, and to whose
interest,
the day after he has left it, and carried his whole
fortune
with him, it is perfectly indifferent though the whole
country
was swallowed up by an earthquake.
I mean
not, however, by any thing which I have here said, to
throw
any odious imputation upon the general character of the
servants
of the East India company, and touch less upon that of
any
particular persons. It is the system of government, the
situation
in which they are placed, that I mean to censure, not
the
character of those who have acted in it. They acted as their
situation
naturally directed, and they who have clamoured the
loudest
against them would probably not have acted better
themselves.
In war and negotiation, the councils of Madras and
Calcutta,
have upon several occasions, conducted themselves with
a
resolution and decisive wisdom, which would have done honour to
the
senate of Rome in the best days of that republic. The members
of
those councils, however, had been bred to professions very
different
from war and politics. But their situation alone,
without
education, experience, or even example, seems to have
formed
in them all at once the great qualities which it required,
and to
have inspired them both with abilities and virtues which
they
themselves could not well know that they possessed. If upon
some
occasions, therefore, it has animated them to actions of
magnanimity
which could not well have been expected from them, we
should
not wonder if, upon others, it has prompted them to
exploits
of somewhat a different nature.
Such
exclusive companies, therefore, are nuisances in every
respect;
always more or less inconvenient to the countries in
which
they are established, and destructive to those which have
the
misfortune to fall under their government.
CHAPTER VIII.
CONCLUSION
OF THE MERCANTILE SYSTEM.
Though
the encouragement of exportation, and the discouragement
of
importation, are the two great engines by which the mercantile
system
proposes to enrich every country, yet, with regard to some
particular
commodities, it seems to follow an opposite plan : to
discourage
exportation, and to encourage importation. Its
ultimate
object, however, it pretends, is always the same, to
enrich
the country by an advantageous balance of trade. It
discourages
the exportation of the materials of manufacture, and
of the
instruments of trade, in order to give our own workmen an
advantage,
and to enable them to undersell those of other nations
in all
foreign markets; and by restraining, in this manner, the
exportation
of a few commodities, of no great price, it proposes
to
occasion a much greater and more valuable exportation of
others.
It encourages the importation of the materials of
manufacture,
in order that our own people may be enabled to work
them up
more cheaply, and thereby prevent a greater and more
valuable
importation of the manufactured commodities. I do not
observe,
at least in our statute book, any encouragement given to
the
importation of the instruments of trade. When manufactures
have
advanced to a certain pitch of greatness, the fabrication of
the
instruments of trade becomes itself the object of agreat
number
of very important manufactures. To give any particular
encouragement
to the importation of such instruments, would
interfere
too much with the interest of those manufactures. Such
importation,
therefore, instead of being encouraged, has
frequently
been prohibited. Thus the importation of wool cards,
except
from Ireland, or when brought in as wreck or prize goods,
was
prohibited by the 3rd of Edward IV. ; which prohibition was
renewed
by the 39th of Elizabeth, and has been continued and
rendered
perpetual by subsequent laws.
The
importation of the materials of manufacture has sometimes
been
encouraged by an exemption from the duties to which other
goods
are subject, and sometimes by bounties.
The
importation of sheep's wool from several different countries,
of
cotton wool from all countries, of undressed flax, of the
greater
part of dyeing drugs, of the greater part of undressed
hides
from Ireland, or the British colonies, of seal skins from
the
British Greenland fishery, of pig and bar iron from the
British
colonies, as well as of several other materials of
manufacture,
has been encouraged by an exemption from all duties,
if
properly entered at the custom-house. The private interest of
our
merchants and manufacturers may, perhaps, have extorted from
the
legislature these exemptions, as well as the greater part of
our
other commercial regulations. They are, however, perfectly
just
and reasonable; and if, consistently with the necessities of
the
state, they could be extended to all the other materials of
manufacture,
the public would certainly be a gainer.
The
avidity of our great manufacturers, however, has in some
cases
extended these exemptions a good deal beyond what can
justly
be considered as the rude materials of their work. By the
24th
Geo. II. chap. 46, a small duty of only 1d. the pound was
imposed
upon the importation of foreign brown linen yarn, instead
of much
higher duties, to which it had been subjected before,
viz. of
6d. the pound upon sail yarn, of 1s. the pound upon all
French
and Dutch yarn, and of £2:13:4 upon the hundred weight of
all
spruce or Muscovia yarn. But our manufacturers were not long
satisfied
with this reduction: by the 29th of the same king,
chap.
15, the same law which gave a bounty upon the exportation
of
British and Irish linen, of which the price did not exceed
18d.
the yard, even this small duty upon the importation of brown
linen
yarn was taken away. In the different operations, however,
which
are necessary for the preparation of linen yarn, a good
deal
more industry is employed, than in the subsequent operation
of
preparing linen cloth from linen yarn. To say nothing of the
industry
of the flax-growers and flaxdressers, three or four
spinners
at least are necessary in order to keep one weaver in
constant
employment; and more than four-fifths of the whole
quantity
of labour necessary for the preparation of linen cloth,
is
employed in that of linen yarn ; but our spinners are poor
people;
women commonly scattered about in all different parts of
the
country, without support or protection. It is not by the sale
of
their work, but by that of the complete work of the weavers,
that
our great master manufacturers make their profits. As it is
their
interest to sell the complete manufacture as dear, so it is
to buy
the materials as cheap as possible. By extorting from the
legislature
bounties upon the exportation of their own linen,
high
duties upon the importation of all foreign linen, and a
total
prohibition of the home consumption of some sorts of French
linen,
they endeavour to sell their own goods as dear as
possible.
By encouraging the importation of foreign linen yarn,
and
thereby bringing it into competition with that which is made
by our
own people, they endeavour to buy the work of the poor
spinners
as cheap as possible. They are as intent to keep down
the
wages of their own weavers, as the earnings of the poor
spinners
; and it is by no means for the benefit of the workmen
that
they endeavour either to raise the price of the complete
work,
or to lower that of the rude materials. It is the industry
which
is carried on for the benefit of the rich and the powerful,
that is
principally encouraged by our mercantile system. That
which
is carried on for the benefit of the poor and the indigent
is too
often either neglected or oppressed.
Both
the bounty upon the exportation of linen, and the exemption
from
the duty upon the importation of foreign yarn, which were
granted
only for fifteen years, but continued by two different
prolongations,
expire with the end of the session of parliament
which
shall immediately follow the 24th of June 1786.
The
encouragement given to the importation of the materials of
manufacture
by bounties, has been principally confined to such as
were
imported from our American plantations.
The
first bounties of this kind were those granted about the
beginning
of the present century, upon the importation of naval
stores
from America. Under this denomination were comprehended
timber fit
for masts, yards, and bowsprits; hemp, tar, pitch, and
turpentine.
The bounty, however, of £1 the ton upon
masting-timber,
and that of £6 the ton upon hemp, were extended
to such
as should be imported into England from Scotland. Both
these
bounties continued, without any variation, at the same
rate,
till they were severally allowed to expire; that upon hemp
on the
1st of January 1741, and that upon masting-timber at the
end of
the session of parliament immediately following the 24th
June
1781.
The
bounties upon the importation of tar, pitch, and turpentine,
underwent,
during their continuance, several alterations.
Originally,
that upon tar was £4 the ton ; that upon pitch the
same;
and that upon turpentine £3 the ton. The bounty of £4 the
ton
upon tar was afterwards confined to such as had been prepared
in a
particular manner ; that upon other good, clean, and
merchantable
tar was reduced to £2:4s. the ton. The bounty upon
pitch
was likewise reduced to £1, and that upon turpentine to
£1:10s.
the ton.
The
second bounty upon the importation of any of the materials of
manufacture,
according to the order of time, was that granted by
the
21st Geo. II. chap.30, upon the importation of indigo from
the
British plantations. When the plantation indigo was worth
three-fourths
of the price of the best French indigo, it was, by
this
act, entitled to a bounty of 6d. the pound. This bounty,
which,
like most others, was granted only for a limited time, was
continued
by several prolongations, but was reduced to 4d. the
pound.
It was allowed to expire with the end of the session of
parliament
which followed the 25th March 1781.
The
third bounty of this kind was that granted (much about the
time
that we were beginning sometimes to court, and sometimes to
quarrel
with our American colonies), by the 4th. Geo. III. chap.
26,
upon the importation of hemp, or undressed flax, from the
British
plantations. This bounty was granted for twenty-one
years,
from the 24th June 1764 to the 24th June 1785. For the
first
seven years, it was to be at the rate of £8 the ton; for
the
second at £6; and for the third at £4. It was not extended to
Scotland,
of which the climate (although hemp is sometimes raised
there
in small quantities, and of an inferior quality) is not
very
fit for that produce. Such a bounty upon the importation of
Scotch
flax in England would have been too great a discouragement
to the
native produce of the southern part of the united kingdom.
The
fourth bounty of this kind was that granted by the 5th Geo.
III.
chap. 45, upon the importation of wood from America. It was
granted
for nine years from the 1st January 1766 to the 1st
January
1775. During the first three years, it was to be for
every
hundred-and-twenty good deals, at the rate of £1, and for
every
load containing fifty cubic feet of other square timber, at
the
rate of 12s. For the second three years, it was for deals, to
be at
the rate of 15s., and for other squared timber at the rate
of 8s.;
and for the third three years, it was for deals, to be at
the
rate of 10s.; and for every other squared timber at the rate
of 5s.
The
fifth bounty of this kind was that granted by the 9th Geo.
III.
chap. 38, upon the importation of raw silk from the British
plantations.
It was granted for twenty-one years, from the 1st
January
1770, to the 1st January 1791. For the first seven years,
it was
to be at the rate of £25 for every hundred pounds value ;
for the
second, at £20; and for the third, at £15. The management
of the
silk-worm, and the preparation of silk, requires so much
hand-labour,
and labour is so very dear in America, that even
this
great bounty, I have been informed, was not likely to
produce
any considerable effect.
The
sixth Bounty of this kind was that granted by 11th Geo. III.
chap.
50, for the importation of pipe, hogshead, and barrelstaves
and
leading from the British plantations. It was granted for nine
years,
from 1st January 1772 to the 1st January 1781. For the
first
three years, it was, for a certain quantity of each, to be
at the
rate of £6; for the second three years at £4; and for the
third
three years at £2.
The
seventh and last bounty of this kind was that granted by the
19th
Geo. III chap. 37, upon the importation of hemp from
Ireland.
It was granted in the same manner as that for the
importation
of hemp and undressed flax from America, for
twenty-one
years, from the 24th June 1779 to the 24th June 1800.
The
term is divided likewise into three periods, of seven years
each;
and in each of those periods, the rate of the Irish bounty
is the
same with that of the American. It does not, however, like
the
American bounty, extend to the importation of undressed flax.
It
would have been too great a discouragement to the cultivation
of that
plant in Great Britain. When this last bounty was
granted,
the British and Irish legislatures were not in much
better
humour with one another, than the British and American had
been
before. But this boon to Ireland, it is to be hoped, has
been
granted under more fortunate auspices than all those to
America.
The same commodities, upon which we thus gave bounties,
when
imported from America, were subjected to considerable duties
when
imported from any other country. The interest of our
American
colonies was regarded as the same with that of the
mother
country. Their wealth was considered as our wealth.
Whatever
money was sent out to them, it was said, came all back
to us
by the balance of trade, and we could never become a
farthing
the poorer by any expense which we could lay out upon
them.
They were our own in every respect, and it was an expense
laid
out upon the improvement of our own property, and for the
profitable
employment of our own people. It is unnecessary, I
apprehend,
at present to say anything further, in order to expose
the
folly of a system which fatal experience has now sufficiently
exposed.
Had our American colonies really been a part of Great
Britain,
those bounties might have been considered as bounties
upon
production, and would still have been liable to all the
objections
to which such bounties are liable, but to no other.
The
exportation of the materials of manufacture is sometimes
discouraged
by absolute prohibitions, and sometimes by high
duties.
Our woollen
manufacturers have been more successful than any
other
class of workmen, in persuading the legislature that the
prosperity
of the nation depended upon the success and extension
of
their particular business. They have not only obtained a
monopoly
against the consumers, by an absolute prohibition of
importing
woollen cloths from any foreign country; but they have
likewise
obtained another monopoly against the sheep farmers and
growers
of wool, by a similar prohibition of the exportation of
live
sheep and wool. The severity of many of the laws which have
been
enacted for the security of the revenue is very justly
complained
of, as imposing heavy penalties upon actions which,
antecedent
to the statutes that declared them to be crimes, had
always
been understood to be innocent. But the cruellest of our
revenue
laws, I will venture to affirm, are mild and gentle, in
comparison
to some of those which the clamour of our merchants
and
manufacturers has extorted from the legisiature, for the
support
of their own absurd and oppressive monopolies. Like the
laws of
Draco, these laws may be said to be all written in blood.
By the
8th of Elizabeth, chap. 3, the exporter of sheep, lambs,
or
rams, was for the first offence, to forfeit all his goods for
ever,
to suffer a year's imprisonment, and then to have his left
hand
cut off in a market town, upon a market day, to be there
nailed
up; and for the second offence, to be adjudged a felon,
and to
suffer death accordingly. To prevent the breed of our
sheep
from being propagated in foreign countries, seems to have
been
the object of this law. By the 13th and 14th of Charles II.
chap.
18, the exportation of wool was made felony, and the
exporter
subjected to the same penalties and forfeitures as a
felon.
For the
honour of the national humanity, it is to be hoped that
neither
of these statutes was ever executed. The first of them,
however,
so far as I know, has never been directly repealed, and
serjeant
Hawkins seems to consider it as still in force. It may,
however,
perhaps be considered as virtually repealed by the 12th
of
Charles II. chap. 32, sect. 3, which, without expressly taking
away
the penalties imposed by former statutes, imposes a new
penalty,
viz. that of 20s. for every sheep exported, or attempted
to be
exported, together with the forfeiture of the sheep, and of
the
owner's share of the sheep. The second of them was expressly
repealed
by the 7th and 8th of William III. chap. 28, sect. 4, by
which
it is declared that " Whereas the statute of the 13th and
14th of
king Charles II. made against the exportation of wool,
among
other things in the said act mentioned, doth enact the same
to be
deemed felony, by the severity of which penalty the
prosecution
of offenders hath not been so effectually put in
execution
; be it therefore enacted, by the authority aforesaid,
that so
much of the said act, which relates to the making the
said
offence felony, be repealed and made void."
The
penalties, however, which are either imposed by this milder
statute,
or which, though imposed by former statutes, are not
repealed
by this one, are still sufficiently severe. Besides the
forfeiture
of the goods, the exporter incurs the penalty of 3s.
for
every pound weight of wool, either exported or attempted to
be
exported, that is, about four or five times the value. Any
merchant,
or other person convicted of this offence, is disabled
from
requiring any debt or account belonging to him from any
factor
or other person. Let his fortune be
what it will,
whether
he is or is not able to pay those heavy penalties, the
law
means to ruin him completely. But, as the morals of the great
body of
the people are not yet so corrupt as those of the
contrivers
of this statute, I have not heard that any advantage
has
ever been taken of this clause. If the person convicted of
this
offence is not able to pay the penalties within three months
after
judgment, he is to be transported for seven years; and if
he
returns before the expiration of that term, he is liable to
the
pains of felony, without benefit of clergy. The owner of the
ship,
knowing this offence, forfeits all his interest in the ship
and
furniture. The master and mariners, knowing this offence,
forfeit
all their goods and chattels, and suffer three months
imprisonment.
By a subsequent statute, the master suffers six
months
imprisonment.
In
order to prevent exportation, the whole inland commerce of
wool is
laid under very burdensome and oppressive restrictions.
It
cannot be packed in any box, barrel, cask, case, chest, or any
other
package, but only in packs of leather or pack-cloth, on
which
must be marked on the outside the words WOOL or YARN, in
large
letters, not less than three inches long, on pain of
forfeiting
the same and the package, and 8s. for every pound
weight,
to be paid by the owner or packer. It cannot be loaden on
any
horse or cart, or carried by land within five miles of the
coast,
but between sun-rising, and sun-setting, on pain of
forfeiting
the same, the horses and carriages. The hundred next
adjoining
to the sea coast, out of, or through which the wool is
carried
or exported, forfeits £20, if the wool is under the value
of £10;
and if of greater value, then treble that value, together
with
treble costs, to be sued for within the year. The execution
to be
against any two of the inhabitants, whom the sessions must
reimburse,
by an assessment on the other inhabitants, as in the
cases
of robbery. And if any person compounds with the hundred
for less
than this penalty, he is to be imprisoned for five
years;
and any other person may prosecute. These regulations take
place
through the whole kingdom.
But in
the particular counties of Kent and Sussex, the
restrictions
are still more troublesome. Every owner of wool
within
ten miles of the sea coast must give an account in
writing,
three days after shearing, to the next officer of the
customs,
of the number of his fleeces, and of the places where
they
are lodged. And before he removes any part of them, he must
give
the like notice of the number and weight of the fleeces, and
of the
name and abode of the person to whom they are sold, and of
the
place to which it is intended they should be carried. No
person
within fifteen miles of the sea, in the said counties, can
buy any
wool, before he enters into bond to the king, that no
part of
the wool which he shall so buy shall be sold by him to
any
other person within fifteen miles of the sea. If any wool is
found
carrying towards the sea side in the said counties, unless
it has
been entered and security given as aforesaid, it is
forfeited,
and the offender also forfeits 3s. for every pound
weight.
if any person lay any wool, not entered as aforesaid,
within
fifteen miles of the sea, it must be seized and forfeited
; and
if, after such seizure, any person shall claim the same, he
must
give security to the exchequer, that if he is cast upon
trial
he shall pay treble costs, besides all other penalties.
When
such restrictions are imposed upon the inland trade, the
coasting
trade, we may believe, cannot be left very free. Every
owner
of wool, who carrieth, or causeth to be carried, any wool
to any
port or place on the sea coast, in order to be from thence
transported
by sea to any other place or port on the coast, must
first
cause an entry thereof to be made at the port from whence
it is
intended to be conveyed, containing the weight, marks, and
number,
of the packages, before he brings the same within five
miles
of that port, on pain of forfeiting the same, and also the
horses,
carts, and other carriages; and also of suffering and
forfeiting,
as by the other laws in force against the exportation
of
wool. This law, however (1st of William III. chap. 32), is so
very
indulgent as to declare, that this shall not hinder any
person
from carrying his wool home from the place of shearing,
though
it be within five miles of the sea, provided that in ten
days
after shearing, and before he remove the wool, he do under
his
hand certify to the next officer of the customs the true
number
of fleeces, and where it is housed; and do not remove the
same,
without certifying to such officer, under his hand, his
intention
so to do, three days before. Bond must
be given that
the
wool to be carried coast-ways is to be landed at the
particular
port for which it is entered outwards; and if my part
of it
is landed without the presence of an officer, not only the
forfeiture
of the wool is incurred, as in other goods, but the
usual
additional penalty of 3s. for every pound weight is
likewise
incurred.
Our
woollen manufacturers, in order to justify their demand of
such
extraordinary restrictions and regulations, confidently
asserted,
that English wool was of a peculiar quality, superior
to that
of any other country; that the wool of other countries
could
not, without some mixture of it, be wrought up into any
tolerable
manufacture; that fine cloth could not be made without
it ;
that England, therefore, if the exportation of it could be
totally
prevented, could monopolize to herself almost the whole
woollen
trade of the world; and thus, having no rivals, could
sell at
what price she pleased, and in a short time acquire the
most
incredible degree of wealth by the most advantageous balance
of trade.
This doctrine, like most other doctrines which are
confidently
asserted by any considerable number of people, was,
and
still continues to be, most implicitly believed by a much
greater
number: by almost all those who are either unacquainted
with the
woollen trade, or who have not made particular
inquiries.
It is, however, so perfectly false, that English wool
is in
any respect necessary for the making of fine cloth, that it
is
altogether unfit for it. Fine cloth is made altogether of
Spanish
wool. English wool, cannot be even so mixed with Spanish
wool,
as to enter into the composition without spoiling and
degrading,
in some degree, the fabric of the cloth.
It has
been shown in the foregoing part of this work, that the
effect
of these regulations has been to depress the price of
English
wool, not only below what it naturally would be in the
present
times, but very much below what it actually was in the
time of
Edward III. The price of Scotch wool, when, in
consequence
of the Union, it became subject to the same
regulations,
is said to have fallen about one half. It is
observed
by the very accurate and intelligent author of the
Memoirs
of Wool, the Reverend Mr. John Smith, that the price of
the
best English wool in England, is generally below what wool of
a very
inferior quality commonly sells for in the market of
Amsterdam.
To depress the price of this commodity below what may
be
called its natural and proper price, was the avowed purpose of
those
regulations ; and there seems to be no doubt of their
having
produced the effect that was expected from them.
This
reduction of price, it may perhaps be thought, by
discouraging
the growing of wool, must have reduced very much the
annual
produce of that commodity, though not below what it
formerly
was, yet below what, in the present state of things, it
would
probably have been, had it, in consequence of an open and
free
market, been allowed to rise to the natural and proper
price.
I am, however, disposed to believe, that the quantity of
the
annual produce cannot have been much, though it may, perhaps,
have
been a little affected by these regulations. The growing of
wool is
not the chief purpose for which the sheep farmer employs
his
industry and stock. He expects his profit, not so much from
the
price of the fleece, as from that of the carcase; and the
average
or ordinary price of the latter must even, in many cases,
make up
to him whatever deficiency there may be in the average or
ordinary
price of the former. It has been observed, in the
foregoing
part of this work, that 'whatever regulations tend to
sink
the price, either of wool or of raw hides, below what it
naturally
would be, must, in an improved and cultivated country,
have
some tendency to raise the price of butcher's meat. The
price,
both of the great and small cattle which are fed on
improved
and cultivated land, must be sufficient to pay the rent
which
the landlord, and the profit which the farmer, has reason
to
expect from improved and cultivated land. If it is not, they
will
soon cease to feed them. Whatever part of this price,
therefore,
is not paid by the wool and the hide, must be paid by
the
carcase. The less there is paid for the one, the more must be
paid
for the other. In what manner this price is to be divided
upon
the different parts of the beast, is indifferent to the
landlords
and farmers, provided it is all paid to them. In an
improved
and cultivated country, therefore, their interest as
landlords
and farmers cannot be much affected by such
regulations,
though their interest as consumers may, by the rise
in the
price of provisions.' According to this reasoning,
therefore,
this degradation in the price of wool is not likely,
in an
improved and cultivated country, to occasion any diminution
in the
annual produce of that commodity; except so far as, by
raising
the price of mutton, it may somewhat diminish the demand
for,
and consequently the production of, that particular species
of
butcher's meat, Its effect, however, even in this way, it is
probable,
is not very considerable.
But
though its effect upon the quantity of the annual produce may
not
have been very considerable, its effect upon the quality, it
may
perhaps be thought, must necessarily have been very great.
The
degradation in the quality of English wool, if not below what
it was
in former times, yet below what it naturally would have
been in
the present state of improvement and cultivation, must
have
been, it may perhaps be supposed, very nearly in proportion
to the
degradation of price. As the quality
depends upon the
breed,
upon the pasture, and upon the management and cleanliness
of the
sheep, during the whole progress of the growth of the
fleece,
the attention to these circumstances, it may naturally
enough
be imagined, can never be greater than in proportion to
the
recompence which the price of the fleece is likely to make
for the
labour and expense which that attention requires. It
happens,
however, that the goodness of the fleece depends, in a
great
measure, upon the health, growth, and bulk of the animal:
the
same attention which is necessary for the improvement of the
carcase
is, in some respect, sufficient for that of the fleece.
Notwithstanding
the degradation of price, English wool is said to
have
been improved considerably during the course even of the
present
century. The improvement, might, perhaps, have been
greater
if the price had been better; but the lowness of price,
though
it may have obstructed, yet certainly it has not
altogether
prevented that improvement.
The
violence of these regulations, therefore, seems to have
affected
neither the quantity nor the quality of the annual
produce
of wool, so much as it might have been expected to do
(though
I think it probable that it may have affected the latter
a good
deal more than the former); and the interest of the
growers
of wool, though it must have been hurt in some degree,
seems
upon the whole, to have been much less hurt than could well
have
been imagined.
These
considerations, however, will not justify the absolute
prohibition
of the exportation of wool ; but they will fully
justify
the imposition of a considerable tax upon that
exportation.
To
hurt, in any degree, the interest of any one order of
citizens,
for no other purpose but to promote that of some other,
is
evidently contrary to that justice and equality of treatment
which
the sovereign owes to all the different orders of his
subjects.
But the prohibition certainly hurts, in some degree,
the
interest of the growers of wool, for no other purpose but to
promote
that of the manufacturers.
Every
different order of citizens is bound to contribute to the
support
of the sovereign or commonwealth. A tax of five, or even
of ten
shillings, upon the exportation of every tod of wool,
would
produce a very considerable revenue to the sovereign. It
would
hurt the interest of the growers somewhat less than the
prohibition,
because it would not probably lower the price of
wool
quite so much. It would afford a sufficient advantage to the
manufacturer,
because, though he might not buy his wool
altogether
so cheap as under the prohibition, he would still buy
it at
least five or ten shillings cheaper than any foreign
manufacturer
could buy it, besides saving the freight and
insurance
which the other would be obliged to pay. It is scarce
possible
to devise a tax which could produce any considerable
revenue
to the sovereign, and at the same time occasion so little
inconveniency
to anybody.
The
prohibition, notwithstanding all the penalties which guard
it,
does not prevent the exportation of wool. It is exported, it
is well
known. in great quantities. The great difference between
the
price in the home and that in the foreign market, presents
such a
temptation to smuggling, that all the rigour of the law
cannot
prevent it. This illegal exportation is advantageous to
nobody
but the smuggler. A legal exportation, subject to a tax,
by
affording a revenue to the sovereign, and thereby saving the
imposition
of some other, perhaps more burdensome and
inconvenient
taxes, might prove advantageous to all the different
subjects
of the state.
The
exportation of fuller's earth, or fuller's clay, supposed to
be
necessary for preparing and cleansing the woollen
manufactures,
has been subjected to nearly the same penalties as
the
exportation of wool. Even tobacco-pipe clay, though
acknowledged
to be different from fuller's clay, yet, on account
of
their resemblance, and because fuller's clay might sometimes
be
exported as tobacco-pipe clay, has been laid under the same
prohibitions
and penalties.
By the
13th and 14th of Charles II. chap, 7, the exportation, not
only of
raw hides, but of tanned leather, except in the shape of
boots,
shoes, or slippers, was prohibited ; and the law gave a
monopoly
to our boot-makers and shoe-makers, not only against our
graziers,
but against our tanners. By subsequent statutes, our
tanners
have got themselves exempted from this monopoly, upon
paying
a small tax of only one shilling on the hundred weight of
tanned
leather, weighing one hundred and twelve pounds. They have
obtained
likewise the drawback of two-thirds of the excise duties
imposed
upon their commodity, even when exported without further
manufacture.
All manufactures of leather may be exported duty
free ;
and the exporter is besides entitled to the drawback of
the
whole duties of excise. Our graziers
still continue
subject
to the old monopoly. Graziers, separated from one
another,
and dispersed through all the different corners of the
country,
cannot, without great difficulty, combine together for
the
purpose either of imposing monopolies upon their
fellow-citizens,
or of exempting themselves from such as may have
been
imposed upon them by other people. Manufacturers of all
kinds,
collected together in numerous bodies in all great cities,
easily
can. Even the horns of cattle are prohibited to be
exported
; and the two insignificant trades of the horner and
comb-maker
enjoy, in this respect, a monopoly against the
graziers.
Restraints,
either by prohibitions, or by taxes, upon the
exportation
of goods which are partially, but not completely
manufactured,
are not peculiar to the manufacture of leather. As
long as
anything remains to be done, in order to fit any
commodity
for immediate use and consumption, our manufacturers
think
that they themselves ought to have the doing of it. Woollen
yarn
and worsted are prohibited to be exported, under the same
penalties
as wool even white cloths we subject to a duty upon
exportation;
and our dyers have so far obtained a monopoly
against
our clothiers. Our clothiers would probably have been
able to
defend themselves against it; but it happens that the
greater
part of our principal clothiers are themselves likewise
dyers.
Watch-cases, clock-cases, and dial-plates for clocks and
watches,
have been prohibited to be exported. Our clock-makers
and
watch-makers are, it seems, unwilling that the price of this
sort of
workmanship should be raised upon them by the competition
of
foreigners.
By some
old statutes of Edward III, Henry VIII. and Edward VI.
the
exportation of all metals was prohibited. Lead and tin were
alone
excepted, probably on account of the great abundance of
those
metals; in the exportation of which a considerable part of
the
trade of the kingdom in those days consisted. For the
encouragement
of the mining trade, the 5th of William and Mary,
chap.17,
exempted from this prohibition iron, copper, and mundic
metal
made from British ore. The exportation of all sorts of
copper
bars, foreign as well as British, was afterwards permitted
by the
9th and 10th of Willimn III. chap 26. The exportation of
unmanufactured
brass, of what is called gun-metal, bell-metal,
and
shroff metal, still continues to be prohibited. Brass
manufactures
of all sorts may be exported duty free.
The
exportation of the materials of manufacture, where it is not
altogether
prohibited, is, in many cases, subjected to
considerable
duties.
By the 8th
Geo. I. chap.15, the exportation of all goods, the
produce
of manufacture of Great Britain, upon which any duties
had
been imposed by former statutes, was rendered duty free. The
following
goods, however, were excepted: alum, lead, lead-ore,
tin, tanned
leather, copperas, coals, wool, cards, white woollen
cloths,
lapis calaminaris, skins of all sorts, glue, coney hair
or
wool, hares wool, hair of all sorts, horses, and litharge of
lead.
If you except horses, all these are either materials of
manufacture,
or incomplete manufactures (which may be considered
as
materials for still further manufacture), or instruments of
trade.
This statute leaves them subject to all the old duties
which
had ever been imposed upon them, the old subsidy, and one
per
cent. outwards.
By the
same statute, a great number of foreign drugs for dyers
use are
exempted from all duties upon importation. Each of them,
however,
is afterwards subjected to a certain duty, not indeed a
very
heavy one, upon exportation. Our dyers, it seems, while they
thought
it for their interest to encourage the importation of
those
drugs, by an exemption from all duties, thought it likewise
for
their own interest to throw some small discouragement upon
their
exportation. The avidity, however, which suggested this
notable
piece of mercantile ingenuity, most probably disappointed
itself
of its object. It necessarily taught the importers to be
more
careful than they might otherwise have been, that their
importation
should not exceed what was necessary for the supply
of the
home market. The home market was at all times likely to be
more
scantily supplied ; the commodities were at all times likely
to be
somewhat dearer there than they would have been, had the
exportation
been rendered as free as the importation.
By the
above-mentioned statute, gum senega, or gum arabic, being
among
the enumerated dyeing drugs, might be imported duty free.
They
were subjected, indeed, to a small poundage duty, amounting
only to
threepence in the hundred weight, upon their
re-exportation.
France enjoyed, at that time, an exclusive trade
to the
country most productive of those drugs, that which lies in
the
neighbourhood of the Senegal ; and the British market could
not be
easily supplied by the immediate importation of them from
the
place of growth. By the 25th Geo. II. therefore, gum senega
was
allowed to be imported (contrary to the general dispositions
of the
act of navigation) from any part of Europe. As the law,
however,
did not mean to encourage this species of trade, so
contrary
to the general principles of the mercantile policy of
England,
it imposed a duty of ten shillings the hundred weight
upon
such importation, and no part of this duty was to be
afterwards
drawn back upon its exportation. The successful war
which
began in 1755 gave Great Britain the same exclusive trade
to
those countries which France had enjoyed before. Our
manufactures,
as soon as the peace was made, endeavoured to avail
themselves
of this advantage, and to establish a monopoly in
their
own favour both against the growers and against the
importers
of this comnmdity. By the 5th of Geo. III. therefore,
chap.
37, the exportation of gum senega, from his majesty's
dominions
in Africa, was confined to Great Britain, and was
subjected
to all the same restrictions, regulations, forfeitures,
and
penalties, as that of the enumerated commodities of the
British
colonies in America and the West Indies. Its importation,
indeed,
was subjected to a small duty of sixpence the hundred
weight;
but its re-exportation was subjected to the enormous duty
of one
pound ten shillings the hundred weight. It was the
intention
of our manufacturers, that the whole produce of those
countries
should be imported into Great Britain; and in order
that
they themselves might he enabled to buy it at their own
price,
that no part of it should be exported again, but at such
an
expense as would sufficiently discourage that exportation.
Their
avidity, however, upon this, as well as upon many other
occasions,
disappointed itself of its object. This enormous duty
presented
such a temptation to smuggling, that great quantities
of this
commodity were clandestinely exported, probably to all
the
manufacturing countries of Europe, but particularly to
Holland,
not only from Great Britain, but from Afrira. Upon this
account,
by the 14th Geo. III. chap.10, this duty upon
exportation
was reduced to five shillings the hundred weight.
In the
book of rates, according to which the old subsidy was
levied,
beaver skins were estimated at six shillings and eight
pence a
piece; and the different subsidies and imposts which,
before
the year 1722, had been laid upon their importation,
amounted
to one-fifth part of the rate, or to sixteen pence upon
each
skin; all of which, except half the old subsidy, amounting
only to
twopence, was drawn back upon exportation. This duty,
upon
the importation of so important a material of manufacture,
had
been thought too high; and, in the year 1722, the rate was
reduced
to two shillings and sixpence, which reduced the duty
upon
importation to sixpence, and of this only one-half was to be
drawn
back upon exportation. The same successful war put the
country
most productive of beaver under the dominion of Great
Britain
; and beaver skins being among the enumerated
commodities,
the exportation from America was consequently
confined
to the market of Great Britain. Our manufacturers soon
bethought
themselves of the advantage which they might make of
this
circumstance; and in the year 1764, the duty upon the
importation
of beaver skin was reduced to one penny, but the duty
upon
exportation was raised to sevenpence each skin, without any
drawback
of the duty upon importation. By the same law, a duty of
eighteen
pence the pound was imposed upon the exportation of
beaver
wool or woumbs, without making any alteration in the duty
upon
the importation of that commodity, which, when imported by
British,
and in British shipping, amounted at that time to
between
fourpence and fivepence the piece.
Coals
may be considered both as a material of manufacture, and as
an
instrument of trade. Heavy duties, accordingly, have been
imposed
upon their exportation, amounting at present (1783) to
more
than five shillings the ton, or more than fifteen shillings
the
chaldron, Newcastle measure ; which is, in most cases, more
than
the original value of the commodity at the coal-pit, or even
at the
shipping port for exportation.
The
exportation, however, of the instruments of trade, properly
so
called, is commonly restrained, not by high duties, but by
absolute
prohibitions. Thus, by the 7th and 8th of William III
chap.20,
sect.8, the exportation of frames or engines for
knitting
gloves or stockings, is prohibited, under the penalty,
not
only of the forfeiture of such frames or engines, so
exported,
or attempted to be exported, but of forty pounds, one
half to
the king, the other to the person who shall inform or sue
for the
same. In the same manner, by the 14th Geo. III. chap. 71,
the
exportation to foreign parts, of any utensils made use of in
the
cotton, linen, woollen, and silk manufactures, is prohibited
under
the penalty, not only of the forfeiture of such utensils,
but of
two hundred pounds, to be paid by the person who shall
offend
in this manner ; and likewise of two hundred pounds, to be
paid by
the master of the ship, who shall knowingly suffer such
utensils
to be loaded on board his ship.
When
such heavy penalties were imposed upon the exportation of
the
dead instruments of trade, it could not well be expected that
the
living instrument, the artificer, should be allowed to go
free.
Accordingly, by the 5th Geo. I. chap. 27, the person who
shall
be convicted of enticing any artificer, of or in any of the
manufactures
of Great Britain, to go into any foreign parts, in
order
to practise or teach his trade, is liable, for the first
offence,
to be fined in any sum not exceeding one hundred pounds,
and to
three months imprisomnent, and until the fine shall be
paid ;
and for the second offence, to be fined in any sum, at the
discretion
of the court, and to imprisonment for twelve months,
and
until the fine shall be paid. By the 23d Geo. II. chap. 13,
this
penalty is increased, for the first offence, to five hundred
pounds
for every artificer so enticed, and to twelve months
imprisonment,
and until the fine shall be paid ; and for the
second
offence, to one thousand pounds, and to two years
imprisonment,
and until the fine shall be paid.
By the
former of these two statutes, upon proof that any person
has
been enticing any artificer, or that any artificer has
promised
or contracted to go into foreign parts, for the purposes
aforesaid,
such artificer may be obliged to give security, at the
discretion
of the court, that he shall not go beyond the seas,
and may
be committed to prison until he give such security.
If any
artificer has gone beyond the seas, and is exercising or
teaching
his trade in any foreign country, upon warning being
given
to him by any of his majesty's ministers or consuls abroad,
or by
one of his majesty's secretaries of state, for the time
being,
if he does not, within six months after such warning,
return
into this realm, and from henceforth abide and inhabit
continually
within the same, he is from thenceforth declared
incapable
of taking any legacy devised to him within this
kingdom,
or of being executor or administrator to any person, or
of
taking any lands within this kingdom, by descent, devise, or
purchase.
He likewise forfeits to the king all his lands, goods,
and
chattels; is declared an alien in every respect; and is put
out of
the king's protection.
It is
unnecessary, I imagine, to observe how contrary such
regulations
are to the boasted liberty of the subject, of which
we
affect to be so very jealous ; but which, in this case, is so
plainly
sacrificed to the futile interests of our merchants and
manufacturers.
The
laudable motive of all these regulations, is to extend our
own
manufactures, not by their own improvement, but by the
depression
of those of all our neighbours, and by putting an end,
as much
as possible, to the troublesome competition of such
odious
and disagreeable rivals. Our master manufacturers think it
reasonable
that they themselves should have the monopoly of the
ingenuity
of all their countrymen. Though by restraining, in some
trades,
the number of apprentices which can be employed at one
time,
and by imposing the necessity of a long apprenticeship in
all
trades, they endeavour, all of them, to confine the knowledge
of
their respective employments to as small a number as possible
; they
are unwilling, however, that any part of this small number
should
go abroad to instruct foreigners.
Consumption
is the sole end and purpose of all production ; and
the
interest of the producer ought to be attended to, only so far
as it
may be necessary for promoting that of the consumer.
The
maxim is so perfectly self-evident, that it would be absurd
to
attempt to prove it. But in the mercantile system, the
interest
of the consumer is almost constantly sacrificed to that
of the
producer ; and it seems to consider production, and not
consumption,
as the ultimate end and object of all industry and
commerce.
In the
restraints upon the importation of all foreign commodities
which
can come into competition with those of our own growth or
manufacture,
the interest of the home consumer is evidently
sacrificed
to that of the producer. It is altogether for the
benefit
of the latter, that the former is obliged to pay that
enhancement
of price which this monopoly almost always occasions.
It is
altogether for the benefit of the producer, that bounties
are
granted upon the exportation of some of his productions. The
home
consumer is obliged to pay, first the tax which is necessary
for
paying the bounty ; and, secondly, the still greater tax
which
necessarily arises from the enhancement of the price of the
commodity
in the home market.
By the
famous treaty of commerce with Portugal, the consumer is
prevented
by duties from purchasing of a neighbouring country, a
commodity
which our own climate does not produce ; but is obliged
to
purchase it of a distant country, though it is acknowledged,
that
the commodity of the distant country is of a worse quality
than
that of the near one. The home consumer is obliged to submit
to this
inconvenience, in order that the producer may import into
the
distant country some of his productions, upon more
advantageous
terms than he otherwise would have been allowed to
do. The
consumer, too, is obliged to pay whatever enhancement in
the
price of those very productions this forced exportation may
occasion
in the home market.
But in
the system of laws which has been established for the
management
of our American and West Indian colonies, the interest
of the
home consumer has been sacrificed to that of the producer,
with a
more extravagant profusion than in all our other
commercial
regulations. A great empire has been established for
the
sole purpose of raising up a nation of customers, who should
be
obliged to buy, from the shops of our different producers, all
the
goods with which these could supply them. For the sake of
that
little enhancement of price which this monopoly might afford
our
producers, the home consumers have been burdened with the
whole
expense of maintaining and defending that empire. For this
purpose,
and for this purpose only, in the two last wars, more
than
two hundred millions have been spent, and a new debt of more
than a
hundred and seventy millions has been contracted, over and
above
all that had been expended for the same purpose in former
wars. The interest of this debt alone is not
only greater
than
the whole extraordinary profit which, it never could be
pretended,
was made by the monopoly of the colony trade, but than
the
whole value of that trade, or than the whole value of the
goods
which, at an average, have been annually exported to the
colonies.
It
cannot be very difficult to determine who have been the
contrivers
of this whole mercantile system; not the consumers, we
may
believe, whose interest has been entirely neglected; but the
producers,
whose interest has been so carefully attended to ; and
among
this latter class, our merchants and manufacturers have
been by
far the principal architects. In the mercantile
regulations
which have been taken notice of in this chapter, the
interest
of our manufacturers has been most peculiarly attended
to; and
the interest, not so much of the consumers, as that of
some
other sets of producers, has been sacrificed to it.
CHAPTER IX.
OF THE
AGRICULTURAL SYSTEMS, OR OF THOSE SYSTEMS OF POLITICAL
ECONOMY
WHICH REPRESENT THE PRODUCE OF LAND, AS EITHER THE SOLE
OR THE
PRINCIPAL SOURCE OF THE REVENUE AND WEALTH OF EVERY
COUNTRY.
The
agricultural systems of political economy will not require so
long an
explanation as that which I have thought it necessary to
bestow
upon the mercantile or commercial system.
That
system which represents the produce of land as the sole
source
of the revenue and wealth of every country, has so far as
I know,
never been adopted by any nation, and it at present
exists
only in the speculations of a few men of great learning
and ingenuity
in France. It would not, surely, be worth while to
examine
at great length the errors of a system which never has
done,
and probably never will do, any harm in any part of the
world.
I shall endeavour to explain, however, as distinctly as I
can,
the great outlines of this very ingenious system.
Mr.
Colbert, the famous minister of Lewis XIV. was a man of
probity,
of great industry, and knowledge of detail ; of great
experience
and acuteness in the examination of public accounts;
and of
abilities, in short, every way fitted for introducing
method
and good order into the collection and expendture of the
public
revenue. That minister had unfortunately embraced all the
prejudices
of the mercantile system, in its nature and essence a
system
of restraint and regulation, and such as could scarce fail
to be
agreeable to a laborious and plodding man of business, who
had
been accustomed to regulate the different departments of
public
offices, and to establish the necessary checks and
controlls
for confining each to its proper sphere. The industry
and
commerce of a great country, he endeavoured to regulate upon
the
same model as the departments of a public office ; and
instead
of allowing every man to pursue his own interest his own
way,
upon the liberal plan of equality, liberty, and justice, he
bestowed
upon certain branches of industry extraordinary
privileges,
while he laid others under as extraordinary
restraints.
He was not only disposed, like other European
ministers,
to encourage more the industry of the towns than that
of the
country; but, in order to support the industry of the
towns,
he was willing even to depress and keep down that of the
country.
In order to render provisions cheap to the inhabitants
of the
towns, and thereby to encourage manufactures and foreign
commerce,
he prohibited altogether the exportation of corn, and
thus
excluded the inhabitants of the country from every foreign
market,
for by far the most important part of the produce of
their
industry. This prohibition, joined to the restraints
imposed
by the ancient provincial laws of France upon the
transportation
of corn from one province to another, and to the
arbitrary
and degading taxes which are levied upon the
cultivators
in almost all the provinces, discouraged and kept
down
the agriculture of that country very much below the state to
which
it would naturally have risen in so very fertile a soil,
and so
very happy a climate. This state of discouragement and
depression
was felt more or less in every different part of the
country,
and many different inquiries were set on foot concerning
the
causes of it. One of those causes appeared to be the
preference
given, by the institutions of Mr. Colbert, to the
industry
of the towns above that of the country.
If the
rod be bent too much one way, says the proverb, in order
to make
it straight, you must bend it as much the other. The
French
philosophers, who have proposed the system which
represents
agriculture as the sole source of the revenue and
wealth
of every country, seem to have adopted this proverbial
maxim;
and, as in the plan of Mr. Colbert, the industry of the
towns
was certainly overvalued in comparison with that of the
country,
so in their system it seems to be as certainly
under-valued.
The
different orders of people, who have ever been supposed to
contribute
in any respect towards the annual produce of the land
and
labour of the country, they divide into three classes. The
first
is the class of the proprietors of land. The second is the
class
of the cultivators, of farmers and country labourers, whom
they
honour with the peculiar appellation of the productive
class.
The third is the class of artificers, manufacturers, and
merchants,
whom they endeavour to degrade by the humiliating
appellation
of the barren or unproductive class.
The
class of proprietors contributes to the annual produce, by
the
expense which they may occasionally lay out upon the
improvement
of the land, upon the buildings, drains, inclosures,
and other
ameliorations, which they may either make or maintain
upon
it, and by means of which the cultivators are enabled, with
the
same capital, to raise a greater produce, and consequently to
pay a
greater rent. This advanced rent may be considered as the
interest
or profit due to the proprietor, upon the expense or
capital
which be thus employs in the improvement of his land.
Such
expenses are in this system called ground expenses (depenses
foncieres).
The
cultivators or farmers contribute to the annual produce, by
what
are in this system called the original and annual expenses
(depenses
primitives, et depenses annuelles), which they lay out
upon
the cultivation of the land. The original expenses consist
in the
instruments of husbandry, in the stock of cattle, in the
seed,
and in the maintenance of the farmer's family, servants,
and
cattle, during at least a great part of the first year of his
occupancy,
or till he can receive some return from the land. The
annual
expenses consist in the seed, in the wear and tear of
instruments
of husbandry, and in the annual maintenance of the
farmer's
servants and cattle, and of his family too, so far as
any
part of them can be considered as servants employed in
cultivation.
That part of the produce of the land which remains
to him
after paying the rent, ought to be sufficient, first, to
replace
to him, within a reasonable time, at least during the
term of
his occupancy, the whole of his original expenses,
together
with the ordinary profits of stock; and, secondly, to
replace
to him annually the whole of his annual expenses,
together
likewise with the ordinary profits of stock. Those two
sorts
of expenses are two capitals which the farmer employs in
cultivation;
and unless they are regularly restored to him,
together
with a reasonable profit, he cannot carry on his
employment
upon a level with other employments; but, from a
regard
to his own interest, must desert it as soon as possible,
and
seek some other. That part of the produce of the land which
is thus
necessary for enabling the farmer to continue his
business,
ought to be considered as a fund sacred to cultivation,
which,
if the landlord violates, he necessarily reduces the
produce
of his own land, and, in a few years, not only disables
the
farmer from paying this racked rent, but from paying the
reasonable
rent which he might otherwise have got for his land.
The
rent which properly belongs to the landlord, is no more than
the
neat produce which remains after paying, in the completest
manner,
all the necessary expenses which must be previously laid
out, in
order to raise the gross or the whole produce. It is
because
the labour of the cultivators, over and above paying
completely
all those necessary expenses, affords a neat produce
of this
kind, that this class of people are in this system
peculiarly
distinguished by the honourable appellation of the
productive
class. Their original and annual expenses are for the
same
reason called, In this system, productive expenses, because,
over
and above replacing their own value, they occasion the
annual
reproduction of this neat produce.
The
ground expenses, as they are called, or what the landlord
lays
out upon the improvement of his land, are, in this system,
too,
honoured with the appellation of productive expenses. Till
the
whole of those expenses, together with the ordinary profits
of
stock, have been completely repaid to him by the advanced rent
which
he gets from his land, that advanced rent ought to be
regarded
as sacred and inviolable, both by the church and by the
king ;
ought to be subject neither to tithe nor to taxation. If
it is
otherwise, by discouraging the improvement of land, the
church
discourages the future increase of her own tithes, and the
king
the future increase of his own taxes. As in a well ordered
state
of things, therefore, those ground expenses, over and above
reproducing
in the completest manner their own value, occasion
likewise,
after a certain time, a reproduction of a neat produce,
they are
in this system considered as productive expenses.
The
ground expenses of the landlord, however, together with the
original
and the annual expenses of the farmer, are the only
three
sorts of expenses which in this system are considered as
productive.
All other expenses, and all other orders of people,
even
those who, in the common apprehensions of men, are regarded
as the
most productive, are, in this account of things,
represented
as altogether barren and unproductive.
Artificers
and manufacturers, in particular, whose industry, in
the
common apprehensions of men, increases so much the value of
the
rude produce of land, are in this system represented as a
class
of people altogether barren and unproductive. Their labour,
it is
said, replaces only the stock which employs them, together
with
its ordinary profits. That stock consists in the materials,
tools,
and wages, advanced to them by their employer; and is the
fund
destined for their employment and maintenance. Its profits
are the
fund destined for the maintenance of their employer.
Their
employer, as he advances to them the stock of materials,
tools,
and wages, necessary for their employment, so he advances
to
himself what is necessary for his own maintenance; and this
maintenance
he generally proportions to the profit which he
expects
to make by the price of their work. Unless its price
repays
to him the maintenance which he advances to himself, as
well as
the materials, tools, and wages, which he advances to his
workmen,
it evidently does not repay to him the whole expense
which
he lays out upon it. The profits of manufacturing stock,
therefore,
are not, like the rent of land, a neat produce which
remains
after completely repaying the whole expense which must be
laid
out in order to obtain them. The stock of the farmer yields
him a
profit, as well as that of the master manufacturer; and it
yields
a rent likewise to another person, which that of the
master
manufacturer does not. The expense, therefore, laid out in
employing
and maintaining artificers and manufacturers, does no
more
than continue, if one may say so, the existence of its own
value,
and does not produce any new value. It is, therefore,
altogether
a barren and unproductive expense. The expense, on the
contrary,
laid out in employing farmers and country labourers,
over
and above continuing the existence of its own value,
produces
a new value the rent of the landlord. It is, therefore,
a
productive expense.
Mercantile
stock is equally barren and unproductive with
manufacturing
stock. It only continues the existence of its own
value,
without producing any new value. Its profits are only the
repayment
of the maintenance which its employer advances to
himself
during the time that he employs it, or till he receives
the
returns of it. They are only the repayment of a part of the
expense
which must be laid out in employing it.
The
labour of artificers and manufacturers never adds any thing
to the
value of the whole annual amount of the rude produce of
the
land. It adds, indeed, greatly to the value of some
particular
parts of it. But the consumption which, in the mean
time,
it occasions of other parts, is precisely equal to the
value
which it adds to those parts; so that the value of the
whole
amount is not, at any one moment of time, in the least
augmented
by it. The person who works the lace of a pair of fine
ruffles
for example, will sometimes raise the value of, perhaps,
a
pennyworth of flax to £30 sterling. But though, at first sight,
he appears
thereby to multiply the value of a part of the rude
produce
about seven thousand and two hundred times, he in reality
adds
nothing to the value of the whole annual amount of the rude
produce.
The working of that lace costs him, perhaps, two years
labour.
The £30 which he gets for it when it is finished, is no
more
than the repayment of the subsistence which he advances to
himself
during the two years that he is employed about it. The
value
which, by every day's, month's, or year's labour, he adds
to the
flax, does no more than replace the value of his own
consumption
during that day, month, or year. At no moment of
time,
therefore, does he add any thing to the value of the whole
annual
amount of the rude produce of the land : the portion of
that
produce which he is continually consuming, being always
equal
to the value which he is continually producing. The extreme
poverty
of the greater part of the persons employed in this
expensive,
though trifling manufacture, may satisfy us that the
price
of their work does not, in ordinary cases, exceed the value
of
their subsistence. It is otherwise with the work of farmers
and
country labourers. The rent of the landlord is a value which,
in
ordinary cases, it is continually producing over and above
replacing,
in the most complete manner, the whole consumption,
the
whole expense laid out upon the employment and maintenance
both of
the workmen and of their employer.
Artificers,
manufacturers, and merchants, can augment the revenue
and
wealth of their society by parsimony only ; or, as it is
expressed
in this system, by privation, that is, by depriving
themselves
of a part of the funds destined for their own
subsistence. They annually reproduce nothing but those
funds.
Unless,
therefore, they annually save some part of them, unless
they
annually deprive themselves of the enjoyment of some part of
them,
the revenue and wealth of their society can never be, in
the
smallest degree, augmented by means of their industry.
Farmers
and country labourers, on the contrary, may enjoy
completely
the whole funds destined for their own subsistence,
and yet
augment, at the same time, the revenue and wealth of
their
society. Over and above what is destined for their own
subsistence,
their industry annually affords a neat produce, of
which
the augmentation necessarily augments the revenue and
wealth
of their society. Nations, therefore, which, like France
or
England, consist in a great measure, of proprietors and
cultivators,
can be enriched by industry and enjoyment.
Nations,
on the contrary, which, like Holland and Hamburgh, are
composed
chiefly of merchants, artificers, and manufacturers, can
grow
rich only through parsimony and privation. As the interest
of
nations so differently circumstanced is very different, so is
likewise
the common character of the people. In those of the
former
kind, liberality, frankness, and good fellowship,
naturally
make a part of their common character ; in the latter,
narrowness,
meanness, and a selfish disposition, averse to all
social
pleasure and enjoyment.
The
unproductive class, that of merchants, artificers, and
manufacturers,
is maintained and employed altogether at the
expense
of the two other classes, of that of proprietors, and of
that of
cultivators. They furnish it both with the materials of
its
work, and with the fund of its subsistence, with the corn and
cattle
which it consumes while it is employed about that work.
The
proprietors and cultivators finally pay both the wages of all
the
workmen of the unproductive class, and the profits of all
their
employers. Those workmen and their employers are properly
the
servants of the proprietors and cultivators. They are only
servants
who work without doors, as menial servants work within.
Both
the one and the other, however, are equally maintained at
the
expense of the same masters. The labour of both is equally
unproductive.
It adds nothing to the value of the sum total of
the
rude produce of the land. Instead of increasing the value of
that
sum total, it is a charge and expense which must be paid out
of it.
The
unproductive class, however, is not only useful, but greatly
useful,
to the other two classes. By means of the industry of
merchants,
artificers, and manufacturers, the proprietors and
cultivators
can purchase both the foreign goods and the
manufactured
produce of their own country, which they have
occasion
for, with the produce of a much smaller quantity of
their
own labour, than what they would be obliged to employ, if
they
were to attempt, in an awkward and unskilful manner, either
to
import the one, or to make the other, for their own use. By
means
of the unproductive class, the cuitivators are delivered
from
many cares, which would otherwise distract their attention
from
the cultivation of land. The superiority of produce, which
in
consequence of this undivided attention, they are enabled to
raise,
is fully sufficient to pay the whole expense which the
maintenance
and employment of the unproductive class costs either
the
proprietors or themselves. The industry of merchants,
artificers,
and manufacturers, though in its own nature
altogether
unproductive, yet contributes in this manner
indirectly
to increase the produce of the land. It increases the
productive
powers of productive labour, by leaving it at liberty
to
confine itself to its proper employment, the cultivation of
land ;
and the plough goes frequently the easier and the better,
by
means of the labour of the man whose business is most remote
from
the plough.
It can
never be the interest of the proprietors and cultivators,
to
restrain or to discourage, in any respect, the industry of
merchants,
artificers, and manufacturers. The greater the liberty
which
this unproductive class enjoys, the greater will be the
competition
in all the different trades which compose it, and the
cheaper
will the other two classes be supplied, both with foreign
goods
and with the manufactured produce of their own country.
It can
never be the interest of the unproductive class to oppress
the
other two classes. It is the surplus produce of the land, or
what
remains after deducting the maintenance, first of the
cultivators,
and afterwards of the proprietors, that maintains
and
employs the unproductive class. The greater this surplus, the
greater
must likewise be the maintenance and employment of that
class.
The establishment of perfect justice, of perfect liberty,
and of
perfect equality, is the very simple secret which most
effectually
secures the highest degree of prosperity to all the
three
classes.
The
merchants, artificers, and manufacturers of those mercantile
states,
which, like Holland and Hamburgh, consist chiefly of this
unproductive
class, are in the same manner maintained and
employed
altogether at the expense of the proprietors and
cultivators
of land. The only difference is, that those
proprietors
and cultivators are, the greater part of them, placed
at a
most inconvenient distance from the merchants, artificers,
and
manufacturers, whom they supply with the materials of their
work
and the fund of their subsistence; are the inhabitants of
other
countries, and the subjects of other governments.
Such
mercantile states, however, are not only useful, but greatly
useful,
to the inhabitants of those other countries. They fill
up, in
some measure, a very important void ; and supply the place
of the
merchants, artificers, and manufacturers, whom the
inhabitants
of those countries ought to find at home, but whom,
from
some defect in their policy, they do not find at home.
It can
never be the interest of those landed nations, if I may
call
them so, to discourage or distress the industry of such
mercantile
states, by imposing high duties upon their trade, or
upon
the commodities which they furnish.
Such duties, by
rendering
those commodities dearer, could serve only to sink the
real
value of the surplus produce of their own land, with which,
or,
what comes to the same thing, with the price of which those
commodities
are purchased. Such duties could
only serve to
discourage
the increase of that surplus produce, and consequently
the
improvement and cultivation of their own land. The most
effectual
expedient, on the contrary, for raising the value of
that
surplus produce, for encouraging its increase, and
consequently
the improvement and cultivation of their own land,
would
be to allow the most perfect freedom to the trade of all
such
mercantile nations.
This
perfect freedom of trade would even be the most effectual
expedient
for supplying them, in due time, with all the
artificers,
manufacturers, and merchants, whom they wanted at
home;
and for filling up, in the properest and most advantageous
manner,
that very important void which they felt there.
The continual
increase of the surplus produce of their land
would,
in due time, create a greater capital than what would be
employed
with the ordinary rate of profit in the improvement and
cultivation
of land; and the surplus part of it would naturally
turn itself
to the employment of artificers and manufacturers, at
home.
But these artificers and manufacturers, finding at home
both
the materials of their work and the fund of their
subsistence,
might immediately, even with much less art and skill
be able
to work as cheap as the little artificers and
manufacturers
of such mercantile states, who had both to bring
from a
greater distance. Even though, from want of art and skill,
they
might not for some time be able to work as cheap, yet,
finding
a market at home, they might be able to sell their work
there
as cheap as that of the artificers and manufacturers of
such
mercantile states. which could not be brought to that market
but
from so great a distance ; and as their art and skill
improved,
they would soon be able to sell it cheaper. The
artificers
and manufacturers of such mercantile states,
therefore,
would immediately be rivalled in the market of those
landed
nations, and soon after undersold and justled out of it
altogether.
The cheapness of the manufactures of those landed
nations,
in consequence of the gradual improvements of art and
skill,
would, in due time, extend their sale beyond the home
market,
and carry them to many foreign markets, from which they
would,
in the same manner, gradually justle out many of the
manufacturers
of such mercantile nations.
This
continual increase, both of the rude and manufactured
produce
of those landed nations, would, in due time, create a
greater
capital than could, with the ordinary rate of profit, be
employed
either in agriculture or in manufactures. The surplus of
this
capital would naturally turn itself to foreign trade and be
employed
in exporting, to foreign countries, such parts of the
rude
and manufactured produce of its own country, as exceeded the
demand
of the home market. In the exportation of the produce of
their
own country, the merchants of a landed nation would have an
advantage
of the same kind over those of mercantile nations,
which
its artificers and manufacturers had over the artificers
and
manufacturers of such nations; the advantage of finding at
home
that cargo, and those stores and provisions, which the
others
were obliged to seek for at a distance. With inferior art
and
skill in navigation, therefore, they would be able to sell
that
cargo as cheap in foreign markets as the merchants of such
mercantile
nations; and with equal art and skill they would be
able to
sell it cheaper. They would soon, therefore, rival those
mercantile
nations in this branch of foreign trade, and, in due
time,
would justle them out of it altogether.
According
to this liberal and generous system, therefore, the
most
advantageous method in which a landed nation can raise up
artificers,
manufacturers, and merchants of its own, is to grant
the
most perfect freedom of trade to the artificers,
manufacturers,
and merchants of all other nations. It thereby
raises
the value of the surplus produce of its own land, of which
the
continual increase gradually establishes a fund, which, in
due
time, necessarily raises up all the artificers,
manufacturers,
and merchants, whom it has occasion for.
When a
landed nation on the contrary, oppresses, either by high
duties
or by prohibitions, the trade of foreign nations, it
necessarily
hurts its own interest in two different ways. First,
by
raising the price of all foreign goods, and of all sorts of
manufactures,
it necessarily sinks the real value of the surplus
produce
of its own land, with which, or, what comes to the same
thing,
with the price of which, it purchases those foreign goods
and
manufactures. Secondly, by giving a sort of monopoly of the
home
market to its own merchants, artificers, and manufacturers,
it
raises the rate of mercantile and manufacturing profit, in
proportion
to that of agricultural profit; and, consequently,
either
draws from agriculture a part of the capital which had
before
been employed in it, or hinders from going to it a part of
what
would otherwise have gone to it. This policy, therefore,
discourages
agriculture in two different ways; first, by sinking
the
real value of its produce, and thereby lowering the rate of
its
profits; and, secondly, by raising the rate of profit in all
other
employments. Agriculture is rendered less advantageous, and
trade
and manufactures more advantageous, than they otherwise
would
be; and every man is tempted by his own interest to turn,
as much
as he can, both his capital and his industry from the
former
to the latter employments.
Though,
by this oppressive policy, a landed nation should be able
to
raise up artificers, manufacturers, and merchants of its own,
somewhat
sooner than it could do by the freedom of trade; a
matter,
however, which is not a little doubtful ; yet it would
raise
them up, if one may say so, prematurely, and before it was
perfectly
ripe for them. By raising up too hastily one species of
industry,
it would depress another more valuable species of
industry.
By raising up too hastily a species of industry which
duly
replaces the stock which employs it, together with the
ordinary
profit, it would depress a species of industry which,
over
and above replacing that stock, with its profit, affords
likewise
a neat produce, a free rent to the landlord. It would
depress
productive labour, by encouraging too hastily that labour
which
is altogether barren and unproductive.
In what
manner, according to this system, the sum total of the
annual
produce of the land is distributed among the three classes
above
mentioned, and in what manner the labour of the
unproductive
class does no more than replace the value of its own
consumption,
without increasing in any respect the value of that
sum
total, is represented by Mr Quesnai, the very ingenious and
profound
author of this system, in some arithmetical formularies.
The
first of these formularies, which, by way of eminence, he
peculiarly
distinguishes by the name of the Economical Table,
represents
the manner in which he supposes this distribution
takes
place, in a state of the most perfect liberty, and,
therefore,
of the highest prosperity; in a state where the annual
produce
is such as to afford the greatest possible neat produce,
and
where each class enjoys its proper share of the whole annual
produce.
Some subsequent formularies represent the manner in
which
he supposes this distribution is made in different states
of
restraint and regulation ; in which, either the class of
proprietors,
or the barren and unproductive class, is more
favoured
than the class of cultivators ; and in which either the
one or
the other encroaches, more or less, upon the share which
ought
properly to belong to this productive class. Every such
encroachment,
every violation of that natural distribution, which
the
most perfect liberty would establish, must, according to this
system,
necessarily degrade, more or less, from one year to
another,
the value and sum total of the annual produce, and must
necessarily
occasion a gradual declension in the real wealth and
revenue
of the society ; a declension, of which the progress must
be
quicker or slower, according to the degree of this
encroachment,
according as that natural distribution, which the
most
perfect liberty would establish, is more or less violated.
Those
subsequent formularies represent the different degrees of
declension
which, according to this system, correspond to the
different
degrees in which this natural distribution of things is
violated.
Some
speculative physicians seem to have imagined that the health
of the
human body could be preserved only by a certain precise
regimen
of diet and exercise, of which every, the smallest
violation,
necessarily occasioned some degree of disease or
disorder
proportionate to the degree of the violation.
Experience,
however, would seem to shew, that the human body
frequently
preserves, to all appearance at least, the most
perfect
state of health under a vast variety of different
regimens;
even under some which are generally believed to be very
far
from being perfectly wholesome. But the healthful state of
the
human body, it would seem, contains in itself some unknown
principle
of preservation, capable either of preventing or of
correcting,
in many respects, the bad effects even of a very
faulty
regimen. Mr Quesnai, who was himself a physician, and a
very
speculative physician, seems to have entertained a notion of
the
same kind concerning the political body, and to have imagined
that it
would thrive and prosper only under a certain precise
regimen,
the exact regimen of perfect liberty and perfect
justice.
He seems not to have considered, that in the political
body,
the natural effort which every man is continually making to
better
his own condition, is a principle of preservation capable
of
preventing and correcting, in many respects, the bad effects
of a
political economy, in some degree both partial and
oppressive.
Such a political economy, though it no doubt retards
more or
less, is not always capable of stopping altogether, the
natural
progress of a nation towards wealth and prosperity, and
still
less of making it go backwards. If a nation could not
prosper
without the enjoyment of perfect liberty and perfect
justice,
there is not in the world a nation which could ever have
prospered.
In the political body, however, the wisdom of nature
has
fortunately made ample provision for remedying many of the
bad
effects of the folly and injustice of man ; it the same
manner
as it has done in the natural body, for remedying those of
his
sloth and intemperance.
The
capital error of this system, however, seems to lie in its
representing
the class of artificers, manufacturers, and
merchants,
as altogether barren and unproductive. The following
observations
may serve to shew the impropriety of this
representation
: ˜
First, this class, it is acknowledged, reproduces annually the
value
of its own annual consmnption, and continues, at least, the
existence
of the stock or capital which maintains and employs it.
But,
upon this account alone, the denomination of barren or
unproductive
should seem to be very improperly applied to it. We
should
not call a marriage barren or unproductive, though it
produced
only a son and a daughter, to replace the father and
mother,
and though it did not increase the number of the human
species,
but only continued it as it was before. Farmers and
country
labourers, indeed, over and above the stock which
maintains
and employs them, reproduce annually a neat produce, a
free
rent to the landlord. As a marriage which affords three
children
is certainly more productive than one which affords only
two, so
the labour of farmers and country labourers is certainly
more
productive than that of merchants, artificers, and
manufacturers.
The superior produce of the one class, however,
does
not, render the other barren or unproductive.
Secondly, it seems, on this account, altogether
improper to
consider
artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, in the same
light
as menial servants. The labour of menial servants does not
continue
the existence of the fund which maintains and employs
them.
Their maintenance and employment is altogether at the
expense
of their masters, and the work which they perform is not
of a
nature to repay that expense. That work consists in services
which
perish generally in the very instant of their performance,
and
does not fix or realize itself in any vendible commodity,
which
can replace the value of their wages and maintenance. The
labour,
on the contrary, of artificers, manufacturers, and
merchants,
naturally does fix and realize itself in some such
vendible
commodity. It is upon this account that, in the chapter
in
which I treat of productive and unproductive labour, I have
classed
artificers, manufacturers, and merchants among the
productive
labourers, and menial servants among the barren or
unproductive.
Thirdly, it seems, upon every supposition,
improper to say,
that
the labour of artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, does
not
increase the real revenue of the society. Though we should
suppose,
for example, as it seems to be supposed in this system,
that
the value of the daily, monthly, and yearly consumption of
this
class was exactly equal to that of its daily, monthly, and
yearly
production; yet it would not from thence follow, that its
labour
added nothing to the real revenue, to the real value of
the
annual produce of the land and labour of the society. An
artificer,
for example, who, in the first six months after
harvest,
executes ten pounds worth of work, though he should, in
the
same time, consume ten pounds worth of corn and other
necessaries,
yet really adds the value of ten pounds to the
annual
produce of the land and labour of the society. While he
has
been consuming a half-yearly revenue of ten pounds worth of
corn
and other necessaries, he has produced an equal value of
work,
capable of purchasing, either to himself, or to some other
person,
an equal half-yearly revenue. The value, therefore, of
what
has been consumed and produced during these six months, is
equal,
not to ten, but to twenty pounds. It is possible, indeed,
that no
more than ten pounds worth of this value may ever have
existed
at any one moment of time. But if the ten pounds worth of
corn
and other necessaries which were consumed by the artificer,
had
been consumed by a soldier, or by a menial servant, the value
of that
part of the annual produce which existed at the end of
the six
months, would have been ten pounds less than it actually
is in
consequence of the labour of the artificer. Though the
value
of what the artificer produces, therefore, should not, at
any one
moment of time, be supposed greater than the value he
consumes,
yet, at every moment of time, the actually existing
value
of goods in the market is, in consequence of what he
produces,
greater than it otherwise would be.
When
the patrons of this system assert, that the consumption of
artificers,
manufacturer's, and merchants, is equal to the value
of what
they produce, they probably mean no more than that their
revenue,
or the fund destined for their consumption, is equal to
it. But
if they had expressed themselves more accurately, and
only
asserted, that the revenue of this class was equal to the
value
of what they produced, it might readily have occurred to
the
reader, that what would naturally be saved out of this
revenue,
must necessarily increase more or less the real wealth
of the
society. In order, therefore, to make out something like
an
argument, it was necessary that they should express themselves
as they
have done ; and this argument, even supposing things
actually
were as it seems to presume them to be, turns out to be
a very
inconclusive one.
Fourthly, farmers and country labourers can no more
augment,
without
parsimony, the real revenue, the annual produce of the
land
and labour of their society, than artificers, manufacturers,
and
merchants. The annual produce of the land and labour of any
society
can be augmented only in two ways ; either, first, by
some
improvement in the productive powers of the useful labour
actually
maintained within it; or, secondly, by some increase in
the
quantity of that labour.
The
improvement in the productive powers of useful labour
depends,
first, upon the improvement in the ability of the
workman;
and, secondly, upon that of the machinery with which be
works.
But the labour of artificers and manufacturers, as it is
capable
of being more subdivided, and the labour of each workman
reduced
to a greater simplicity of operation, than that of
farmers
and country labourers; so it is likewise capable of both
these
sorts of improvement in a much higher degree {See book i
chap.
1.} In this respect, therefore, the class of cultivators
can
have no sort of advantage over that of artificers and
manufacturers.
The
increase in the quantity of useful labour actually employed
within
any society must depend altogether upon the increase of
the
capital which employs it ; and the increase of that capital,
again,
must be exactly equal to the anount of the savings from
the
revenue, either of the particular persons who manage and
direct
the employment of that capital, or of some other persons,
who
lend it to them. If merchants, artificers, and manufacturers
are, as
this system seems to suppose, naturally more inclined to
parsimony
and saving than proprietors and cultivators, they are,
so far,
more likely to augment the quantity of useful labour
employed
within their society, and consequently to increase its
real
revenue, the annual produce of its land and labour.
Fifthly
and lastly, though the revenue of the inhabitants of
every
country was supposed to consist altogether, as this system
seems
to suppose, in the quantity of subsistence which their
industry
could procure to them; yet, even upon this supposition,
the
revenue of a trading and manufacturing country must, other
things
being equal, always be much greater than that of one
without
trade or manufactures. By means of trade and
manufactures,
a greater quantity of subsistence can be annually
imported
into a particular country, than what its own lands, in
the
actual state of their cultivation, could afford. The
inhabitants
of a town, though they frequently possess no lands of
their
own, yet draw to themselves, by their industry, such a
quantity
of the rude produce of the lands of other people, as
supplies
them, not only with the materials of their work, but
with
the fund of their subsistence. What a town always is with
regard
to the country in its neighbourhood, one independent state
or
country may frequently be with regard to other independent
states
or countries. It is thus that Holland draws a great part
of its
subsistence from other countries; live cattle from
Holstein
and Jutland, and corn from almost all the different
countries
of Europe. A small quantity of manufactured produce,
purchases
a great quantity of rude produce. A trading and
manufacturing
country, therefore, naturally purchases, with a
small
part of its manufactured produce, a great part of the rude
produce
of other countries; while, on the contrary, a country
without
trade and manufactures is generally obliged to purchase,
at the
expense of a great part of its rude produce, a very small
part of
the manufactured produce of other countries. The one
exports
what can subsist and accommodate but a very few, and
imports
the subsistence and accommodation of a great number. The
other
exports the accommodation and subsistence of a great
number,
and imports that of a very few only. The inhabitants of
the one
must always enjoy a much greater quantity of subsistence
than
what their own lands, in the actual state of their
cultivation,
could afford. The inhabitants of the other must
always
enjoy a much smaller quantity.
This
system, however, with all its imperfections, is perhaps the
nearest
approximation to the truth that has yet been published
upon
the subject of political economy ; and is upon that account,
well
worth the consideration of every man who wishes to examine
with
attention the principles of that very important science.
Though
in representing the labour which is employed upon land as
the
only productive labour, the notions which it inculcates are,
perhaps,
too narrow and confined ; yet in representing the wealth
of
nations as consisting, not in the unconsumable riches of
money,
but in the consumable goods annually reproduced by the
labour
of the society, and in representing perfect liberty as the
only
effectual expedient for rendering this annual reproduction
the
greatest possible, its doctrine seems to be in every respect
as just
as it is generous and liberal. Its followers are very
numerous
; and as men are fond of paradoxes, and of appearing to
understand
what surpasses the comprehensions of ordinary people,
the
paradox which it maintains, concerning the unproductive
nature
of manufacturing labour, has not, perhaps, contributed a
little
to increase the number of its admirers. They have for some
years
past made a pretty considerable sect, distinguished in the
French
republic of letters by the name of the Economists. Their
works
have certainly been of some service to their country; not
only by
bringing into general discussion, many subjects which had
never
been well examined before, but by influencing, in some
measure,
the public administration in favour of agriculture. It
has
been in consequence of their representations, accordingly,
that
the agriculture of France has been delivered from several of
the
oppressions which it before laboured under. The term, during
which
such a lease can be granted, as will be valid against every
future
purchaser or proprietor of the land, has been prolonged
from
nine to twenty-seven years. The ancient provincial
restraints
upon the transportation of corn from one province of
the
kingdom to another, have been entirely taken away; and the
liberty
of exporting it to all foreign countries, has been
established
as the common law of the kingdom in all ordinary
cases.
This sect, in their works, which are very numerous, and
which
treat not only of what is properly called Political
Economy,
or of the nature and causes or the wealth of nations,
but of
every other branch of the system of civil government, all
follow
implicitly, and without any sensible variation, the
doctrine
of Mr. Qttesnai. There is, upon this account, little
variety
in the greater part of their works. The most distinct and
best
connected account of this doctrine is to be found in a
little
book written by Mr. Mercier de la Riviere, some time
intendant
of Martinico, entitled, The natural and essential Order
of
Political Societies. The admiration of this whole sect for
their
master, who was himself a man of the greatest modesty and
simplicity,
is not inferior to that of any of the ancient
philosophers
for the founders of their respective systems. 'There
have
been since the world began,' says a very diligent and
respectable
author, the Marquis de Mirabeau, 'three great
inventions
which have principally given stability to political
societies,
independent of many other inventions which have
enriched
and adorned them. The first is the invention of writing,
which
alone gives human nature the power of transmitting, without
alteration,
its laws, its contracts, its annals, and its
discoveries.
The second is the invention of money, which binds
together
all the relations between civilized societies. The third
is the
economical table, the result of the other two, which
completes
them both by perfecting their object ; the great
discovery
of our age, but of which our posterity will reap the
benefit.'
As the
political economy of the nations of modern Europe has been
more
favourable to manufactures and foreign trade, the industry
of the
towns, than to agriculture, the industry of the country;
so that
of other nations has followed a different plan, and has
been
more favourable to agriculture than to manufactures and
foreign
trade.
The
policy of China favours agriculture more than all other
employments.
In China, the condition of a labourer is said to be
as much
superior to that of an artificer, as in most parts of
Europe
that of an artificer is to that of a labourer. In China,
the
great ambition of every man is to get possession of a little
bit of
land, either in property or in lease ; and leases are
there
said to be granted upon very moderate terms, and to be
sufficiently
secured to the lessees. The Chinese have little
respect
for foreign trade. Your beggarly commerce ! was the
language
in which the mandarins of Pekin used to talk to Mr. De
Lange,
the Russian envoy, concerning it {See the Journal of Mr.
De
Lange, in Bell's Travels, vol. ii. p. 258, 276, 293.}. Except
with
Japan, the Chinese carry on, themselves, and in their own
bottoms,
little or no foreign trade ; and it is only into one or
two
ports of their kingdom that they even admit the ships of
foreign
nations. Foreign trade, therefore, is, in China, every
way
confined within a much narrower circle than that to which it
would
naturally extend itself, if more freedom was allowed to it,
either
in their own ships, or in those of foreign nations.
Manufactures,
as in a small bulk they frequently contain a great
value,
and can upon that account be transported at less expense
from
one country to another than most parts of rude produce, are,
in
almost all countries, the principal support of foreign trade.
In
countries, besides, less extensive, and less favourably
circumstanced
for inferior commerce than China, they generally
require
the support of foreign trade.
Without an extensive
foreign
market, they could not well flourish, either in countries
so
moderately extensive as to afford but a narrow home market, or
in
countries where the communication between one province and
another
was so difficult, as to render it impossible for the
goods
of any particular place to enjoy the whole of that home
market
which the country could afford. The perfection of
manufacturing
industry, it must be remembered, depends altogether
upon
the division of labour ; and the degree to which the
division
of labour can be introduced into any manufacture, is
necessarily
regulated, it has already been shewn, by the extent
of the
market. But the great extent of the empire of China, the
vast
multitude of its inhabitants, the variety of climate, and
consequently
of productions in its different provinces, and the
easy
communication by means of water-carriage between the greater
part of
them, render the home market of that country of so great
extent,
as to be alone sufficient to support very great
manufactures,
and to admit of very considerable subdivisions of
labour.
The home market of China is, perhaps, in extent, not much
inferior
to the market of all the different countries of Europe
put
together. A more extensive foreign trade, however, which to
this
great home market added the foreign market of all the rest
of the
world, especially if any considerable part of this trade
was
carried on in Chinese ships, could scarce fail to increase
very
much the manufactures of China, and to improve very much the
productive
powers of its manufacturing industry. By a more
extensive
navigation, the Chinese would naturally learn the art
of
using and constructing, themselves, all the different machines
made
use of in other countries, as well as the other improvements
of art
and industry which are practised in all the different
parts
of the world. Upon their present plan, they have little
opportunity
of improving themselves by the example of any other
nation,
except that of the Japanese.
The
policy of ancient Egypt, too, and that of the Gentoo
government
of Indostan, seem to have favoured agriculture more
than
all other employments.
Both in
ancient Egypt and Indostan, the whole body of the people
was
divided into different casts or tribes each of which was
confined,
from father to son, to a particular employment, or
class
of employments. The son of a priest was necessarily a
priest;
the son of a soldier, a soldier; the son of a labourer, a
labourer
; the son of a weaver, a weaver ; the son of a tailor, a
tailor,
etc. In both countries, the cast of the priests holds the
highest
rank, and that of the soldiers the next; and in both
countries
the cast of the farmers and labourers was superior to
the
casts of merchants and manufacturers.
The
government of both countries was particularly attentive to
the
interest of agriculture. The works constructed by the ancient
sovereigns
of Egypt, for the proper distribution of the waters of
the
Nile, were famous in antiquity, and the ruined remains of
some of
them are still the admiration of travellers. Those of the
same
kind which were constructed by the ancient sovereigns of
Indostan,
for the proper distribution of the waters of the
Ganges,
as well as of many other rivers, though they have been
less
celebrated, seem to have been equally great. Both countries,
accordingly,
though subject occasionally to dearths, have been
famous
for their great fertility. Though both were extremely
populous,
yet, in years of moderate plenty, they were both able
to
export great quantities of grain to their neighbours.
The
ancient Egyptians had a superstitious aversion to the sea;
and as
the Gentoo religion does not permit its followers to light
a fire,
nor consequently to dress any victuals, upon the water,
it, in
effect, prohibits them from all distant sea voyages.
Both
the Egyptians and Indians must have depended almost
altogether
upon the navigation of other nations for the
exportation
of their surplus produce; and this dependency, as it
must
have confined the market, so it must have discouraged the
increase
of this surplus produce. It must have discouraged, too,
the
increase of the manufactured produce, more than that of the
rude
produce. Manufactures require a much more extensive market
than
the most important parts of the rude produce of the land. A
single
shoemaker will make more than 300 pairs of shoes in the
year;
and his own family will not, perhaps, wear out six pairs.
Unless,
therefore, he has the custom of, at least, 50 such
families
as his own, he cannot dispose of the whole product of
his own
labour. The most numerous class of artificers will
seldom,
in a large country, make more than one in 50, or one in a
100, of
the whole number of families contained in it. But in such
large
countries, as France and England, the number of people
employed
in agriculture has, by some authors been computed at a
half,
by others at a third and by no author that I know of, at
less
that a fifth of the whole inhabitants of the country. But as
the
produce of the agriculture of both France and England is, the
far
greater part of it, consumed at home, each person employed in
it
must, according to these computations, require little more
than
the custom of one, two, or, at most, of
four such families
as his
own, in order to dispose of the whole produce of his own
labour.
Agriculture, therefore, can support itself under the
discouragement
of a confined market much better than
manufactures.
In both ancient Egypt and Indostan, indeed, the
confinement
of the foreign market was in some measure compensated
by the
conveniency of many inland navigations, which opened, in
the
most advantageous manner, the whole extent of the home market
to
every part of the produce of every different district of those
countries.
The great extent of Indostan, too, rendered the home
market
of that country very great, and sufficient to support a
great
variety of manufactures. But the small extent of ancient
Egypt,
which was never equal to England, must at all times, have
rendered
the home market of that country too narrow for
supporting
any great variety of manufactures. Bengal accordingly,
the
province of Indostan which commonly exports the greatest
quantity
of rice, has always been more remarkable for the
exportation
of a great variety of manufactures, than for that of
its
grain. Ancient Egypt, on the contrary, though it exported
some
manufactures, fine linen in particular, as well as some
other
goods, was always most distinguished for its great
exportation
of grain. It was long the granary of the Roman
empire.
The
sovereigns of China, of ancient Egypt, and of the different
kindoms
into which Indostan has, at different times, been
divided,
have always derived the whole, or by far the most
considerable
part, of their revenue, from some sort of land tax
or land
rent. This land tax, or land rent, like the tithe in
Europe,
consisted in a certain proportion, a fifth, it is said,
of the
produce of the land, which was either delivered in kind,
or paid
in money, according to a certain valuation, and which,
therefore,
varied from year to year, according to all the
variations
of the produce. It was natural, therefore, that the
sovereigns
of those countries should be particularly attentive to
the
interests of agriculture, upon the prosperity or declension
of
which immediately depended the yearly increase or diminution
of
their own revenue.
The
policy of the ancient republics of Greece, and that of Rome,
though
it honoured agriculture more than manufactures or foreign
trade,
yet seems rather to have discouraged the latter
employments,
than to have given any direct or intentional
encouragement
to the former. In several of the ancient states of
Greece,
foreign trade was prohibited altogether; and in several
others,
the employments of artificers and manufacturers were
considered
as hurtful to the strength and agility of the human
body,
as rendering it incapable of those habits which their
military
and gymnastic exercises endeavoured to form in it, and
as
thereby disqualifying it, more or less, for undergoing the
fatigues
and encountering the dangers of war. Such occupations
were
considered as fit only for slaves, and the free citizens of
the
states were prohibited from exercising them. Even in those
states
where no such prohibition took place, as in Rome and
Athens,
the great body of the people were in effect excluded from
all the
trades which are now commonly exercised by the lower sort
of the
inhabitants of towns. Such trades
were, at Athens and
Rome,
all occupied by the slaves of the rich, who exercised them
for the
benefit of their masters, whose wealth, power, and
protection,
made it almost impossible for a poor freeman to find
a
market for his work, when it came into competition with that of
the
slaves of the rich. Slaves, however, are very seldom
inventive
; and all the most important improvements, either in
machinery,
or in the arrangement and distribution of work, which
facilitate
and abridge labour have been the discoveries of
freemen.
Should a slave propose any improvement of this kind, his
master
would be very apt to consider the proposal as the
suggestion
of laziness, and of a desire to save his own labour at
the
master's expense. The poor slave, instead of reward would
probably
meet with much abuse, perhaps with some punishment. In
the
manufactures carried on by slaves, therefore, more labour
must
generally have been employed to execute the same quantity of
work,
than in those carried on by freemen. The work of the farmer
must,
upon that account, generally have been dearer than that of
the
latter. The Hungarian mines, it is remarked by Mr.
Montesquieu,
though not richer, have always been wrought with
less
expense, and therefore with more profit, than the Turkish
mines
in their neighbourhood. The Turkish mines are wrought by
slaves;
and the arms of those slaves are the only machines which
the
Turks have ever thought of employing. The Hungarian mines are
wrought
by freemen, who employ a great deal of machinery, by
which
they facilitate and abridge their own labour. From the very
little
that is known about the price of manufactures in the times
of the
Greeks and Romans, it would appear that those of the finer
sort
were excessively dear. Silk sold for its weight in gold. It
was
not, indeed, in those times an European manufacture ; and as
it was
all brought from the East Indies, the distance of the
carriage
may in some measure account for the greatness of the
price.
The price, however, which a lady, it is said, would
sometimes
pay for a piece of very fine linen, seems to have been
equally
extravagant ; and as linen was always either an European,
or at
farthest, an Egyptian manufacture, this high price can be
accounted
for only by the great expense of the labour which must
have
been employed about It, and the expense of this labour again
could
arise from nothing but the awkwardness of the machinery
which
is made use of. The price of fine woollens, too, though not
quite
so extravagant, seems, however, to have been much above
that of
the present times. Some cloths, we are told by Pliny
{Plin.
1. ix.c.39.}, dyed in a particular manner, cost a hundred
denarii,
or £3:6s:8d. the pound weight. Others, dyed in another
manner,
cost a thousand denarii the pound weight, or £33:6s:8d.
The Roman
pound. it must be remembered, contained only twelve of
our
avoirdupois ounces. This high price, indeed, seems to have
been
principally owing to the dye. But had not the cloths
themselves
been much dearer than any which are made in the
present
times, so very expensive a dye would not probably have
been
bestowed upon them. The disproportion would have been too
great
between the value of the accessory and that of the
principal.
The price mentioned by the same author
{Plin. 1.
viii.c.48.},
of some triclinaria, a sort of woollen pillows or
cushions
made use of to lean upon as they reclined upon their
couches
at table, passes all credibility; some of them being said
to have
cost more than £30,000, others more than £300,000. This
high
price, too, is not said to have arisen from the dye. In the
dress
of the people of fashion of both sexes, there seems to have
been
much less variety, it is observed by Dr. Arbuthnot, in
ancient
than in modern times; and the very little variety which
we find
in that of the ancient statues, confirms his observation.
He
infers from this, that their dress must, upon the whole, have
been
cheaper than ours; but the conclusion does not seem to
follow.
When the expense of fashionable dress is very great, the
variety
must be very small. But when, by the improvements in the
productive
powers of manufacturing art and industry, the expense
of any
one dress comes to be very moderate, the variety will
naturally
be very great. The rich, not being able to distinguish
themselves
by the expense of any one dress, will naturally
endeavour
to do so by the multitude and variety of their dresses.
The
greatest and most important branch of the commerce of every
nation,
it has already been observed, is that which is carried on
between
the inhabitants of the town and those of the country. The
inhabitants
of the town draw from the country the rude produce,
which
constitutes both the materials of their work and the fund
of
their subsistence ; and they pay for this rude produce, by
sending
back to the country a certain portion of it manufactured
and
prepared for immediate use. The trade which is carried on
between
these two different sets of people, consists ultimately
in a
certain quantity of rude produce exchanged for a certain
quantity
of manufactured produce. The dearer the latter,
therefore,
the cheaper the former; and whatever tends in any
country
to raise the price of manufactured produce, tends to
lower
that of the rude produce of the land, and thereby to
discourage
agriculture. The smaller the
quantity of
manufactured
produce, which any given quantity of rude produce,
or,
what comes to the same thing, which the price of any given
quantity
of rude produce, is capable of purchasing, the smaller
the
exchangeable value of that given quantity of rude produce;
the
smaller the encouragement which either the landlord has to
increase
its quantity by improving, or the farmer by cultivating
the
land. Whatever, besides, tends to diminish in any country the
number
of artificers and manufacturers, tends to diminish the
home
market, the most important of all markets, for the rude
produce
of the land, and thereby still further to discourage
agriculture.
Those
systems, therefore, which preferring agriculture to all
other
employments, in order to promote it, impose restraints upon
manufactures
and foreign trade, act contrary to the very end
which
they propose, and indirectly discourage that very species
of
industry which they mean to promote. They are so far, perhaps,
more
inconsistent than even the mercantile system. That system,
by
encouraging manufactures and foreign trade more than
agriculture,
turns a certain portion of the capital of the
society,
from supporting a more advantageous, to support a less
advantageous
species of industry. But still it really, and in the
end,
encourages that species of industry which it means to
promote.
Those agricultural systems, on the contrary, really, and
in the
end, discourage their own favourite species of industry.
It is
thus that every system which endeavours, either, by
extraordinary
encouragements to draw towards a particular species
of
industry a greater share of the capital of the society than
what
would naturally go to it, or, by extraordinary restraints,
to
force from a particular species of industry some share of the
capital
which would otherwise be employed in it, is, in reality,
subversive
of the great purpose which it means to promote. It
retards,
instead of accelerating the progress of the society
towards
real wealth and greatness ; and diminishes, instead of
increasing,
the real value of the annual produce of its land and
labour.
All
systems, either of preference or of restraint, therefore,
being
thus completely taken away, the obvious and simple system
of
natural liberty establishes itself of its own accord. Every
man, as
long as he does not violate the laws of justice, is left
perfectly
free to pursue his own interest his own way, and to
bring
both his industry and capital into competition with those
of any
other man, or order of men. The sovereign is completely
discharged
from a duty, in the attempting to perform which he
must
always be exposed to innumerable delusions, and for the
proper
performance of which, no human wisdom or knowledge could
ever be
sufficient ; the duty of superintending the industry of
private
people, and of directing it towards the employments most
suitable
to the interests of the society. According to the system
of
natural liberty, the sovereign has only three duties to attend
to;
three duties of great importance, indeed, but plain and
intelligible
to common understandings: first, the duty of
protecting
the society from the violence and invasion of other
independent
societies ; secondly, the duty of protecting, as far
as
possible, every member of the society from the injustice or
oppression
of every other member of it, or the duty of
establishing
an exact administration of justice ; and, thirdly,
the
duty of erecting and maintaining certain public works, and
certain
public institutions, which it can never be for the
interest
of any individual, or small number of individuals to
erect
and maintain ; because the profit could never repay the
expense
to any individual, or small number of individuals, though
it may
frequently do much more than repay it to a great society.
The
proper performance of those several duties of the sovereign
necessarily
supposes a certain expense ; and this expense again
necessarily
requires a certain revenue to support it. In the
following
book, therefore, I shall endeavour to explain, first,
what
are the necessary expenses of the sovereign or commonwealth;
and
which of those expenses ought to be defrayed by the general
contribution
of the whole society ; and which of them, by that of
some
particular part ouly, or of some particular members of the
society:
secondly, what are the different methods in which the
whole
society may be made to contribute towards defraying the
expenses
incumbent on the whole society ; and what are the
principal
advantages and inconveniencies of each of those methods
: and
thirdly, what are the reasons and causes which have induced
almost
all modern governments to mortgage some part of this
revenue,
or to contract debts; and what have been the effects of
those
debts upon the real wealth, the annual produce of the land
and
labour of the society. The following book, therefore, will
naturally
be divided into three chapters.
APPENDIX TO
BOOK IV
The two
following accounts are subjoined, in order to illustrate
and
confirm what is said in the fifth chapter of the fourth book,
concerning
the Tonnage Bounty to the Whit-herring Fishery. The
reader,
I believe, may depend upon the accuracy of both accounts.
An
account of Busses fitted out in Scotland for eleven Years, with
the
Number of empty Barrels carried out, and the Number of Barrels
of
Herrings caught; also the Bounty, at a Medium, on each Barrel of
Sea-sricks,
and on each Barrel when fully packed.
Years Number of
Empty Barrels Barrels of
Her- Bounty paid on
Busses carried out rings
caught the Busses
£. s.
d.
1771 29 5,948
2,832 2,885 0
0
1772 168 41,316
22,237 11,055 7
6
1773 190 42,333
42,055 12,510 8
6
1774 240 59,303
56,365 26,932 2
6
1775 275 69,144
52,879 19,315 15
0
1776 294 76,329
51,863 21,290 7
6
1777 240 62,679
43,313 17,592 2
6
1778 220 56,390
40,958 16,316 2
6
1779 Â 206 55,194
29,367 15,287
0 0
1780 181 48,315
19,885 13,445 12
6
1781 135 33,992
16,593 9,613 15
6
Totals 2,186 550,943
378,347 £165,463 14
0
Sea-sticks 378,347
Bounty, at a medium, for each
barrel of
sea-sticks, £ 0 8
2¼
But a barrel of
sea-sticks
being only reckoned
two thirds
of a barrel fully
packed, one
third to be deducted, which
¹/³deducted 126,115
brings the bounty to £
0 12
3¾
Barrels
fully
packed 252,231
And if
the herings are exported, there is besides a
premium
of £ 0 2 8
So the
bounty paid by government in money for each
barrel is £ 0 14
11¾
But if
to this, the duty of the salt usually taken
credit
for as expended in curing each barrel, which
at a medium,
is, of foreign, one bushel and one-
fourth
of a bushel, at 10s. a-bushel, be added, viz 0 12 6
the
bounty on each barrel would amount to £ 1 7 5¾
If the
herrings are cured with British salt, it will
stand
thus, viz.
Bounty
as before
£ 0 14 11¾
But if
to this bounty, the duty on two bushels of
Scotch
salt, at 1s.6d. per bushel, supposed to be
the
quantity, at a medium, used in curing each
barrel
is added, viz. 0 3 0
The
bounty on each barrel will amount to £ 0 17 11¾
And
when buss herrings are enterd for home
consumption
in Scotland, and pay the shilling a
barrel
of duty, the bounty stands thus, to wit,
as before
£ 0 12 3¾
From
which the shilling a barrel is to be deducted 0 1 0
£ 0 11 3¾
But to
that there is to be added again, the duty of
the
foreign salt used curing a barrel of herring viz 0 12 6
So that
the premium allowed for each barrel of her-
rings
entered for home consumption is
£ 1 3 9¾
If the
herrings are cured in British salt, it will
stand
as follows viz.
Bounty
on each barrel brought in by the busses, as
above
£ 0 12 3¾
From
which deduct 1s. a-barrel, paid at the time
they
are entered for home consumption 0
1 0
£ 0 11
3¾
But if
to the bounty, the the duty on two bushel
of
Scotch salt, at 1s.6d. per bushel supposed to
be the
quantity, at a medium, used in curing each
barrel,
is added, viz
0 3 0
the
premium for each barrel entered for home
consumption
will be
£ 1 14 3¾
Though
the loss of duties upon herrings exported cannot, perhaps,
properly
be considerd as bounty, that upon herrings entered for
home
consumption certainly may.
An
account of the Quantity of Foreign Salt imported into Scotland,
and of
Scotch Salt delivered Duty-free from the Works there, for
the
Fishery, from the 5th. of April 1771 to the 5th. of April 1782
with
the Medium of both for one Year.
Foreign
Salt Scotch Salt delivered
PERIOD imported
from the Works
Bushels Bushels
From 5th. April 1771 to
5th. April 1782 936,974 168,226
Medium for one year 85,159½ 15,293¼
It is
to be observed, that the bushel of foreign salt weighs 48lbs.,
that of
British weighs 56lbs. only.
BOOK V. OF THE REVENUE OF THE SOVEREIGN OR
COMMONWEALTH
CHAPTER I.
OF THE
EXPENSES OF THE SOVEREIGN OR COMMONWEALTH.
PART I. Of the Expense of Defence.
The
first duty of the sovereign, that of protecting the society
from
the violence and invasion of other independent societies,
can be
performed only by means of a military force. But the
expense
both of preparing this military force in time of peace,
and of
employing it in time of war, is very different in the
different
states of society, in the different periods of
improvement.
Among
nations of hunters, the lowest and rudest state of society,
such as
we find it among the native tribes of North America,
every
man is a warrior, as well as a hunter. When he goes to war,
either
to defend his society, or to revenge the injuries which
have
been done to it by other societies, he maintains himself by
his own
labour, in the same manner as when he lives at home. His
society
(for in this state of things there is properly neither
sovereign
nor commonwealth) is at no sort of expense, either to
prepare
him for the field, or to maintain him while he is in it.
Among
nations of shepherds, a more advanced state of society,
such as
we find it among the Tartars and Arabs, every man is, in
the
same manner, a warrior. Such nations have commonly no fixed
habitation,
but live either in tents, or in a sort of covered
waggons,
which are easily transported from place to place. The
whole
tribe, or nation, changes its situation according to the
different
seasons of the year, as well as according to other
accidents.
When its herds and flocks have consumed the forage of
one
part of the country, it removes to another, and from that to
a
third. In the dry season, it comes down to the banks of the
rivers;
in the wet season, it retires to the upper country. When
such a
nation goes to war, the warriors will not trust their
herds
and flocks to the feeble defence of their old men, their
women
and children; and their old men, their women and children,
will
not be left behind without defence, and without subsistence.
The
whole nation, besides, being accustomed to a wandering life,
even in
time of peace, easily takes the field in time of war.
Whether
it marches as an army, or moves about as a company of
herdsmen,
the way of life is nearly the same, though the object
proposed
by it be very different. They all go to war together,
therefore,
and everyone does as well as he can. Among the
Tartars,
even the women have been frequently known to engage in
battle.
If they conquer, whatever belongs to the hostile tribe is
the
recompence of the victory ; but if they are vanquished, all
is
lost; and not only their herds and flocks, but their women and
children.
become the booty of the conqueror. Even the greater
part of
those who survive the action are obliged to submit to him
for the
sake of immediate subsistence. The rest are commonly
dissipated
and dispersed in the desert.
The
ordinary life, the ordinary exercise of a Tartar or Arab,
prepare
him sufficiently for war. Running, wrestling,
cudgel-playing,
throwing the javelin, drawing the bow, etc. are
the
common pastimes of those who live in the open air, and are
all of
them the images of war. When a Tartar or Arab actually
goes to
war, he is maintained by his own herds and flocks, which
he
carries with him, in the same manner as in peace. His chief or
sovereign
(for those nations have all chiefs or sovereigns) is at
no sort
of expense in preparing him for the field ; and when he
is in
it, the chance of plunder is the only pay which he either
expects
or requires.
An army
of hunters can seldom exceed two or three hundred men.
The
precarious subsistence which the chace affords, could seldom
allow a
greater number to keep together for any considerable
time.
An army of shepherds, on the contrary, may sometimes amount
to two
or three hundred thousand. As long as nothing stops their
progress,
as long as they can go on from one district, of which
they
have consumed the forage, to another, which is yet entire;
there
seems to be scarce any limit to the number who can march on
together.
A nation of hunters can never be formidable to the
civilized
nations in their neighbourhood; a nation of shepherds
may.
Nothing can be more contemptible than an Indian war in North
America;
nothing, on the contrary, can be more dreadful than a
Tartar
invasion has frequently been in Asia. The judgment of
Thucydides,
that both Europe and Asia could not resist the
Scythians
united, has been verified by the experience of all
ages.
The inhabitants of the extensive, but defenceles plains of
Scythia
or Tartary, have been frequently united under the
dominion
of the chief of some conquering horde or clan; and the
havock
and devastation of Asia have always signalized their
union.
The inhabitants of the inhospitable deserts of Arabia, the
other
great nation of shepherds, have never been united but once,
under
Mahomet and his immediate successors. Their union, which
was
more the effect of religious enthusiasm than of conquest, was
signalized
in the same manner. If the hunting nations of America
should
ever become shepherds, their neighbourhood would be much
more
dangerous to the European colonies than it is at present.
In a
yet more advanced state of society, among those nations of
husbandmen
who have little foreign commerce, and no other
manufactures
but those coarse and household ones, which almost
every
private family prepares for its own use, every man, in the
same
manner, either is a warrior, or easily becomes such. Those
who
live by agricuiture generally pass the whole day in the open
air,
exposed to all the inclemencies of the seasons. The
hardiness
of their ordinary life prepares them for the fatigues
of war,
to some of which their necessary occupations bear a great
analogy. The necessary occupation of a ditcher
prepares him to
work in
the trenches, and to fortify a camp, as well as to
inclose
a field. The ordinary pastimes of such husbandmen are the
same as
those of shepherds, and are in the same manner the images
of war.
But as husbandmen have less leisure than shepherds, they
are not
so frequently employed in those pastimes. They are
soldiers
but soldiers not quite so much masters of their
exercise.
Such as they are, however, it seldom costs the
sovereign
or commonwealth any expense to prepare them for the
field.
Agriculture,
even in its rudest and lowest state, supposes a
settlement,
some sort of fixed habitation, which cannot be
abandoned
without great loss. When a nation of mere husbandmen,
therefore,
goes to war, the whole people cannot take the field
together.
The old men, the women and children, at least, must
remain
at home, to take care of the habitation. All the men of
the
military age, however, may take the field, and in small
nations
of this kind, have frequently done so. In every nation,
the men
of the military age are supposed to amount to about a
fourth
or a fifth part of the whole body of the people. If the
campaign,
too, should begin after seedtime, and end before
harvest,
both the husbandman and his principal labourers can be
spared
from the farm without much loss. He trusts that the work
which
must be done in the mean time, can be well enough executed
by the
old men, the women, and the children. He is not unwilling,
therefore,
to serve without pay during a short campaign ; and it
frequently
costs the sovereign or commonwealth as little to
maintain
him in the field as to prepare him for it. The citizens
of all
the different states of ancient Greece seem to have served
in this
manner till after the second Persian war; and the people
of
Peloponnesus till after the Peloponnesian war. The
Peloponnesians,
Thucydides observes, generally left the field in
the
summer, and returned home to reap the harvest. The Roman
people,
under their kings, and during the first ages of the
republic,
served in the same manner. It was not till the seige of
Veii,
that they who staid at home began to contribute something
towards
maintaining those who went to war. In the European
monarchies,
which were founded upon the ruins of the Roman
empire,
both before, and for some time after, the establishment
of what
is properly called the feudal law, the great lords, with
all
their immediate dependents, used to serve the crown at their
own
expense. In the field, in the same manner as at home, they
maintained
themselves by their own revenue, and not by any
stipend
or pay which they received from the king upon that
particular
occasion.
In a
more advanced state of society, two different causes
contribute
to render it altogether impossible that they who take
the
field should maintain themselves at their own expense. Those
two
causes are, the progress of manufactures, and the improvement
in the
art of war.
Though
a husbandman should be employed in an expedition, provided
it
begins after seedtime, and ends before harvest, the
interruption
of his business will not always occasion any
considerable
diminution of his revenue. Without the intervention
of his
labour, Nature does herself the greater part of the work
which
remains to be done. But the moment that an artificer, a
smith,
a carpenter, or a weaver, for example, quits his
workhouse,
the sole source of his revenue is completely dried up.
Nature
does nothing for him ; he does all for himself. When he
takes
the field, therefore, in defence of the public, as he has
no
revenue to maintain himself, he must necessarily be maintained
by the
public. But in a country, of which a great part of the
inhabitants
are artificers and manufacturers, a great part of the
people
who go to war must be drawn from those classes, and must,
therefore,
be maintained by the public as long as they are
employed
in its service,
When
the art of war, too, has gradually grown up to be a very
intricate
and complicated science; when the event of war ceases
to be
determined, as in the first ages of society, by a single
irregular
skirmish or battle ; but when the contest is generally
spun
out through several different campaigns, each of which lasts
during
the greater part of the year; it becomes universally
necessary
that the public should maintain those who serve the
public
in war, at least while they are employed in that service.
Whatever,
in time of peace, might be the ordinary occupation of
those
who go to war, so very tedious and expensive a service
would
otherwise be by far too heavy a burden upon them. After the
second
Persian war, accordingly, the armies of Athens seem to
have
been generally composed of mercenary troops, consisting,
indeed,
partly of citizens, but partly, too, of foreigners; and
all of
them equally hired and paid at the expense of the state.
From
the time of the siege of Veii, the armies of Rome received
pay for
their service during the time which they remained in the
field.
Under the feudal governments, the military service, both
of the
great lords, and of their immediate dependents, was, after
a
certain period, universally exchanged for a payment in money,
which
was employed to maintain those who served in their stead.
The
number of those who can go to war, in proportion to the whole
number
of the people, is necessarily much smaller in a civilized
than in
a rude state of society. In a civilized society, as the
soldiers
are maintained altogether by the labour of those who are
not
soldiers, the number of the former can never exceed what the
latter
can maintain, over and above maintaining, in a manner
suitable
to their respective stations, both themselves and the
other
officers of government and law, whom they are obliged to
maintain.
In the little agrarian states of ancient Greece, a
fourth
or a fifth part of the whole body of the people considered
the
themselves as soldiers, and would sometimes, it is said, take
the
field. Among the civilized nations of modern Europe, it is
commonly
computed, that not more than the one hundredth part of
the
inhabitants of any country can be employed as soldiers,
without
ruin to the country which pays the expense of their
service.
The
expense of preparing the army for the field seems not to have
become
considerable in any nation, till long after that of
maintaining
it in the field had devolved entirely upon the
sovereign
or commonwealth. In all the different republics of
ancient
Greece, to learn his military exercises, was a necessary
part of
education imposed by the state upon every free citizen.
In
every city there seems to have been a public field, in which,
under
the protection of the public magistrate, the young people
were
taught their different exercises by different masters. In
this
very simple institution consisted the whole expense which
any
Grecian state seems ever to have been at, in preparing its
citizens
for war. In ancient Rome, the exercises of the Campus
Martius
answered the same purpose with those of the Gymnasium in
ancient
Greece. Under the feudal governments, the many public
ordinances,
that the citizens of every district should practise
archery,
as well as several other military exercises, were
intended
for promoting the same purpose, but do not seem to have
promoted
it so well. Either from want of interest in the officers
entrusted
with the execution of those ordinances, or from some
other
cause, they appear to have been universally neglected; and
in the
progress of all those governments, military exercises seem
to have
gone gradually into disuse among the great body of the
people.
In the
republics of ancient Greece and Rome, during the whole
period
of their existence, and under the feudal govermnents, for
a
considerable time after their first establishment, the trade of
a
soldier was not a separate, distinct trade, which constituted
the
sole or principal occupation of a particular class of
citizens;
every subject of the state, whatever might be the
ordinary
trade or occupation by which he gained his livelihood,
considered
himself, upon all ordinary occasions, as fit likewise
to
exercise the trade of a soldier, and, upon many extraordinary
occasions,
as bound to exercise it.
The art
of war, however, as it is certainly the noblest of all
arts,
so, in the progress of improvement, it necessarily becomes
one of
the most complicated among them. The state of the
mechanical,
as well as some other arts, with which it is
necessarily
connected, determines the degree of perfection to
which
it is capable of being carried at any particular time. But
in
order to carry it to this degree of perfection, it is
necessary
that it should become the sole or principal occupation
of a
particular class of citizens; and the division of labour is
as
necessary for the improvement of this, as of every other art.
Into
other arts, the division of labour is naturally introduced
by the
prudence of individuals, who find that they promote their
private
interest better by confining themselves to a particular
trade,
than by exercising a great number. But it is the wisdom of
the
state only, which can render the trade of a soldier a
particular
trade, separate and distinct from all others. A
private
citizen, who, in time of profound peace, and without any
particular
encouragement from the public, should spend the
greater
part of his time in military exercises, might, no doubt,
both
improve himself very much in them, and amuse himself very
well;
but he certainly would not promote his own interest. It is
the
wisdom of the state only, which can render it for his
interest
to give up the greater part of his time to this peculiar
occupation
; and states have not always had this wisdom, even
when
their circumstances had become such, that the preservation
of
their existence required that they should have it.
A
shepherd has a great deal of leisure; a husbmdman, in the rude
state
of husbandry, has some; an artificer or manufacturer has
none at
all. The first may, without any loss, employ a great deal
of his
time in martial exercises ; the second may employ some
part of
it ; but the last cannot employ a single hour in them
without
some loss, and his attention to his own interest
naturally
leads him to neglect them altogether. Those
improvements
in husbandry, too, which the progress of arts and
manufactures
necessarily introduces, leave the husbandman as
little
leisure as the artificer. Military exercises come to be as
much
neglected by the inhabitants of the country as by those of
the
town, and the great body of the people becomes altogether
unwarlike.
That wealth, at the same time, which always follows
the
improvements of agriculture and manufactures, and which, in
reality,
is no more than the accumulated produce of those
improvements,
provokes the invasion of all their neighbours. An
industrious,
and, upon that account, a wealthy nation, is of all
nations
the most likely to be attacked ; and unless the state
takes
some new measure for the public defence, the natural habits
of the
people render them altogether incapable of defending
themselves.
In
these circumstances, there seem to be but two methods by which
the
state can make any tolerable provision for the public
defence.
It may
either, first, by means of a very rigorous police, and in
spite
of the whole bent of the interest, genius, and inclinations
of the
people, enforce the practice of military exercises, and
oblige
either all the citizens of the military age, or a certain
number
of them, to join in some measure the trade of a soldier to
whatever
other trade or profession they may happen to carry on.
Or,
secondly, by maintaining and employing a certain number of
citizens
in the constant practice of military exercises, it may
render
the trade of a soldier a particular trade, separate and
distinct
from all others.
If the
state has recourse to the first of those two expedients,
its
military force is said to consist in a militia; if to the
second,
it is said to consist in a standing army. The practice of
military
exercises is the sole or principal occupation of the
soldiers
of a standing army, and the maintenance or pay which the
state
affords them is the principal and ordinary fund of their
subsistence.
The practice of military exercises is only the
occasional
occupation of the soldiers of a militia, and they
derive
the principal and ordinary fund of their subsistence from
some
other occupation. In a militia, the character of the
labourer,
artificer, or tradesman, predominates over that of the
soldier;
in a standing army, that of the soldier predominates
over
every other character ; and in this distinction seems to
consist
the essential difference between those two different
species
of military force.
Militias
have been of several different kinds. In some countries,
the
citizens destined for defending the state seem to have been
exercised
only, without being, if I may say so, regimented; that
is,
without being divided into separate and distinct bodies of
troops,
each of which performed its exercises under its own
proper
and permanent officers. In the republics of ancient Greece
and
Rome, each citizen, as long as he remained at home, seems to
have
practised his exercises, either separately and
independently,
or with such of his equals as he liked best; and
not to
have been attached to any particular body of troops, till
he was
actually called upon to take the field. In other
countries,
the militia has not only been exercised, but
regimented.
In England, in Switzerland, and, I believe, in every
other
country of modern Europe, where any imperfect military
force
of this kind has been established, every militiaman is,
even in
time of peace, attached to a particular body of troops,
which
performs its exercises under its own proper and permanent
officers.
Before
the invention of fire-arms, that army was superior in
which
the soldiers had, each individually, the greatest skill and
dexterity
in the use of their arms. Strength and agility of body
were of
the highest consequence, and commonly determined the fate
of
battles. But this skill and dexterity in the use of their arms
could
be acquired only, in the same manner as fencing is at
present,
by practising, not in great bodies, but each man
separately,
in a particular school, under a particular master, or
with
his own particular equals and companions. Since the
invention
of fire-arms, strength and agility of body, or even
extraordinary
dexterity and skill in the use of arms, though they
are far
from being of no consequence, are, however, of less
consequence.
The nature of the weapon, though it by no means puts
the
awkward upon a level with the skilful, puts him more nearly
so than
he ever was before. All the dexterity and skill, it is
supposed,
which are necessary for using it, can be well enough
acquired
by practising in great bodies.
Regularity,
order, and prompt obedience to command, are qualities
which,
in modern armies, are of more importance towards
determining
the fate of battles, than the dexterity and skill of
the
soldiers in the use of their arms. But the noise of
fire-arms,
the smoke, and the invisible death to which every man
feels
himself every moment exposed, as soon as he comes within
cannon-shot,
and frequently a long time before the battle can be
well
said to be engaged, must render it very difficult to
maintain
any considerable degree of this regularity, order, and
prompt
obedience, even in the beginning of a modern battle. In an
ancient
battle, there was no noise but what arose from the human
voice ;
there was no smoke, there was no invisible cause of
wounds
or death. Every man, till some mortal weapon actually did
approach
him, saw clearly that no such weapon was near him.
In
these circumstances, and among troops who had some confidence
in
their own skill and dexterity in the use of their arms, it
must
have been a good deal less difficult to preserve some degree
of
regularity and order, not only in the beginning, but through
the
whole progress of an ancient battle, and till one of the two
armies
was fairly defeated. But the habits of regularity, order,
and
prompt obedience to command, can be acquired only by troops
which
are exercised in great bodies.
A
militia, however, in whatever manner it may be either
disciplined
or exercised, must always be much inferior to a well
disciplined
and well exercised standing army.
The
soldiers who are exercised only once aweek, or once a-month,
can
never be so expert in the use of their arms, as those who are
exercised
every day, or every other day; and though this
circumstance
may not be of so much consequence in modern, as it
was in
ancient times, yet the acknowledged superiority of the
Prussian
troops, owing, it is said, very much to their superior
expertness
in their exercise, may satisfy us that it is, even at
this
day, of very considerable consequence.
The
soldiers, who are bound to obey their officer only once
a-week,
or once a-month, and who are at all other times at
liberty
to manage their own affairs their own way, without being,
in any
respect, accountable to him, can never be under the same
awe in
his presence, can never have the same disposition to ready
obedience,
with those whose whole life and conduct are every day
directed
by him, and who every day even rise and go to bed, or at
least
retire to their quarters, according to his orders. In what
is
called discipline, or in the habit of ready obedience, a
militia
must always be still more inferior to a standing army,
than it
may sometimes be in what is called the manual exercise,
or in
the management and use of its arms. But, in modern war, the
habit
of ready and instant obedience is of much greater
consequence
than a considerable superiority in the management of
arms.
Those
militias which, like the Tartar or Arab militia, go to war
under
the same chieftains whom they are accustomed to obey in
peace,
are by far the best. In respect for their officers, in the
habit
of ready obedience, they approach nearest to standing
armies
The Highland militia, when it served under its own
chieftains,
had some advantage of the same kind. As the
Highlanders,
however, were not wandering, but stationary
shepherds,
as they had all a fixed habitation, and were not, in
peaceable
times, accustomed to follow their chieftain from place
to
place; so, in time of war, they were less willing to follow
him to
any considerable distance, or to continue for any long
time in
the field. When they had acquired any booty, they were
eager
to return home, and his authority was seldom sufficient to
detain
them. In point of obedience, they were always much
inferior
to what is reported of the Tartars and Arabs. As the
Highlanders,
too, from their stationary life, spend less of their
time in
the open air, they were always less accustomed to
military
exercises, and were less expert in the use of their arms
than
the Tartars and Arabs are said to be.
A
militia of any kind, it must be observed, however, which has
served
for several successive campaigns in the field, becomes in
every
respect a standing army. The soldiers are every day
exercised
in the use of their arms, and, being constantly under
the
command of their officers, are habituated to the same prompt
obedience
which takes place in standing armies.
What they
were
before they took the field, is of little importance. They
necessarily
become in every respect a standing army, after they
have
passed a few campaigns in it. Should the war in America drag
out
through another campaign, the American militia may become, in
every
respect, a match for that standing army, of which the
valour
appeared, in the last war at least, not inferior to that
of the
hardiest veterans of France and Spain.
This
distinction being well understood, the history of all ages,
it will
be found, hears testimony to the irresistible superiority
which a
well regulated standing army has over a militia.
One of
the first standing armies, of which we have any distinct
account
in any well authenticated history, is that of Philip of
Macedon.
His frequent wars with the Thracians, Illyrians,
Thessalians,
and some of the Greek cities in the neighbourhood of
Macedon,
gradually formed his troops, which in the beginning were
probably
militia, to the exact discipline of a standing army.
When he
was at peace, which he was very seldom, and never for any
long
time together, he was careful not to disband that army. It
vanquished
and subdued, after a long and violent struggle,
indeed,
the gallant and well exercised militias of the principal
republics
of ancient Greece; and afterwards, with very little
struggle,
the effeminate and ill exercised militia of the great
Persian
empire. The fall of the Greek republics, and of the
Persian
empire was the effect of the irresistible superiority
which a
standing arm has over every other sort of militia. It
is the
first great revolution in the affairs of mankind of which
history
has preserved any distinct and circumstantial account.
The
fall of Carthage, and the consequent elevation of Rome, is
the
second. All the varieties in the fortune of those two famous
republics
may very well be accounted for from the same cause.
From
the end of the first to the beginning of the second
Carthaginian
war, the armies of Carthage were continually in the
field,
and employed under three great generals, who succeeded one
another
in the command; Amilcar, his son-in-law Asdrubal, and his
son
Annibal: first in chastising their own rebellious slaves,
afterwards
in subduing the revolted nations of Africa; and
lastly,
in conquering the great kingdom of Spain. The army which
Annibal
led from Spain into Italy must necessarily, in those
different
wars, have been gradually formed to the exact
discipline
of a standing army. The Romans, in
the meantime,
though
they had not been altogether at peace, yet they had not,
during
this period, been engaged in any war of very great
consequence;
and their military discipline, it is generally said,
was a
good deal relaxed. The Roman armies which Annibal
encountered
at Trebi, Thrasymenus, and Cannae, were militia
opposed
to a standing army. This circumstance, it is probable,
contributed
more than any other to determine the fate of those
battles.
The
standing army which Annibal left behind him in Spain had the
like superiority
over the militia which the Romans sent to oppose
it;
and, in a few years, under the command of his brother, the
younger
Asdrubal, expelled them almost entirely from that
country.
Annibal
was ill supplied from home. The Roman militia, being
continually
in the field, became, in the progress of the war, a
well
disciplined and well exercised standing army ; and the
superiority
of Annibal grew every day less and less. Asdrubal
judged
it necessary to lead the whole, or almost the whole, of
the
standing army which he commanded in Spain, to the assistance
of his
brother in Italy. In this march, he is said to have been
misled
by his guides ; and in a country which he did not know,
was
surprised and attacked, by another standing army, in every
respect
equal or superior to his own, and was entirely defeated.
When
Asdrubal had left Spain, the great Scipio found nothing to
oppose
him but a militia inferior to his own. He conquered and
subdued
that militia, and, in the course of the war, his own
militia
necessarily became a well disciplined and well exercised
standing
army. That standing army was afterwards carried to
Africa,
where it found nothing but a militia to oppose it. In
order
to defend Carthage, it became necessary to recal the
standing
army of Annibal. The disheartened and frequently
defeated
African militia joined it, and, at the battle of Zama,
composed
the greater part of the troops of Annibal. The event of
that
day determined the fate of the two rival republics.
From the
end of the second Carthaginian war till the fall of the
Roman
republic, the armies of Rome were in every respect standing
armies.
The standing army of Macedon made some resistance to
their
arms. In the height of their grandeur, it cost them two
great
wars, and three great battles, to subdue that little
kingdom,
of which the conquest would probably have been still
more
difficult, had it not been for the cowardice of its last
king.
The militias of all the civilized nations of the ancient
world,
of Greece, of Syria, and of Egypt, made but a feeble
resistance
to the standing armies of Rome. The militias of some
barbarous
nations defended themselves much better.
The
Scythian
or Tartar militia, which Mithridates drew from the
countries
north of the Euxine and Caspian seas, were the most
formidable
enemies whom the Romans had to encounter after the
second
Carthaginian war. The Parthian and German militias, too,
were
always respectable, and upon several occasions, gained very
considerable
advantages over the Roman armies. In general,
however,
and when the Roman armies were well commanded, they
appear
to have been very much superior; and if the Romans did not
pursue
the final conquest either of Parthia or Germany, it was
probably
because they judged that it was not worth while to add
those
two barbarous countries to an empire which was already too
large.
The ancient Parthians appear to have been a nation of
Scythian
or Tartar extraction, and to have always retained a good
deal of
the manners of their ancestors. The ancient Germans were,
like
the Scythians or Tartars, a nation of wandering shepherds,
who
went to war under the same chiefs whom they were accustomed
to
follow in peace. 'Their militia was exactly of the same kind
with
that of the Scythians or Tartars, from whom, too, they were
probably
descended.
Many
different causes contributed to relax the discipline of the
Roman
armies. Its extreme severity was, perhaps, one of those
causes.
In the days of their grandeur, when no enemy appeared
capable
of opposing them, their heavy armour was laid aside as
unnecessarily
burdensome, their laborious exercises were
neglected,
as unnecessarily toilsome. Under the Roman emperors,
besides,
the standing armies of Rome, those particularly which
guarded
the German and Pannonian frontiers, became dangerous to
their
masters, against whom they used frequently to set up their
own
generals. In order to render them less formidable, according
to some
authors, Dioclesian, according to others, Constantine,
first
withdrew them from the frontier, where they had always
before
been encamped in great bodies, generally of two or three
legions
each, and dispersed them in small bodies through the
different
provincial towns, from whence they were scarce ever
removed,
but when it became necessary to repel an invasion. Small
bodies
of soldiers, quartered in trading and manufacturing towns,
and
seldom removed from those quarters, became themselves trades
men,
artificers, and manufacturers. The civil came to predominate
over
the military character ; and the standing armies of Rome
gradually
degenerated into a corrupt, neglected. and
undisciplined
militia, incapable of resisting the attack of the
German
and Scythian militias, which soon afterwards invaded the
western
empire. It was only by hiring the militia of some of
those
nations to oppose to that of others, that the emperors were
for
some time able to defend themselves. The fall of the western
empire
is the third great revolution in the affairs of mankind,
of
which ancient history has preserved any distinct or
circumstantial
account. It was brought about by the
irresistible
superiority which the militia of a barbarous has
over
that of a civilized nation; which the militia of a nation of
shepherds
has over that of a nation of husbandmen, artificers,
and
manufacturers. The victories which have been gained by
militias
have generally been, not over standing armies, but over
other
militias, in exercise and discipline inferior to
themselves.
Such were the victories which the Greek militia
gained
over that of the Persian empire; and such, too, were those
which,
in later times, the Swiss militia gained over that of the
Austrians
and Burgundians.
The
military force of the German and Scythian nations, who
established
themselves upon ruins of the western empire,
continued
for some time to be of the same kind in their new
settlements,
as it had been in their original country. It was a
militia
of shepherds and husbandmen, which, in time of war, took
the
field under the command of the same chieftains whom it was
accustomed
to obey in peace. It was, therefore, tolerably well
exercised,
and tolerably well disciplined. As arts and industry
advanced,
however, the authority of the chieftains gradually
decayed,
and the great body of the people had less time to spare
for
military exercises. Both the discipline and the exercise of
the
feudal militia, therefore, went gradually to ruin, and
standing
armies were gradually introduced to supply the place of
it.
When the expedient of a standing army, besides, had once been
adopted
by one civilized nation, it became necessary that all its
neighbours
should follow the example. They soon found that their
safety
depended upon their doing so, and that their own militia
was
altogether incapable of resisting the attack of such an army.
The
soldiers of a standing army, though they may never have seen
an
enemy, yet have frequently appeared to possess all the courage
of
veteran troops, and, the very moment that they took the field,
to have
been fit to face the hardiest and most experienced
veterans.
In 1756, when the Russian army marched into Poland, the
valour
of the Russian soldiers did not appear inferior to that of
the
Prussians, at that time supposed to be the hardiest and most
experienced
veterans in Europe. The Russian empire, however, had
enjoyed
a profound peace for near twenty years before, and could
at that
time have very few soldiers who had ever seen an enemy.
When
the Spanish war broke out in 1739, England had enjoyed a
profound
peace for about eight-and-twenty years. The valour of
her
soldiers, however, far from being corrupted by that long
peace,
was never more distinguished than in the attempt upon
Carthagena,
the first unfortunate exploit of that unfortunate
war. In
a long peace, the generals, perhaps, may sometimes forget
their
skill; but where a well regulated standing army has been
kept
up, the soldiers seem never to forget their valour.
When a
civilized nation depends for its defence upon a militia,
it is
at all times exposed to be conquered by any barbarous
nation
which happens to be in its neighbourhood.
The frequent
conquests
of all the civilized countries in Asia by the Tartars,
sufficiently
demonstrates the natural superiority which the
militia
of a barbarous has over that of a civilized nation. A
well
regulated standing army is superior to every militia.
Such an
army, as it can best be maintained by an opulent and
civilized
nation, so it can alone defend such a nation against
the
invasion of a poor and barbarous neighbour. It is only by
means
of a standing army, therefore, that the civilization of any
country
can be perpetuated, or even preserved, for any
considerable
time.
As it
is only by means of a well regulated standing army, that a
civilized
country can be defended, so it is only by means of it
that a
barbarous country can be suddenly and tolerably civilized.
A
standing army establishes, with an irresistible force, the law
of the
sovereign through the remotest provinces of the empire,
and
maintains some degree of regular government in countries
which
could not otherwise admit of any. Whoever examines with
attention,
the improvements which Peter the Great introduced into
the
Russian empire, will find that they almost all resolve
themselves
into the establishment of a well regulated standing
army.
It is the instrument which executes and maintains all his
other
regulations. That degree of order and internal peace, which
that
empire has ever since enjoyed, is altogether owing to the
influence
of that army.
Men of
republican principles have been jealous of a standing
army,
as dangerous to liberty. It certainly is so, wherever the
interest
of the general, and that of the principal officers, are
not
necessarily connected with the support of the constitution of
the
state. The standing army of Czesar destroyed the Roman
republic.
The standing army of Cromwell turned the long
parliament
out of doors. But where the sovereign is himself the
general,
and the principal nobility and gentry of the country the
chief
officers of the army ; where the military force is placed
under
the command of those who have the greatest interest in the
support
of the civil authority, because they have themselves the
greatest
share of that authority, a standing army can never be
dangerous
to liberty. On the contrary, it may, in some cases, be
favourable
to liberty. The security which it gives to the
sovereign
renders unnecessary that troublesome jealousy, which,
in some
modern republics, seems to watch over the minutest
actions,
and to be at all times ready to disturb the peace of
every
citizen. Where the security of the magistrate, though
supported
by the principal people of the country, is endangered
by
every popular discontent; where a small tumult is capable of
bringing
about in a few hours a great revolution, the whole
authority
of government must be employed to suppress and punish
every
murmur and complaint against it. To a sovereign, on the
contrary,
who feels himself supported, not only by the natural
aristocracy
of the country, but by a well regulated standing
army,
the rudest, the most groundless, and the most licentious
remonstrances,
can give little disturbance. He can safely pardon
or
neglect them, and his consciousness of his own superiority
naturally
disposes him to do so. That degree of liberty which
approaches
to licentiousness, can be tolerated only in countries
where
the sovereign is secured by a well regulated standing army.
It is
in such countries only, that the public safety does not
require
that the sovereign should be trusted with any
discretionary
power, for suppressing even the impertinent
wantonness
of this licentious liberty.
The
first duty of the sovereign, therefore, that of defending the
society
from the violence and injustice of other independent
societies,
grows gradually more and more expensive, as the
society
advances in civilization. The
military force of the
society,
which originally cost the sovereign no expense, either
in time
of peace, or in time of war, must, in the progress of
improvement,
first be maintained by him in time of war, and
afterwards
even in time of peace.
The
great change introduced into the art of war by the invention
of
fire-arms, has enhanced still further both the expense of
exercising
and disciplining any particular number of soldiers in
time of
peace, and that of employing them in time of war. Both
their
arms and their ammunition are become more expensive. A
musket
is a more expensive machine than a javelin or a bow and
arrows;
a cannon or a mortar, than a balista or a catapulta. The
powder
which is spent in a modern review is lost irrecoverably,
and
occasions a very considerable expense. The javelins and
arrows
which were thrown or shot in an ancient one, could easily
be
picked up again, and were, besides, of very little value. The
cannon
and the mortar are not only much dearer, but much heavier
machines
than the balista or catapulta; and require a greater
expense,
not only to prepare them for the field, but to carry
them to
it. As the superiority of the modern artillery, too, over
that of
the ancients, is very great ; it has become much more
difficult,
and consequently much more expensive, to fortify a
town,
so as to resist, even for a few weeks, the attack of that
superior
artillery. In modern times, many different causes
contribute
to render the defence of the society more expensive.
The
unavoidable effects of the natural progress of improvement
have,
in this respect, been a good deal enhanced by a great
revolution
in the art of war, to which a mere accident, the
invention
of gunpowder, seems to have given occasion.
In
modern war, the great expense of firearms gives an evident
advantage
to the nation which can best afford that expense; and,
consequently,
to an opulent and civilized, over a poor and
barbarous
nation. In ancient times, the opulent and civilized
found
it difficult to defend themselves against the poor and
barbarous
nations. In modern times, the poor and barbarous find
it
difficult to defend themselves against the opulent and
civilized.
The invention of fire-arms, an invention which at
first
sight appears to be so pernicious, is certainly favourable,
both to
the permanency and to the extension of civilization.
PART II.
Of the
Expense of Justice
The
second duty of the sovereign, that of protecting, as far as
possible,
every member of the society from the injustice or
oppression
of every other member of it, or the duty of
establishing
an exact administration of justice, requires two
very
different degrees of expense in the different periods of
society.
Among
nations of hunters, as there is scarce any property, or at
least
none that exceeds the value of two or three days labour ;
so
there is seldom any established magistrate, or any regular
administration
of justice. Men who have no property, can injure
one
another only in their persons or reputations. But when one
man
kills, wounds, beats, or defames another, though he to whom
the
injury is done suffers, he who does it receives no benefit.
It is
otherwise with the injuries to property. The benefit of the
person
who does the injury is often equal to the loss of him who
suffers
it. Envy, malice, or resentment, are the only passions
which
can prompt one man to injure another in his person or
reputation.
But the greater part of men are not very frequently
under
the influence of those passions; and the very worst men are
so only
occasionally. As their gratification, too, how agreeable
soever
it may be to certain characters, is not attended with any
real or
permanent advantage, it is, in the greater part of men,
commonly
restrained by prudential considerations. Men may live
together
in society with some tolerable degree of security,
though
there is no civil magistrate to protect them from the
injustice
of those passions. But avarice and ambition in the
rich,
in the poor the hatred of labour and the love of present
ease
and enjoyment, are the passions which prompt to invade
property
; passions much more steady in their operation, and much
more
universal in their influence. Wherever there is a great
property,
there is great inequality. For one very rich man, there
must be
at least five hundred poor, and the affluence of the few
supposes
the indigence of the many. The affluence of the rich
excites
the indignation of the poor, who are often both driven by
want,
and prompted by envy to invade his possessions. It is only
under
the shelter of the civil magistrate, that the owner of that
valuable
property, which is acquired by the labour of many years,
or
perhaps of many successive generations, can sleep a single
night
in security. He is at all times surrounded by unknown
enemies,
whom, though he never provoked, he can never appease,
and
from whose injustice he can be protected only by the powerful
arm of
the civil magistrate, continually held up to chastise it.
The
acquisition of valuable and extensive property, therefore,
necessarily
requires the establishment of civil government. Where
there
is no property, or at least none that exceeds the value of
two or
three days labour, civil government is not so necessary.
Civil
government supposes a certain subordination. But as the
necessity
of civil government gradually grows up with the
acquisition
of valuable property; so the principal causes, which
naturally
introduce subordination, gradually grow up with the
growth
of that valuable property.
The
causes or circumstances which naturally introduce
subordination,
or which naturally and antecedent to any civil
institution,
give some men some superiority over the greater part
of
their brethren, seem to be four in number.
The
first of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority of
personal
qualifications, of strength, beauty, and agility of body
; of
wisdom and virtue; of prudence, justice, fortitude, and
moderation
of mind. The qualifications of the body, unless
supported
by those of the mind, can give little authority in any
period
of society. He is a very strong man, who, by mere strength
of
body, can force two weak ones to obey him. The qualifications
of the
mind can alone give very great authority They are however,
invisible
qualities; always disputable, and generally disputed.
No
society, whether barbarous or civilized, has ever found it
convenient
to settle the rules of precedency of rank and
subordination,
according to those invisible qualities; but
according
to something that is more plain and palpable.
The
second of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority
of age.
An old man, provided his age is not so far advanced as to
give
suspicion of dotage, is everywhere more respected than a
young
man of equal rank, fortune, and abilities. Among nations of
hunters,
such as the native tribes of North America, age is the
sole
foundation of rank and precedency. Among them, father is the
appellation
of a superior ; brother, of an equal ; and son, of an
inferior.
In the most opulent and civilized nations, age
regulates
rank among those who are in every other respect equal ;
and
among whom, therefore, there is nothing else to regulate it.
Among
brothers and among sisters, the eldest always takes place ;
and in
the succession of the paternal estate, every thing which
cannot
be divided, but must go entire to one person, such as a
title
of honour, is in most cases given to the eldest. Age is a
plain
and palpable quality, which admits of no dispute.
The
third of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority of
fortune.
The authority of riches, however, though great in every
age of
society, is, perhaps, greatest in the rudest ages of
society,
which admits of any considerable inequality of fortune.
A
Tartar chief, the increase of whose flocks and herds is
sufficient
to maintain a thousand men, cannot well employ that
increase
in any other way than in maintaining a thousand men. The
rude
state of his society does not afford him any manufactured
produce
any trinkets or baubles of any kind, for which he can
exchange
that part of his rude produce which is over and above
his own
consumption. The thousand men whom he thus maintains,
depending
entirely upon him for their subsistence, must both obey
his
orders in war, and submit to his jurisdiction in peace. He is
necessarily
both their general and their judge, and his
chieftainship
is the necessary effect of the superiority of his
fortune.
In an opulent and civilized society, a man may possess a
much
greater fortune, and yet not be able to command a dozen of
people.
Though the produce of his estate may be sufficient to
maintain,
and may, perhaps, actually maintain, more than a
thousand
people, yet, as those people pay for every thing which
they
get from him, as he gives scarce any thing to any body but
in
exchange for an equivalent, there is scarce anybody who
considers
himself as entirely dependent upon him, and his
authority
extends only over a few menial servants. The authority
of
fortune, however, is very great, even in an opulent and
civilized
society. That it is much greater than that either of
age or
of personal qualities, has been the constant complaint of
every
period of society which admitted of any considerable
inequality
of fortune. The first period of
society, that of
hunters,
admits of no such inequality. Universal poverty
establishes
their universal equality ; and the superiority,
either
of age or of personal qualities, are the feeble, but the
sole
foundations of authority and subordination. There is,
therefore,
little or no authority or subordination in this period
of
society. The second period of society, that of shepherds,
admits
of very great inequalities of fortune, and there is no
period
in which the superiority of fortune gives so great
authority
to those who possess it. There is no period,
accordingly,
in which authority and subordination are more
perfectly
established. The authority of an Arabian scherif is
very
great; that of a Tartar khan altogether despotical.
The
fourth of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority
of
birth. Superiority of birth supposes an ancient superiority of
fortune
in the family of the person who claims it. All families
are
equally ancient ; and the ancestors of the prince, though
they
may be better known, cannot well be more numerous than those
of the
beggar. Antiquity of family means everywhere the antiquity
either
of wealth, or of that greatness which is commonly either
founded
upon wealth, or accompanied with it. Upstart greatness is
everywhere
less respected than ancient greatness. The hatred of
usurpers,
the love of the family of an ancient monarch, are in a
great
measure founded upon the contempt which men naturally have
for the
former, and upon their veneration for the latter. As a
military
officer submits, without reluctance, to the authority of
a
superior by whom he has always been commanded, but cannot bear
that
his inferior should be set over his head; so men easily
submit
to a family to whom they and their ancestors have always
submitted;
but are fired with indignation when another family, in
whom
they had never acknowledged any such superiority, assumes a
dominion
over them.
The
distinction of birth, being subsequent to the inequality of
fortune,
can have no place in nations of hunters, among whom all
men,
being equal in fortune, must likewise be very nearly equal
in
birth. The son of a wise and brave man may, indeed, even among
them,
be somewhat more respected than a man of equal merit, who
has the
misfortune to be the son of a fool or a coward. The
difference,
however will not be very great; and there never was,
I
believe, a great family in the world, whose illustration was
entirely
derived from the inheritance of wisdom and virtue.
The
distinction of birth not only may, but always does, take
place
among nations of shepherds. Such nations are always
strangers
to every sort of luxury, and great wealth can scarce
ever be
dissipated among them by improvident profusion. There are
no
nations, accordingly, who abound more in families revered and
honoured
on account of their descent from a long race of great
and
illustrious ancestors ; because there are no nations among
whom
wealth is likely to continue longer in the same families.
Birth
and fortune are evidently the two circumstances which
principally
set one man above another. They are the two great
sources
of personal distinction, and are, therefore, the
principal
causes which naturally establish authority and
subordination
among men. Among nations of shepherds, both those
causes
operate with their full force. The great shepherd or
herdsman,
respected on account of his great wealth, and of the
great
number of those who depend upon him for subsistence, and
revered
on account of the nobleness of his birth, and of the
immemorial
antiquity or his illustrious family, has a natural
authority
over all the inferior shepherds or herdsmen of his
horde
or clan. He can command the united force of a greater
number
of people than any of them. His military power is greater
than
that of any of them. In time of war, they are all of them
naturally
disposed to muster themselves under his banner, rather
than
under that of any other person ; and his birth and fortune
thus
naturally procure to him some sort of executive power. By
commanding,
too, the united force of a greater number of people
than
any of them, he is best able to compel any one of them, who
may
have injured another, to compensate the wrong. He is the
person,
therefore, to whom all those who are too weak to defend
themselves
naturally look up for protection. It is to him that
they
naturally complain of the injuries which they imagine have
been
done to them ; and his interposition, in such cases, is more
easily
submitted to, even by the person complained of, than that
of any
other person would be. His birth and fortune thus
naturally
procure him some sort of judicial authority.
It is
in the age of shepherds, in the second period of society,
that
the inequality of fortune first begins to take place, and
introduces
among men a degree of authority and subordination,
which
could not possibly exist before. It thereby introduces some
degree
of that civil government which is indispensably necessary
for its
own preservation; and it seems to do this naturally, and
even
independent of the consideration of that necessity. The
consideration
of that necessity comes, no doubt, afterwards, to
contribute
very much to maintain and secure that authority and
subordination.
The rich, in particular, are necesarily interested
to
support that order of things, which can alone secure them in
the
possession of their own advantages. Men of inferior wealth
combine
to defend those of superior wealth in the possession of
their
property, in order that men of superior wealth may combine
to
defend them in the possession of theirs. All the inferior
shepherds
and herdsmen feel, that the security of their own herds
and
flocks depends upon the security of those of the great
shepherd
or herdsman; that the maintenance of their lesser
authority
depends upon that of his greater authority ; and that
upon
their subordination to him depends his power of keeping
their
inferiors in subordination to them. They constitute a sort
of
little nobility, who feel themselves interested to defend the
property,
and to support the authority, of their own little
sovereign.
in order that he may be able to defend their property,
and to
support their authority. Civil government, so far as it is
instituted
for the security of property, is, in reality,
instituted
for the defence of the rich against the poor, or of
those
who have some property against those who have none at all.
The
judicial authority of such a sovereign, however, far from
being a
cause of expense, was, for a long time, a source of
revenue
to him. The persons who applied to him for justice were
always
willing to pay for it, and a present never failed to
accompany
a petition. After the authority of the sovereign, too,
was
thoroughly established, the person found guilty, over and
above
the satisfaction which he was obliged to make to the party,
was
like-wise forced to pay an amercement to the sovereign. He
had
given trouble, he had disturbed, he had broke the peace of
his
lord the king, and for those offences an amercement was
thought
due. In the Tartar governments of Asia, in the
governments
of Europe which were founded by the German and
Scythian
nations who overturned the Roman empire, the
administration
of justice was a considerable source of revenue,
both to
the sovereign, and to all the lesser chiefs or lords who
exercised
under him any particular jurisdiction, either over some
particular
tribe or clan, or over some particular territory or
district.
Originally, both the sovereign and the inferior chiefs
used to
exercise this jurisdiction in their own persons.
Afterwards,
they universally found it convenient to delegate it
to some
substitute, bailiff, or judge. This substitute, however,
was
still obliged to account to his principal or constituent for
the profits
of the jurisdiction. Whoever reads the instructions
(They
are to be found in Tyrol's History of England) which were
given
to the judges of the circuit in the time of Henry II will
see
clearly that those judges were a sort of itinerant factors,
sent
round the country for the purpose of levying certain
branches
of the king's revenue. In those days, the administration
of
justice not only afforded a certain revenue to the sovereign,
but, to
procure this revenue, seems to have been one of the
principal
advantages which he proposed to obtain by the
administration
of justice.
This
scheme of making the administration of justice subservient
to the
purposes of revenue, could scarce fail to be productive of
several
very gross abuses. The person who applied for justice
with a
large present in his hand, was likeiy to get something
more
than justice; while he who applied for it with a small one
was
likely to get something less. Justice, too, might frequently
be
delayed, in order that this present might be repeated. The
amercement,
besides, of the person complained of, might
frequently
suggest a very strong reason for finding him in the
wrong,
even when he had not really been so. That such abuses were
far
from being uncommon, the ancient history of every country in
Europe
bears witness.
When
the sovereign or chief exercises his judicial authority in
his own
person, how much soever he might abuse it, it must have
been
scarce possible to get any redress ; because there could
seldom
be any body powerful enough to call him to account. When
he
exercised it by a bailiff, indeed, redress might sometimes be
had. If
it was for his own benefit only, that the bailiff had
been
guilty of an act of injustice, the sovereign himself might
not
always be unwilling to punish him, or to oblige him to repair
the
wrong. But if it was for the benefit of his sovereign; if it
was in
order to make court to the person who appointed him, and
who
might prefer him, that he had committed any act of oppression
; redress
would, upon most occasions, be as impossible as if the
sovereign
had committed it himself. In all barbarous governments,
accordingly,
in all those ancient governments of Europe in
particular,
which were founded upon the ruins of the Roman
empire,
the administration of justice appears for a long time to
have
been extremely corrupt ; far from being quite equal and
impartial,
even under the best monarchs, and altogether
profligate
under the worst.
Among
nations of shepherds, where the sovereign or chief is only
the
greatest shepherd or herdsman of the horde or clan, he is
maintained
in the same manner as any of his vassals or subjects,
by the
increase of his own herds or flocks. Among those nations
of
husbandmen, who are but just come out of the shepherd state,
and who
are not much advanced beyond that state, such as the
Greek
tribes appear to have been about the time of the Trojan
war,
and our German and Scythian ancestors, when they first
settled
upon the ruins of the western empire; the sovereign or
chief
is, in the same manner, only the greatest landlord of the
country,
and is maintained in the same manner as any other
landlord,
by a revenue derived from his own private estate. or
from
what, in modern Europe, was called the demesne of the crown.
His
subjects, upon ordinary occasions, contribute nothing to his
support,
except when, in order to protect them from the
oppression
of some of their fellow-subjects, they stand in need
of his
authority. The presents which they make him upon such
occasions
constitute the whole ordinary revenue, the whole of the
emoluments
which, except, perhaps, upon some very extraordinary
emergencies,
he derives from his dominion over them. When
Agamemnon,
in Homer, offers to Achilles, for his friendship, the
sovereignty
of seven Greek cities, the sole advantage which he
mentions
as likely to be derived from it was, that the people
would
honour him with presents. As long as such presents, as long
as the
emoluments of justice, or what may be called the fees of
court,
constituted, in this manner, the whole ordinary revenue
which
the sovereign derived from his sovereignty, it could not
well be
expected, it could not even decently be proposed, that he
should
give them up altogether. It might, and it frequently was
proposed,
that he should regulate and ascertain them. But after
they
had been so regulated and ascertained, how to hinder a
person
who was all-powerful from extending them beyond those
regulations,
was still very difficult, not to say impossible.
During
the continuance of this state of things, therefore, the
corruption
of justice, naturally resulting from the arbitrary and
uncertain
nature of those presents, scarce admitted of any
effectual
remedy.
But
when, from different causes, chiefly from the continually
increasing
expense of defending the nation against the invasion
of
other nations, the private estate of the sovereign had become
altogether
insufficient for defraying the expense of the
sovereignty;
and when it had become necessary that the people
should,
for their own security, contribute towards this expense
by
taxes of different kinds; it seems to have been very commonly
stipulated,
that no present for the administration of justice
should,
under any pretence, be accepted either by the sovereign,
or by
his bailiffs and substitutes, the judges. Those presents,
it
seems to have been supposed, could more easily be abolished
altogether,
than effectually regulated and ascertained. Fixed
salaries
were appointed to the judges, which were supposed to
compensate
to them the loss of whatever might have been their
share
of the ancient emoluments of justice; as the taxes more
than
compensated to the sovereign the loss of his. Justice was
then
said to be administered gratis.
Justice,
however, never was in reality administered gratis in any
country.
Lawyers and attorneys, at least, must always be paid by
the
parties; and if they were not, they would perform their duty
still
worse than they actually perform it. The fees annually paid
to
lawyers and attorneys, amount, in every court, to a much
greater
sum than the salaries of the judges. The circumstance of
those
salaries being paid by the crown, can nowhere much diminish
the
necessary expense of a law-suit. But it was not so much to
diminish
the expense, as to prevent the corruption of justice,
that
the judges were prohibited from receiving my present or fee
from
the parties.
The
office of judge is in itself so very honourable, that men are
willing
to accept of it, though accompanied with very small
emoluments. The inferior office of justice of peace,
though
attended
with a good deal of trouble, and in most cases with no
emoluments
at all, is an object of ambition to the greater part
of our
country gentlemen. The salaries of all the different
judges,
high and low, together with the whole expense of the
administration
and execution of justice, even where it is not
managed
with very good economy, makes, in any civilized country,
but a
very inconsiderable part of the whole expense of
government.
The
whole expense of justice, too, might easily be defrayed by
the
fees of court ; and, without exposing the administration of
justice
to any real hazard of corruption, the public revenue
might
thus be entirely discharged from a certain, though perhaps
but a
small incumbrance. It is difficult to regulate the fees of
court
effectually, where a person so powerful as the sovereign is
to
share in them and to derive any considerable part of his
revenue
from them. It is very easy, where the judge is the
principal
person who can reap any benefit from them. The law can
very
easily oblige the judge to respect the regulation though it
might
not always be able to make the sovereign respect it. Where
the
fees of court are precisely regulated and ascertained where
they
are paid all at once, at a certain period of every process,
into
the hands of a cashier or receiver, to be by him distributed
in
certain known proportions among the different judges after the
process
is decided and not till it is decided ; there seems to be
no more
danger of corruption than when such fees are prohibited
altogether.
Those fees, without occasioning any considerable
increase
in the expense of a law-suit, might be rendered fully
sufficient
for defraying the whole expense of justice.
But
not
being paid to the judges till the process was determined,
they
might be some incitement to the diligence of the court in
examining
and deciding it. In courts which consisted of a
considerable
number of judges, by proportioning the share of each
judge
to the number of hours and days which he had employed in
examining
the process, either in the court, or in a committee, by
order
of the court, those fees might give some encouragement to
the
diligence of each particular judge. Public services are never
better
performed, than when their reward comes only in
consequence
of their being performed, and is proportioned to the
diligence
employed in performing them. In the
different
parliaments
of France, the fees of court (called epices and
vacations)
constitute the far greater part of the emoluments of
the
judges. After all deductions are made, the neat salary paid
by the
crown to a counsellor or judge in the parliament of
Thoulouse.
in rank and dignity the second parliament of the
kingdom,
amounts only to 150 livres, about £6:11s. sterling
a-year.
About seven years ago, that sum was in the same place the
ordinary
yearly wages of a common footman. The distribuion of
these
epices, too, is according to the diligence of the judges. A
diligent
judge gains a comfortable, though moderate revenue, by
his
office; an idle one gets little more than his salary.
Those
parliaments are, perhaps, in many respects, not very
convenient
courts of justice; but they have never been accused ;
they
seem never even to have been suspected of corruption.
The
fees of court seem originaliy to have been the principal
support
of the different courts of justice in England. Each
court
endeavoured to draw to itself as much business as it could,
and
was, upon that account, willing to take cognizance of many
suits
which were not originally intended to fall under its
jurisdiction.
The court of king's bench, instituted for the trial
of
criminal causes only, took cognizance of civil suits; the
plaintiff
pretending that the defendant, in not doing him
justice,
had been guilty of some trespass or misdemeanour. The
court
of exchequer, instituted for the levying of the king's
revenue,
and for enforcing the payment of such debts only as were
due to
the king, took cognizance of all other contract debts ;
the
plantiff alleging that he could not pay the king, because the
defendant
would not pay him. In consequence of such fictions, it
came,
in many cases, to depend altogether upon the parties,
before
what court they would choose to have their cause tried,
and
each court endeavoured, by superior dispatch and
impartiality,
to draw to itself as many causes as it could. The
present
admirable constitution of the courts of justice in
England
was, perhaps, originally, in a great measure, formed by
this
emulation, which anciently took place between their
respective
judges : each judge endeavouring to give, in his own
court,
the speediest and most effectual remedy which the law
would
admit, for every sort of injustice. Originally, the courts
of law
gave damages only for breach of contract. The court of
chancery,
as a court of conscience, first took upon it to enforce
the
specific performance of agreements. When the breach of
contract
consisted in the non-payment of money, the damage
sustained
could be compensated in no other way than by ordering
payment,
which was equivalent to a specific performance of the
agreement. In such cases, therefore, the remedy of
the courts
of law
was sufficient. It was not so in
others. When the
tenant
sued his lord for having unjustly outed him of his lease,
the
damages which he recovered were by no means equivalent to the
possession
of the land. Such causes, therefore, for some time,
went
all to the court of chancery, to the no small loss of the
courts
of law. It was to draw back such causes to themselves,
that
the courts of law are said to have invented the artificial
and
fictitious writ of ejectment, the most effectual remedy for
an
unjust outer or dispossession of land.
A
stamp-duty upon the law proceedings of each particular court,
to be
levied by that court, and applied towards the maintenance
of the
judges, and other officers belonging to it, might in the
same
manner, afford a revenue sufficient for defraying the
expense
of the administration of justice, without bringing any
burden
upon the general revenue of the society. The judges,
indeed,
might in this case, be under the temptation of
multiplying
unnecessarily the proceedings upon every cause, in
order
to increase, as much as possible, the produce of such a
stamp-duty.
It has been the custom in modern Europe to regulate,
upon
most occasions, the payment of the attorneys and clerks of
court
according to the number of pages which they had occasion to
write;
the court, however, requiring that each page should
contain
so many lines, and each line so many words. In order to
increase
their payment, the attorneys and clerks have contrived
to
multiply words beyond all necessity, to the corruption of the
law
language of, I believe, every court of justice in Europe.
A like
temptation might, perhaps, occasion a like corruption in
the
form of law proceedings.
But
whether the administration of justice be so contrived as to
defray
its own expense, or whether the judges be maintained by
fixed
salaries paid to them from some other fund, it does not
seen
necessary that the person or persons entrusted with the
executive
power should be charged with the management of that
fund,
or with the payment of those salaries. That fund might
arise
from the rent of landed estates, the management of each
estate
being entrusted to the particular court which was to be
maintained
by it. That fund might arise even
from the
interest
of a sum of money, the lending out of which might, in
the
same manner, be entrusted to the court which was to be
maintained
by it. A part, though indeed but a small part of the
salary
of the judges of the court of session in Scotland, arises
from
the interest of a sum of money. The necessary instability of
such a
fund seems, however, to render it an improper one for the
maintenance
of an institution which ought to last for ever.
The
separation of the judicial from the executive power, seems
originally
to have arisen from the increasing business of the
society,
in consequence of its increasing improvement. The
administration
of justice became so laborious and so complicated
a duty,
as to require the undivided attention of the person to
whom it
was entrusted. The person entrusted with the executive
power,
not having leisure to attend to the decision of private
causes
himself, a deputy was appointed to decide them in his
stead.
In the progress of the Roman greatness, the consul was too
much
occupied with the political affairs of the state, to attend
to the
administration of justice. A
praetor, therefore, was
appointed
to administer it in his stead. In the progress of the
European
monarchies, which were founded upon the ruins of the
Roman
empire, the sovereigns and the great lords came universally
to
consider the administration of justice as an office both too
laborious
and too ignoble for them to execute in their own
persons.
They universally, therefore, discharged themselves of
it, by
appointing a deputy, bailiff or judge.
When
the judicial is united to the executive power, it is scarce
possible
that justice should not frequently be sacrificed to what
is
vulgarly called politics. The
persons entrusted with the
great
interests of the state may even without any corrupt views,
sometimes
imagine it necessary to sacrifice to those interests
the
rights of a private man. But upon the impartial
administration
of justice depends the liberty of every
individual,
the sense which he has of his own security. In order
to make
every individual feel himself perfectly secure in the
possession
of every right which belongs to him, it is not only
necessary
that the judicial should be separated from the
executive
power, but that it should be rendered as much as
possible
independent of that power. The judge should not be
liable
to be removed from his office according to the caprice of
that
power. The regular payment of his salary should not depend
upon
the good will, or even upon the good economy of that power.
PART III.
Of the
Expense of public Works and public Institutions.
The
third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth, is that
of
erecting and maintaining those public institutions and those
public
works, which though they may be in the highest degree
advantageous
to a great society, are, however, of such a nature,
that
the profit could never repay the expense to any individual,
or
small number of individuals; and which it, therefore, cannot
be
expected that any individual, or small number of individuals,
should
erect or maintain. The performance of this duty requires,
too,
very different degrees of expense in the different periods
of
society.
After
the public institutions and public works necessary for the
defence
of the socicty, and for the administration of justice,
both of
which have already been mentioned, the other works and
institutions
of this kind are chiefly for facilitating the
commerce
of the society, and those for promoting the instruction
of the
people. The institutions for instruction are of two kinds:
those
for the education of the youth, and those for the
instruction
of people of all ages. The consideration of the
manner
in which the expense of those different sorts of public
works
and institutions may be most properly defrayed will divide
this
third part of the present chapter into three different
articles.
ARTICLE
I. - Of the public Works and Institutions for
facilitating
the Commerce of the Society.
And,
first, of those which are necessary for facilitating
Commerce
in general.
That
the erection and maintenance of the public works which
facilitate
the commerce of any country, such as good roads,
bridges,
navigable canals, harbours, etc. must require very
different
degrees of expense in the different periods of society,
is
evident without any proof. The
expense of making and
maintaining
the public roads of any country must evidently
increase
with the annual produce of the land and labour of that
country,
or with the quantity and weight of the goods which it
becomes
necessary to fetch and carry upon those roads. The
strength
of a bridge must be suited to the number and weight of
the
carriages which are likely to pass over it. The depth and the
supply
of water for a navigable canal must be proportioned to the
number
and tonnage of the lighters which are likely to carry
goods
upon it; the extent of a harbour, to the number of the
shipping
which are likely to take shelter in it.
It does
not seem necessary that the expense of those public works
should
be defrayed from that public revenue, as it is commonly
called,
of which the collection and application are in most
countries,
assigned to the executive power. The greater part of
such
public works may easily be so managed, as to afford a
particular
revenue, sufficient for defraying their own expense
without
bringing any burden upon the general revenue of the
society.
A
highway, a bridge, a navigable canal, for example, may, in most
cases,
be both made add maintained by a small toll upon the
carriages
which make use of them ; a harbour, by a moderate
port-duty
upon the tonnage of the shipping which load or unload
in it.
The coinage, another institution for facilitating
commerce,
in many countries, not only defrays its own expense,
but
affords a small revenue or a seignorage to the sovereign. The
post-office,
another institution for the same purpose, over and
above
defraying its own expense, affords, in almost all
countries,
a very considerable revenue to the sovereign.
When
the carriages which pass over a highway or a bridge, and the
lighters
which sail upon a navigable canal, pay toll in
proportion
to their weight or their tonnage, they pay for the
maintenance
of those public works exactly in proportion to the
wear
and tear which they occasion of them. It seems scarce
possible
to invent a more equitable way of maintaining such
works.
This tax or toll, too, though it is advanced by the
carrier,
is finally paid by the consumer, to whom it must always
be
charged in the price of the goods. As the expense of carriage,
however,
is very much reduced by means of such public works, the
goods,
notwithstanding the toll, come cheaper to the consumer
than
they could otherwise have done, their price not being so
much
raised by the toll, as it is lowered by the cheapness of the
carriage.
The person who finally pays this tax, therefore, gains
by the
application more than he loses by the payment of it. His
payment
is exactly in proportion to his gain. It is, in reality,
no more
than a part of that gain which he is obliged to give up,
in
order to get the rest. It seems
impossible to imagine a
more
equitable method of raising a tax.
When
the toll upon carriages of luxury, upon coaches,
post-chaises,
etc. is made somewhat higher in proportion to their
weight,
than upon carriages of necessary use, such as carts,
waggons,
etc. the indolence and vanity of the rich is made to
contribute,
in a very easy manner, to the relief of the poor, by
rendering
cheaper the transportation of heavy goods to all the
different
parts of the country.
When
high-roads, bridges, canals, etc. are in this manner made
and
supported by the commerce which is carried on by means of
them,
they can be made only where that commerce requires them,
and,
consequently, where it is proper to make them. Their
expense,
too, their grandeur and magnificence, must be suited to
what
that commerce can afford to pay. They must be made,
consequently,
as it is proper to make them. A magnificent
high-road
cannot be made through a desert country, where there is
little
or no commerce, or merely because it happens to lead to
the
country villa of the intendant of the province, or to that of
some
great lord, to whom the intendant finds it convenient to
make
his court. A great bridge cannot be thrown over a river at a
place
where nobody passes, or merely to embellish the view from
the
windows of a neighbouring palace ; things which sometimes
happen
in countries, where works of this kind are carried on by
any
other revenue than that which they themselves are capable of
affording.
In
several different parts of Europe, the toll or lock-duty upon
a canal
is the property of private persons, whose private
interest
obliges them to keep up the canal. If it is not kept in
tolerable
order, the navigation necessarily ceases altogether,
and,
along with it, the whole profit which they can make by the
tolls.
If those tolls were put under the management of
commissioners,
who had themselves no interest in them, they might
be less
attentive to the maintenance of the works which produced
them.
The canal of Languedoc cost the king of France and the
province
upwards of thirteen millions of livres, which (at
twenty-eight
livres the mark of silver, the value of French money
in the
end of the last century) amounted to upwards of nine
hundred
thousand pounds sterling. When that great work was
finished,
the most likely method, it was found, of keeping it in
constant
repair, was to make a present of the tolls to Riquet,
the
engineer who planned and conducted the work. Those tolls
constitute,
at present, a very large estate to the different
branches
of the family of that gentleman, who have, therefore, a
great
interest to keep the work in constant repair. But had those
tolls
been put under the management of commissioners, who had no
such
interest, they might perhaps, have been dissipated in
ornamental
and unnecessary expenses, while the most essential
parts
of the works were allowed to go to ruin.
The
tolls for the maintenance of a highroad cannot, with any
safety,
be made the property of private persons. A high-road,
though
entirely neglected, does not become altogether impassable,
though
a canal does. The proprietors of the tolls upon a
high-road,
therefore, might neglect altogether the repair of the
road,
and yet continue to levy very nearly the same tolls. It is
proper,
therefore, that the tolls for the maintenance of such a
work
should be put under the managmnent of commissioners or
trustees.
In
Great Britain, the abuses which the trustees have committed in
the
management of those tolls, have, in many cases, been very
justly
complained of. At many turnpikes, it has been said, the
money
levied is more than double of what is necessary for
executing,
in the completest manner, the work, which is often
executed
in a very slovenly manner, and sometimes not executed at
all.
The system of repairing the high-roads by tolls of this
kind,
it must be observed, is not of very long standing. We
should
not wonder, therefore, if it has not yet been brought to
that
degree of perfection of which it seems capable. If mean and
improper
persons are frequently appointed trustees ; and if
proper
courts of inspection and account have not yet been
established
for controlling their conduct, and for reducing the
tolls
to what is barely sufficient for executing the work to be
done by
them ; the recency of the institution both accounts and
apologizes
for those defects, of which, by the wisdom of
parliament,
the greater part may, in due time, be gradually
remedied.
The
money levied at the different turnpikes in Great Britain, is
supposed
to exceed so much what is necessary for repairing the
roads,
that the savings which, with proper economy, might be made
from
it, have been considered, even by some ministers, as a very
great
resource, which might, at some time or another, be applied
to the
exigencies of the state. Government, it has been said, by
taking
the management of the turnpikes into its own hands, and by
employing
the soldiers, who would work for a very small addition
to
their pay, could keep the roads in good order, at a much less
expense
than it can be done by trustees, who have no other
workmen
to employ, but such as derive their whole subsistence
from
their wages. A great revenue, half a million, perbaps {Since
publishing
the two first editions of this book, I have got good
reasons
to believe that all the turnpike tolls levied in Great
Britain
do not procduce a neat revenue that amounts to half a
million
; a sum which, under the management of government, would
not be
sufficient to keep, in repair five of the principal roads
in the
kingdom}, it has been pretended, might in this manner be
gained,
without laying any new burden upon the people; and the
turnpike
roads might be made to contribute to the general expense
of the
state, in the same manner as the post-office does at
present.
That a
considerable revenue might be gained in this manner, I
have no
doubt, though probably not near so much as the projectors
of this
plan have supposed. The plan itself, however, seems
liable
to several very important objections.
First,
If the tolls which are levied at the turnpikes should ever
be
considered as one of the resources for supplying the
exigencies
of the state, they would certainly be augmented as
those
exigencies were supposed to require. According to the
policy
of Great Britain, therefore, they would probably he
augmented
very fast. The facility with which a great revenue
could
be drawn from them, would probably encourage administration
to
recur very frequently te this resource. Though it may,
perhaps,
be more than doubtful whether half a million could by
any
economy be saved out of the present tolls, it can scarcely be
doubted,
but that a million might be saved out of them, if they
were
doubled ; and perhaps two millions, if they were tripled {I
have
now good reason to believe that all these conjectural sums
are by
much too large.}. This great revenue, too, might be levied
without
the appointment of a single new officer to collect and
receive
it. But the turnpike tolls, being continually augmented
in this
manner, instead of facilitating the inland commerce of
the
country, as at present, would soon become a very great
incumbrance
upon it. The expense of transporting all heavy goods
from
one part of the country to another, would soon be so much
increased,
the market for all such goods, consequently, would
soon be
so much narrowed, that their production would be in a
great
measure discouraged, and the most important branches of the
domestic
industry of the country annihilated altogether.
Secondly,
A tax upon carriages, in proportion to their weight,
though
a very equal tax when applied to the sole purpose of
repairing
the roads, is a very unequal one when applied to any
other
purpose, or to supply the common exigencies of the state.
When it
is applied to the sole purpose above mentioned, each
carriage
is supposed to pay exactly for the wear and tear which
that
carriage occasions of the roads. But when it is applied to
any
other purpose, each carriage is supposed to pay for more than
that
wear and tear, and contributes to the supply of some other
exigency
of the state. But as the turnpike toll raises the price
of
goods in proportion to their weight and not to their value, it
is
chiefly paid by the consumers of coarse and bulky, not by
those
of precious and light commodities. Whatever exigency of the
state,
therefore, this tax might be intended to supply, that
exigency
would be chiefly supplied at the expense of the poor,
not of
the rich; at the expense of those who are least able to
supply
it, not of those who are most able.
Thirdly,
If government should at any time neglect the reparation
of the
high-roads, it would be still more difficult, than it is
at
present, to compel the proper application of any part of the
turnpike
tolls. A large revenue might thus be levied upon the
people,
without any part of it being applied to the only purpose
to
which a revenue levied in this manner ought ever to be
applied.
If the meanness and poverty of the trustees of turnpike
roads
render it sometimes difficult, at present, to oblige them
to
repair their wrong ; their wealth and greatness would render
it ten
times more so in the case which is here supposed.
In
France, the funds destined for the reparation of the
high-roads
are under the immediate direction of the executive
power.
Those funds consist, partly in a certain number of days
labour,
which the country people are in most parts of Europe
obliged
to give to the reparation of the highways; and partly in
such a
portion of the general revenue of the state as the king
chooses
to spare from his other expenses.
By the
ancient law of France, as well as by that of most other
parts
of Europe, the labour of the country people was under the
direction
of a local or provincial magistracy, which had no
immediate
dependency upon the king's council. But, by the
present
practice, both the labour of the country people, and
whatever
other fund the king may choose to assign for the
reparation
of the high-roads in any particular province or
generality,
are entirely under the management of the intendant ;
an
officer who is appointed and removed by the king's council who
receives
his orders from it, and is in constant correspondence
with
it. In the progress of despotism, the authority of the
executive
power gradually absorbs that of every other power in
the
state, and assumes to itself the management of every branch
of
revenue which is destined for any public purpose. In France,
however,
the great post-roads, the roads which make the
communication
between the principal towns of the kingdom, are in
general
kept in good order; and, in some provinces, are even a
good
deal superior to the greater part of the turnpike roads of
England.
But what we call the cross roads, that is, the far
greater
part of the roads in the country, are entirely neglected,
and are
in many places absolutely impassable for any heavy
carriage.
In some places it is even dangerous to travel on
horseback,
and mules are the only conveyance which can safely be
trusted.
The proud minister of an ostentatious court, may
frequently
take pleasure in executing a work of splendour and
magnificence,
such as a great highway, which is frequently seen
by the
principal nobility, whose applauses not only flatter his
vanity,
but even contribute to support his interest at court. But
to
execute a great number of little works, in which nothing that
can be
done can make any great appearance, or excite the smallest
degree
of admiration in any traveller, and which, in short, have
nothing
to recommend them but their extreme utility, is a
business
which appears, in every respect, too mean and paltry to
merit
the attention of so great a magistrate. Under such an
administration
therefore, such works are almost always entirely
neglected.
In
China, and in several other governments of Asia, the executive
power
charges itself both with the reparation of the high-roads,
and
with the maintenance of the navigable canals. In the
instructions
which are given to the governor of each province,
those
objects, it is said, are constantly recommended to him, and
the
judgment which the court forms of his conduct is very much
regulated
by the attention which he appears to have paid to this
part of
his instructions. This branch of
public police,
accordingly,
is said to be very much attended to in all those
countries,
but particularly in China, where the high-roads, and
still
more the navigable canals, it is pretended, exceed very
much
every thing of the same kind which is known in Europe. The
accounts
of those works, however, which have been transmitted to
Europe,
have generally been drawn up by weak and wondering
travellers;
frequently by stupid and lying missionaries. If they
had
been examined by more intelligent eyes, and if the accounts
of them
had been reported by more faithful witnesses, they would
not,
perhaps, appear to be so wonderful. The account which
Bernier
gives of some works of this kind in Indostan, falls very
short
of what had been reported of them by other travellers, more
disposed
to the marvellous than he was. It may too, perhaps, be
in
those countries, as it is in France, where the great roads,
the
great communications, which are likely to be the subjects of
conversation
at the court and in the capital, are attended to,
and all
the rest neglected. In China, besides, in Indostan, and
in
several other governments of Asia, the revenue of the
sovereign
arises almost altogether from a land tax or land rent,
which
rises or falls with the rise and fall of the annual produce
of the
land. The great interest of the sovereign, therefore, his
revenue,
is in such countries necessarily and immediately
connected
with the cultivation of the land, with the greatness of
its
produce, and with the value of its produce. But in order to
render
that produce both as great and as valuable as possible, it
is
necessary to procure to it as extensive a market as possible,
and
consequently to establish the freest, the easiest, and the
least
expensive communication between all the different parts of
the
country; which can be done only by means of the best roads
and the
best navigable canals. But the revenue of the sovereign
does
not, in any part of Europe, arise chiefly from a land tax or
land
rent. In all the great kingdoms of
Europe, perhaps, the
greater
part of it may ultimately depend upon the produce of the
land:
but that dependency is neither so immediate nor so evident.
In
Europe, therefore, the sovereign does not feel himself so
directly
called upon to promote the increase, both in quantity
and
value of the produce of the land, or, by maintaining good
roads
and canals, to provide the most extensive market for that
produce. Though it should be true, therefore, what
I
apprehend
is not a little doubtful, that in some parts of Asia
this
department of the public police is very properly managed by
the
executive power, there is not the least probability that,
during
the present state of things, it could be tolerably managed
by that
power in any part of Europe.
Even
those public works, which are of such a nature that they
cannot
afford any revenue for maintaining themselves, but of
which
the convecniency is nearly confined to some particular
place
or district, are always better maintained by a local or
provincial
revenue, under the management of a local and
provincial
administration, than by the general revenue of the
state,
of which the executive power must always have the
management.
Were the streets of London to be lighted and paved at
the
expense of the treasury, is there any probability that they
would
be so well lighted and paved as they are at present, or
even at
so small an expense ? The expense, besides, instead of
being
raised by a local tax upon the inhabitants of each
particular
street, parish, or district in London, would, in this
case, be
defrayed out of the general revenue of the state, and
would
consequently be raised by a tax upon all the inhabitants of
the
kingdom, of whom the greater part derive no sort of benefit
from
the lighting and paving of the streets of London.
The
abuses which sometimes creep into the local and provincial
administration
of a local and provincial revenue, how enormous
soever
they may appear, are in reality, however, almost always
very
trifling in comparison of those which commonly take place in
the administration
and expenditure of the revenue of a great
empire.
They are, besides, much more easily corrected. Under the
local
or provincial administration of the justices of the peace
in
Great Britain, the six days labour which the country people
are obliged
to give to the reparation of the highways, is not
always,
perhaps, very judiciously applied, but it is scarce ever
exacted
with any circumstance of cruelty or oppression. In
France,
under the administration of the intendants, the
application
is not always more judicious, and the exaction is
frequently
the most cruel and oppressive. Such corvees, as they
are
called, make one of the principal instruments of tyranny by
which
those officers chastise any parish or communeaute, which
has had
the misfortune to fall under their dspleasure.
Of the
public Works and Institution which are necessary for
facilitating
particular Branches of Commerce.
The
object of the public works and institutions above mentioned,
is to
facilitate commerce in general. But in order to facilitate
some
particular branches of it, particular institutions are
necessary,
which again require a particular and extraordinary
expense.
Some
particular branches of commerce which are carried on with
barbarous
and uncivilized nations, require extraordinary
protection. An ordinary store or counting-house
could give
little
security to the goods of the merchants who trade to the
western
coast of Africa. To defend them from the barbarous
natives,
it is necessary that the place where they are deposited
should
be in some measure fortified. The
disorders in the
government
of Indostan have been supposed to render a like
precaution
necessary, even among that mild and gentle people; and
it was
under pretence of securing their persons and property from
violence,
that both the English and French East India companies
were
allowed to erect the first forts which they possessed in
that
country. Among other nations, whose vigorous government will
suffer
no strangers to possess any fortified place within their
territory,
it may be necessary to maintain some ambassador,
minister,
or consul, who may both decide, according to their own
customs,
the differences arising among his own countrymen, and,
in
their disputes with the natives, may by means of his public
character,
interfere with more authority and afford them a more
powerful
protection than they could expect from any private man.
The
interests of commerce have frequently made it necessary to
maintain
ministers in foreign countries, where the purposes
either
of war or alliance would not have required any. The
commerce
of the Turkey company first occasioned the establishment
of an
ordinary ambassador at Constantinople. The first English
embassies
to Russia arose altogether from commercial interests.
The
constant interference with those interests, necessarily
occasioned
between the subjects of the different states of
Europe,
has probably introduced the custom of keeping, in all
neighbouring
countries, ambassadors or ministers constantly
resident,
even in the time of peace. This custom, unknown to
ancient
times, seems not to be older than the end of the
fifteenth,
or beginning of the sixteenth century; that is, than
the
time when commerce first began to extend itself to the
greater
part of the nations of Europe, and when they first began
to
attend to its interests.
It
seems not unreasonable, that the extraordinary expense which
the
protection of any particular branch of commerce may occasion,
should
be defrayed by a moderate tax upon that particular branch;
by a
moderate fine, for example, to be paid by the traders when
they
first enter into it; or, what is more equal, by a particular
duty of
so much per cent. upon the goods which they either import
into,
or export out of, the particular countries with which it is
carried
on. The protection of trade, in general, from pirates and
freebooters,
is said to have given occasion to the first
institution
of the duties of customs. But, if it was thought
reasonable
to lay a general tax upon trade, in order to defray
the
expense of protecting trade in general, it should seem
equally
reasonable to lay a particular tax upon a particular
branch
of trade, in order to defray the extraordinary expense of
protecting
that branch.
The
protection of trade, in general, has always been considered
as
essential to the defence of the commonwealth, and, upon that
account,
a necessary part of the duty of the executive power. The
collection
and application of the general duties of customs,
therefore,
have always been left to that power. But the
protection
of any particular branch of trade is a part of the
general
protection of trade; a part, therefore, of the duty of
that
power; and if nations always acted consistently, the
particular
duties levied for the purposes of such particular
protection,
should always have been left equally to its disposal.
But in
this respect, as well as in many others, nations have not
always
acted consistently; and in the greater part of the
commercial
states of Europe, particular companies of merchants
have
had the address to persuade the legislature to entrust to
them
the performance of this part of the duty of the sovereign,
together
with all the powers which are necessarily connected with
it.
These
companies, though they may, perhaps, have been useful for
the
first introduction of some branches of commerce, by making,
at
their own expense, an experiment which the state might not
think
it prudent to make, have in the long-run proved,
universally,
either burdensome or useless, and have either
mismanaged
or confined the trade.
When
those companies do not trade upon a joint stock, but are
obliged
to admit any person, properly qualified, upon paying a
certain
fine, and agreeing to submit to the regulations of the
company,
each member trading upon his own stock, and at his own
risk,
they are called regulated companies. When they trade upon a
joint
stock, each member sharing in the common profit or loss, in
proportion
to his share in this stock, they are called
joint-stock
companies. Such companies, whether regulated or
joint-stock,
sometimes have, and sometimes have not, exclusive
privileges.
Regulated
companies resemble, in every respect, the corporation
of trades,
so common in the cities and towns of all the different
countries
of Europe; and are a sort of enlarged monopolies of the
same
kind. As no inhabitant of a town can exercise an
incorporated
trade, without first obtaining his freedom in the
incorporation,
so, in most cases, no subject of the state can
lawfully
carry on any branch of foreign trade, for which a
regulated
company is established, without first becoming a member
of that
company. The monopoly is more or less strict, according
as the
terms of admission are more or less difficult, and
according
as the directors of the company have more or less
authority,
or have it more or less in their power to manage in
such a
manner as to confine the greater part of the trade to
themselves
and their particular friends. In the most ancient
regulated
companies, the privileges of apprenticeship were the
same as
in other corporations, and entitled the person who had
served
his time to a member of the company, to become himself a
member,
either without paying any fine, or upon paying a much
smaller
one than what was exacted of other people. The usual
corporation
spirit, wherever the law does not restrain it,
prevails
in all regulated companies. When they have been allowed
to act
according to their natural genius, they have always, in
order
to confine the competition to as small a number of persons
as
possible, endeavoured to subject the trade to many burdensome
regulations.
When the law has restrained them from doing this,
they
have become altogether useless and insignificant.
The
regulated companies for foreign commerce which at present
subsist
in Great Britain, are the ancient merchant-adventurers
company,
now commonly called the Hamburgh company, the Russia
company,
the Eastland company, the Turkey company, and the
African
company.
The
terms of admission into the Hamburgh company are now said to
be
quite easy ; and the directors either have it not in their
power
to subject the trade to any troublesome restraint or
regulations,
or, at least, have not of late exercised that power.
It has
not always been so. About the middle of the last century,
the
fine for admission was fifty, and at one time one hundred
pounds,
and the conduct of the company was said to be extremely
oppressive.
In l643, in 1645, and in 1661, the clothiers and free
traders
of the west of England complained of them to parliament,
as of
monopolists, who confined the trade, and oppressed the
manufactures
of the country. Though those complaints produced no
act of
parliament, they had probably intimidated the company so
far, as
to oblige them to reform their conduct. Since that time,
at
least, there have been no complaints against them. By the 10th
and
11th of William III. c.6, the fine for admission into the
Russia
company was reduced to five pounds; and by the 25th of
Charles
II. c.7, that for admission into the Eastland company to
forty
shillings ; while, at the same time, Sweden, Denmark, and
Norway,
all the countries on the north side of the Baltic, were
exempted
from their exclusive charter. The conduct of those
companies
had probably given occasion to those two acts of
parliament. Before that time, Sir Josiah Child had
represented
both these and the Hamburgh company as extremely
oppressive,
and imputed to their bad management the low state of
the
trade, which we at that time carried on to the countries
comprehended
within their respective charters. But though such
companies
may not, in the present times, be very oppressive, they
are
certainly altogether useless. To be merely useless, indeed,
is
perhaps, the highest eulogy which can ever justly be bestowed
upon a
regulated company; and all the three companies above
mentioned
seem, in their present state, to deserve this eulogy.
The
fine for admission into the Turkey company was formerly
twenty-five
pounds for all persons under twenty-six years of age,
and
fifty pounds for all persons above that age. Nobody but mere
merchants
could be admitted; a restriction which excluded all
shop-keepers
and retailers. By a bye-law, no British manufactures
could
be exported to Turkey but in the general ships of the
company;
and as those ships sailed always from the port of
London,
this restriction confined the trade to that expensive
port,
and the traders to those who lived in London and in its
neighbourhood.
By another bye-law, no person living within twenty
miles
of London, and not free of the city, could be admitted a
member
; another restriction which, joined to the foregoing,
necessarily
excluded all but the freemen of London. As the time
for the
loading and sailing of those general ships depended
altogether
upon the directors, they could easily fill them with
their
own goods, and those of their particular friends, to the
exclusion
of others, who, they might pretend, had made their
proposals
too late. In this state of things, therefore, this
company
was, in every respect, a strict and oppressive monopoly.
Those
abuses gave occasion to the act of the 26th of George II.
c. 18,
reducing the fine for admission to twenty pounds for all
persons,
without any distinction of ages, or any restriction,
either
to mere merchants, or to the freemen of London; and
granting
to all such persons the liberty of exporting, from all
the
ports of Great Britain, to any port in Turkey, all British
goods,
of which the exportation was not prohibited, upon paying
both
the general duties of customs, and the particular duties
assessed
for defraying the necessary expenses of the company ;
and
submitting, at the same time, to the lawful authority of the
British
ambassador and consuls resident in Turkey, and to the
bye-laws
of the company duly enacted. To prevent any oppression
by
those bye-laws, it was by the same act ordained, that if any
seven
members of the company conceived themselves aggrieved by
any
bye-law which should be enacted after the passing of this
act,
they might appeal to the board of trade and plantations (to
the
authority of which a committee of the privy council has now
succeeded),
provided such appeal was brought within twelve months
after
the bye-law was enacted; and that, if any seven members
conceived
themselves aggrieved by any bye-law which had been
enacted
before the passing of this act, they might bring a like
appeal,
provided it was within twelve months after the day on
which
this act was to take place. The experience of one year,
however,
may not always be sufficient to discover to all the
members
of a great company the pernicious tendency of a
particular
bye-law ; and if several of them should afterwards
discover
it, neither the board of trade, nor the committee of
council,
can afford them any redress. The object, besides, of the
greater
part of the bye-laws of all regulated companies, as well
as of
all other corporations, is not so much to oppress those who
are
already members, as to discourage others from becoming so;
which
may be done, not only by a high fine, but by many other
contrivances.
The constant view of such companies is always to
raise
the rate of their own profit as high as they can; to keep
the
market, both for the goods which they export, and for those
which
they import, as much understocked as they can ; which can
be done
only by restraining the competition, or by discouraging
new
adventurers from entering into the trade. A fine, even of
twenty
pounds, besides, though it may not, perhaps, be sufficient
to
discourage any man from entering into the Turkey trade, with
an
intention to continue in it, may be enough to discourage a
speculative
merchant from hazarding a single adventure in it. In
all
trades, the regular established traders, even though not
incorporated,
naturally combine to raise profits, which are noway
so
likely to be kept, at all times, down to their proper level,
as by
the occasional competition of speculative adventurers. The
Turkey
trade, though in some measure laid open by this act of
parliament,
is still considered by many people as very far from
being
altogether free. The Turkey company contribute to maintain
an ambassador
and two or three consuls, who, like other public
ministers,
ought to be maintained altogether by the state, and
the
trade laid open to all his majesty's subjects. The different
taxes
levied by the company, for this and other corporation
purposes,
might afford a revenue much more than sufficient to
enable
a state to maintain such ministers.
Regulated
companies, it was observed by Sir Josiah Child, though
they
had frequently supported public ministers, had never
maintained
any forts or garrisons in the countries to which they
traded;
whereas joint-stock companies frequently had. And, in
reality,
the former seem to be much more unfit for this sort of
service
than the latter. First, the
directors of a regulated
company
have no particular interest in the prosperity of the
general
trade of the company, for the sake of which such forts
and
garrisons are maintained. The decay of that general trade may
even
frequently contribute to the advantage of their own private
trade;
as, by diminishing the number of their competitors, it may
enable
them both to buy cheaper, and to sell dearer. The
directors
of a joint-stock company, on the contrary, having only
their
share in the profits which are made upon the common stock
committed
to their management, have no private trade of their
own, of
which the interest can be separated from that of the
general
trade of the company. Their private interest is connected
with
the prosperity of the general trade of the company, and with
the
maintenance of the forts and garrisons which are necessary
for its
defence. They are more likely, therefore, to have that
continual
and careful attention which that maintenance
necessarily
requires. Secondly, The directors of a joint-stock
company
have always the management of a large capital, the joint
stock
of the company, a part of which they may frequently employ,
with
propriety, in building, repairing, and maintaining such
necessary
forts and garrisons. But the directors of a regulated
company,
having the management of no common capital, have no
other
fund to employ in this way, but the casual revenue arising
from
the admission fines, and from the corporation duties imposed
upon
the trade of the company. Though they had the same interest,
therefore,
to attend to the maintenance of such forts and
garrisons,
they can seldom have the same ability to render that
attention
effectual. The maintenance of a public minister,
requiring
scarce any attention, and but a moderate and limited
expense,
is a business much more suitable both to the temper and
abilities
of a regulated company.
Long
after the time of Sir Josiah Child, however, in 1750, a
regulated
company was established, the present company of
merchants
trading to Africa ; which was expressly charged at
first
with the maintenance of all the British forts and garrisons
that
lie between Cape Blanc and the Cape of Good Hope, and
afterwards
with that of those only which lie between Cape Rouge
and the
Cape of Good Hope. The act which
establishes this
company
(the 23rd of George II. c.51 ), seems to have had two
distinct
objects in view; first, to restrain effectually the
oppressive
and monopolizing spirit which is natural to the
directors
of a regulated company ; and, secondly, to force them,
as much
as possible, to give an attention, which is not natural
to
them, towards the maintenance of forts and garrisons.
For the
first of these purposes, the fine for admission is
limited
to forty shillings. The company is prohibited from
trading
in their corporate capacity, or upon a joint stock ; from
borrowing
money upon common seal, or from laying any restraints
upon
the trade, which may be carried on freely from all places,
and by
all persons being British subjects, and paying the fine.
The government
is in a committee of nine persons, who meet at
London,
but who are chosen annually by the freemen of the company
at
London, Bristol, and Liverpool ; three from each place. No
committeeman
can be continued in office for more than three years
together.
Any committee-man might be removed by the board of
trade
and plantations, now by a committee of council, after being
heard
in his own defence. The committee are forbid to export
negroes
from Africa, or to import any African goods into Great
Britain.
But as they are charged with the maintenance of forts
and
garrisons, they may, for that purpose export from Great
Britain
to Africa goods and stores of different kinds. Out of the
moneys
which they shall receive from the company, they are
allowed
a sum, not exceeding eight hundred pounds, for the
salaries
of their clerks and agents at London, Bristol, and
Liverpool,
the house-rent of their offices at London, and all
other
expenses of management, commission, and agency, in England.
What
remains of this sum, after defraying these different
expenses,
they may divide among themselves, as compensation for
their
trouble, in what manner they think proper. By this
constitution,
it might have been expected, that the spirit of
monopoly
would have been effectually restrained, and the first of
these
purposes sufficiently answered. It would seem, however,
that it
had not. Though by the 4th of George III. c.20, the fort
of
Senegal, with all its dependencies, had been invested in the
company
of merchants trading to Africa, yet, in the year
following
(by the 5th of George III. c.44), not only Senegal and
its
dependencies, but the whole coast, from the port of Sallee,
in
South Barbary, to Cape Rouge, was exempted from the
jurisdiction
of that company, was vested in the crown, and the
trade
to it declared free to all his majesty's subjects. The
company
had been suspected of restraining the trade and of
establishing
some sort of improper monopoly. It is not, however,
very
easy to conceive how, under the regulations of the 23d
George
II. they could do so. In the printed debates of the house
of
commons, not always the most authentic records of truth, I
observe,
however, that they have been accused of this. The
members
of the committee of nine being all merchants, and the
governors
and factors in their different forts and settlements
being
all dependent upon them, it is not unlikely that the latter
might
have given peculiar attention to the consignments and
commissions
of the former, which would establish a real monopoly.
For the
second of these purposes, the maintenance of the forts
and
garrisons, an annual sum has been allotted to them by
parliament,
generally about £13,000. For the proper application
of this
sum, the committee is obliged to account annually to the
cursitor
baron of exchequer; which account is afterwards to be
laid
before parliament. But parliament, which gives so little
attention
to the application of millions, is not likely to give
much to
that of £13,000 a-year; and the cursitor baron of
exchequer,
from his profession and education, is not likely to be
profoundly
skilled in the proper expense of forts and garrisons.
The
captains of his majesty's navy, indeed, or any other
commissioned
officers, appointed by the board of admiralty, may
inquire
into the condition of the forts and garrisons, and report
their
observations to that board. But that board seems to have no
direct
jurisdiction over the committee, nor any authority to
correct
those whose conduct it may thus inquire into; and the
captains
of his majesty's navy, besides, are not supposed to be
always
deeply learned in the science of fortification. Removal
from an
office, which can he enjoyed only for the term of three
years,
and of which the lawful emoluments, even during that term,
are so
very small, seems to be the utmost punishment to which any
committee-man
is liable, for any fault, except direct
malversation,
or embezzlement, either of the public money, or of
that of
the company ; and the fear of the punishment can never be
a
motive of sufficient weight to force a continual and careful
attention
to a business to which he has no other interest to
attend.
The committee are accused of having sent out bricks and
stones
from England for the reparation of Cape Coast Castle, on
the
coast of Guinea ; a business for which parliament had several
times
granted an extraordinary sum of money. These bricks and
stones,
too, which had thus been sent upon so long a voyage, were
said to
have been of so bad a quality, that it was necessary to
rebuild,
from the foundation, the walls which had been repaired
with
them. The forts and garrisons which lie north of Cape Rouge,
are not
only maintained at the expense of the state, but are
under
the immediate government of the executive power ; and why
those
which lie south of that cape, and which, too, are, in part
at
least, maintained at the expense of the state, should be under
a
different government, it seems not very easy even to imagine a
good
reason. The protection of the Mediterranean trade was the
original
purpose or pretence of the garrisons of Gibraltar and
Minorca
; and the maintenance and government of those garrisons
have
always been, very properly, committed, not to the Turkey
company,
but to the executive power. In the extent of its
dominion
consists, in a great measure, the pride and dignity of
that
power ; and it is not very likely to fail in attention to
what is
necessary for the defence of that dominion. The garrisons
at
Gibraltar and Minorca, accordingly, have never been neglected.
Though
Minorca has been twice taken, and is now probably lost for
ever,
that disaster has never been imputed to any neglect in the
executive
power. I would not, however, be understood to
insinuate,
that either of those expensive garrisons was ever,
even in
the smallest degree, necessary for the purpose for which
they
were originally dismembered from the Spanish monarchy. That
dismemberment,
perhaps, never served any other real purpose than
to
alienate from England her natural ally the king of Spain, and
to
unite the two principal branches of the house of Bourbon in a
much
stricter and more permanent alliance than the ties of blood
could
ever have united them.
Joint-stock
companies, established either by royal charter, or by
act of
parliament, are different in several respects, not only
from
regulated companies, but from private copartneries.
First,
In a private copartnery, no partner without the consent of
the
company, can transfer his share to another person, or
introduce
a new member into the company. Each member, however,
may,
upon proper warning, withdraw from the copartnery, and
demand
payment from them of his share of the common stock. In a
joint-stock
company, on the contrary, no member can demand pay
ment of
his share from the company; but each member can, without
their
consent, transfer his share to another person, and thereby
introduce
a new member. The value of a share in a joint stock is
always
the price which it will bring in the market ; and this may
be
either greater or less in any proportion, than the sum which
its
owner stands credited for in the stock of the company.
Secondly,
In a private copartnery, each partner is bound for the
debts
contracted by the company, to the whole extent of his
fortune.
In a joint-stock company, on the contrary, each partner
is
bound only to the extent of his share.
The
trade of a joint-stock company is always managed by a court
of
directors. This court, indeed, is frequently subject, in many
respects,
to the control of a general court of proprietors.
But the
greater part of these proprietors seldom pretend to
understand
any thing of the business of the company; and when the
spirit
of faction happens not to prevail among them, give
themselves
no trouble about it, but receive contentedly such
halfyearly
or yearly dividend as the directors think proper to
make to
them. This total exemption front trouble and front risk,
beyond
a limited sum, encourages many people to become
adventurers
in joint-stock companies, who would, upon no account,
hazard
their fortunes in any private copartnery. Such companies,
therefore,
commonly draw to themselves much greater stocks, than
any
private copartnery can boast of. The trading stock of the
South
Sea company at one time amounted to upwards of thirty-three
millions
eight hundred thousand pounds. The
divided capital
of the
Bank of England amounts, at present, to ten millions seven
hundred
and eighty thousand pounds. The directors of such
companies,
however, being the managers rather of other people's
money
than of their own, it cannot well be expected that they
should
watch over it with the same anxious vigilance with which
the
partners in a private coparnery frequently watch over their
own.
Like the stewards of a rich man, they are apt to consider
attention
to small matters as not for their master's honour, and
very
easily give themselves a dispensation from having it.
Negligence
and profusion, therefore, must always prevail, more or
less,
in the management of the affairs of such a company. It is
upon
this account, that joint-stock companies for foreign trade
have
seldom been able to maintain the competition against private
adventurers.
They have, accordingly, very seldom succeeded
without
an exclusive privilege ; and frequently have not
succeeded
with one. Without an exclusive privilege, they have
commonly
mismanaged the trade. With an exclusive
privilege, they
have
both mismanaged and confined it.
The Royal African company, the predecessors
of the present
African
company, had an exclusive privilege by charter ; but as
that
charter had not been confirmed by act of parliament, the
trade,
in consequence of the declaration of rights, was, soon
after
the Revolution, laid open to all his majesty's subjects.
The
Hudson's Bay company are, as to their legal rights, in the
same
situation as the Royal African company.
Their exclusive
charter
has not been confirmed by act of parliament. The South
Sea
company, as long as they continued to be a trading company,
had an
exclusive privilege confirmed by act of parliament; as
have
likewise the present united company of merchants trading to
the
East Indies.
The
Royal African company soon found that they could not maintain
the
competition against private adventurers, whom,
notwithstanding
the declaration of rights, they continued for
some
time to call interlopers, and to persecute as such. In 1698,
however,
the private adventurers were subjected to a duty of ten
per cent.
upon almost all the different branches of their trade,
to be
employed by the company in the maintenance of their forts
and
garrisons. But, notwithstanding this
heavy tax, the company
were
still unable to maintain the competition.
Their stock and
credit
gradually declined. In 1712, their debts had become so
great,
that a particular act of parliament was thought necessary,
both
for their security and for that of their creditors. It was
enacted,
that the resolution of two-thirds of these creditors in
number
and value should bind the rust, both with regard to the
time
which should be allowed to the company for the payment of
their
debts, and with regard to any other agreement which it
might
be thought proper to make with them concerning those debts.
In
1730, their affairs were in so great disorder, that they were
altogether
incapable of maintaining their forts and garrisons,
the
sole purpose and pretext of their institution. From that
year
till their final dissolution, the parliament judged it
necessary
to allow the annual sum of £10,000 for that purpose.
In
1732, after having been for many years losers by the trade of
carrying
negroes to the West Indies, they at last resolved to
give it
up altogether ; to sell to the private traders to America
the
negroes which they purchased upon the coast; awl to employ
their
servants in a trade to the inland parts of Africa for gold
dust,
elephants teeth, dyeing drugs, etc. But their success in
this
more confined trade was not greater than in their former
extensive
one. Their affairs continued to go
gradually to
decline,
till at last, being in every respect a bankrupt company,
they
were dissolved by act of parliament, and their forts and
garrisons
vested in the present regulated company of merchants
trading
to Africa. Before the erection of the Royal African
company,
there had been three other joint-stock companies
successively
established, one after another, for the African
trade.
They were all equally unsuccessful. They all, however, had
exclusive
charters, which, though not confirmed by act of
parliament,
were in those days supposed to convey a real
exclusive
privilege.
The
Hudson's Bay company, before their misfortunes in the late
war,
had been much more fortunate than the Royal African company.
Their
necessary expense is much smaller. The whole number of
people
whom they maintain in their different settlements and
habitations,
which they have honoured with the name of forts, is
said
not to exceed a hundred and twenty persons. This number,
however,
is sufficient to prepare beforehand the cargo of furs
and
other goods necessary for loading their ships, which, on
account
of the ice, can seldom remain above six or eight weeks in
those
seas. This advantage of having a cargo ready prepared,
could
not, for several years, be acquired by private adventurers
; and
without it there seems to be no possibility of trading to
Hudson's
Bay. The moderate capital of the company, which, it is
said,
does not exceed one hundred and ten thousand pounds, may,
besides,
be sufficient to enable them to engross the whole, or
almost
the whole trade and surplus produce, of the miserable
though
extensive country comprehended within their charter. No
private
adventurers, accordingly, have ever attempted to trade to
that
country in competition with them. This company, therefore,
have
always enjoyed an exclusive trade, in fact, though they may
have no
right to it in law. Over and above all this, the moderate
capital
of this company is said to be divided among a very small
number
of proprietors. But a joint-stock company, consisting of a
small
number of proprietors, with a moderate capital, approaches
very
nearly to the nature of a private copartnery, and may be
capable
of nearly the same degree of vigilance and attention. It
is not
to be wondered at, therefore, if, in consequence of these
different
advantages, the Hudson's Bay company had, before the
late
war, been able to carry on their trade with a considerable
degree
of success. It does not seem probable, however, that their
profits
ever approached to what the late Mr Dobbs imagined them.
A much
more sober and judicious writer, Mr Anderson, author of
the
Historical and Chronological Deduction of Commerce, very
justly
observes, that upon examining the accounts which Mr Dobbs
himself
has given for several years together, of their exports
and
imports, and upon making proper allowances for their
extraordinary
risk and expense, it does not appear that their
profits
deserve to be envied, or that they can much, if at all,
exceed
the ordinary profits of trade.
The
South Sea company never had any forts or garrisons to
maintain,
and therefore were entirely exempted from one great
expense,
to which other joint-stock companies for foreign trade
are
subject; but they had an immense capital divided among an
immense
number of proprietors. It was naturally to be expected,
therefore,
that folly, negligence, and profusion, should prevail
in the
whole management of their affairs. The knavery and
extravagance
of their stock-jobbing projects are sufficiently
known,
and the explication of them would be foreign to the
present
subject. Their mercantile projects were not much better
conducted.
The first trade which they engaged in, was that of
supplying
the Spanish West Indies with negroes, of which (in
consequence
of what was called the Assiento Contract granted them
by the
treaty of Utrecht) they had the exclusive privilege. But
as it
was not expected that much profit could be made by this
trade,
both the Portuguese and French companies, who had enjoyed
it upon
the same terms before them, having been ruined by it,
they
were allowed, as compensation, to send annually a ship of
acertain
burden, to trade directly to the Spanish West Indies. Of
the ten
voyages which this annual ship was allowed to make, they
are
said to have gained considerably by one, that of the Royal
Caroline,
in 1731 ; and to have been losers, more or less, by
almost
all the rest. Their ill success was imputed, by their
factors
and agents, to the extortion and oppression of the
Spanish
government ; but was, perhaps, principally owing to the
profusion
and depredations of those very factors and agents; some
of whom
are said to have acquired great fortunes, even in one
year.
In 1734, the company petitioned the king, that they might
be
allowed to dispose of the trade and tonnage of their annual
ship,
on account of the little profit which they made by it, and
to
accept of such equivalent as they could obtain from the king
of
Spain.
In
1724, this company had undertaken the whale fishery. Of this,
indeed,
they had no monopoly ; but as long as they carried it on,
no
other British subjects appear to have engaged in it. Of the
eight
voyages which their ships made to Greenland, they were
gainers
by one, and losers by all the rest. After their eighth
and
last voyage, when they had sold their ships, stores, and
utensils,
they found that their whole loss upon this branch,
capital
and interest included, amounted to upwards of £237,000.
In
1722, this company petitioned the parliament to be allowed to
divide
their immense capital of more than thirty-three millions
eight
hundred thousand pounds, the whole of which had been lent
to
government, into two equal parts; the one half, or upwards of
£16,900,000,
to be put upon the same footing with other
government
annuities, and not to be subject to the debts
contracted,
or losses incurred, by the directors of the company,
in the
prosecution of their mercantile projects ; the other half
to
remain as before, a trading stock, and to be subject to those
debts
and losses. The petition was too reasonable not to be
granted.
In 1733, they again petitioned the parliament, that
three-fourths
of their trading stock might be turned into annuity
stock,
and only one-fourth remain as trading stock, or exposed to
the
hazards arising from the bad management of their directors.
Both
their annuity and trading stocks had, by this time, been
reduced
more than two millions each, by several different
payments
from government ; so that this fourth amounted only to
£3,662,784:8:6.
In 1748, all the demands of the company upon the
king of
Spain, in consequence of the assiento contract, were, by
the
treaty of Aix-la-Chapelle, given up for what was supposed an
equivalent.
An end was put to their trade with the Spanish West
Indies;
the remainder of their trading stock was turned into an
annuity
stock ; and the company ceased, in every respect, to be a
trading
company.
It
ought to be observed, that in the trade which the South Sea
company
carried on by means of their annual ship, the only trade
by
which it ever was expected that they could make any
considerable
profit, they were not without competitors, either in
the
foreign or in the home market. At Carthagena, Porto Bello,
and La
Vera Cruz, they had to encounter the competition of the
Spanish
merchants, who brought from Cadiz to those markets
European
goods, of the same kind with the outward cargo of their
ship ;
and in England they had to encounter that of the English
merchants,
who imported from Cadiz goods of the Spanish West
Indies,
of the same kind with the inward cargo. The goods, both
of the
Spanish and English merchants, indeed, were, perhaps,
subject
to higher duties. But the loss occasioned by the
negligence,
profusion, and malversation of the servants of the
company,
had probably been a tax much heavier than all those
duties.
That a joint-stock company should be able to carry on
successfully
any branch of foreign trade, when private
adventurers
can come into any sort of open and fair competition
with
them, seems contrary to all experience.
The old
English East India company was established in 1600, by a
charter
from Queen Elizabeth. In the first twelve voyages which
they
fitted out for India, they appear to have traded as a
regulated
company, with separate stocks, though only in the
general
ships of the company. In 1612, they united into a joint
stock. Their charter was exclusive, and, though
not confirmed
by act
of parliament, was in those days supposed to convey a real
exclusive
privilege. For many years, therefore, they were not
much
disturbed by interlopers. Their capital, which never
exceeded
£744,000, and of which £50 was a share, was not so
exorbitant,
nor their dealings so extensive, as to afford either
a
pretext for gross negligence and profusion, or a cover to gross
malversation.
Notwithstanding some extraordinary losses,
occassioned
partly by the malice of the Dutch East India company,
and
partly by other accidents, they carried on for many years a
successful
trade. But in process of time, when the principles of
liberty
were better understood, it became every day more and more
doubtful,
how far a royal charter, not confirmed by act of
parliament,
could convey an exclusive privilege. Upon this
question
the decisions of the courts of justice were not uniform,
but
varied with the authority of government, and the humours of
the
times. Interlopers multiplied upon
them; and towards the
end of
the reign of Charles II., through the whole of that of
James
II., and during a part of that of William III., reduced
them to
great distress. In 1698, a proposal was made to
parliament,
of advancing two millions to government, at eight per
cent.
provided the subscribers were erected into a new East India
company,
with exclusive privileges. The old East India company
offered
seven hundred thousand pounds, nearly the amount of their
capital,
at four per cent. upon the same conditions. But such was
at that
time the state of public credit, that it was more
convenient
for government to borrow two millions at eight per
cent.
than seven hundred thousand pounds at four. The proposal of
the new
subscribers was accepted, and a new East India company
established
in consequence. The old East India company, however,
had a
right to continue their trade till 1701. They had, at the
same
time, in the name of their treasurer, subscribed very
artfully
three hundred and fifteen thousand pounds into the stock
of the
new. By a negligence in the expression of the act of
parliament,
which vested the East India trade in the subscribers
to this
loan of two millions, it did not appear evident that they
were
all obliged to unite into a joint stock. A few private
traders,
whose subscriptions amounted only to seven thousand two
hundred
pounds, insisted upon the privilege of trading separately
upon
their own stocks, and at their own risks. The old East India
company
had a right to a separate trade upon their own stock till
1701 ;
and they had likewise, both before and after that period,
a
right, like that or other private traders, to a separate trade
upon
the £315,000, which they had subscribed into the stock of
the new
company. The competition of the two companies with the
private
traders, and with one another, is said to have well nigh
ruined
both. Upon a subsequent occasion, in 1750, when a proposal
was
made to parliament for putting the trade under the management
of a
regulated company, and thereby laying it in some measure
open,
the East India company, in opposition to this proposal,
represented,
in very strong terms, what had been, at this time,
the
miserable effects, as they thought them, of this competition.
In
India, they said, it raised the price of goods so high, that
they
were not worth the buying ; and in England, by overstocking
the
market, it sunk their price so low, that no profit could be
made by
them. That by a more plentiful supply, to the great
advantage
and conveniency of the public, it must have reduced
very
much the price of India goods in the English market, cannot
well be
doubted; but that it should have raised very much their
price
in the Indian market, seems not very probable, as all the
extraordinary
demand which that competition could occasion must
have
been but as a drop of water in the immense ocean of Indian
commerce.
The increase of demand, besides, though in the
beginning
it may sometimes raise the price of goods, never fails
to
lower it in the long-run. It encourages production, and
thereby
increases the competition of the producers, who, in order
to
undersell one another, have recourse to new divisions or
labour
and new improvements of art, which might never otherwise
have
been thought of. The miserable
effects of which the
company
complained, were the cheapness of consumption, and the
encouragement
given to production ; precisely the two effects
which
it is the great business of political economy to promote.
The
competition, however, of which they gave this doleful
account,
had not been allowed to be of long continuance. In 1702,
the two
companies were, in some measure, united by an indenture
tripartite,
to which the queen was the third party ; and in 1708,
they
were by act of parliament, perfectly consolidated into one
company,
by their present name of the United Company of Merchants
trading
to the East Indies. Into this act it was thought worth
while
to insert a clause, allowing the separate traders to
continue
their trade till Michaelmas 1711 ; but at the same time
empowering
the directors, upon three years notice, to redeem
their
little capital of seven thousand two hundred pounds, and
thereby
to convert the whole stock of the company into a joint
stock.
By the same act, the capital of the company, in
consequence
of a new loan to government, was augmented from two
millions
to three millions two hundred thousand pounds. In 1743,
the
company advanced another million to government. But this
million
being raised, not by a call upon the proprietors, but by
selling
annuities and contracting bond-debts, it did not augment
the
stock upon which the proprietors could claim a dividend. It
augmented,
however, their trading stock, it being equally liable
with
the other three millions two hundred thousand pounds, to the
losses
sustained, and debts contracted by the company in
prosecution
of their mercantile projects. From 1708, or at least
from
1711, this company, being delivered from all competitors,
and
fully established in the monopoly of the English commerce to
the
East Indies, carried on a succesful trade, and from their
profits,
made annually a moderate dividend to their proprietors.
During
the French war, which began in 1741, the ambition of Mr.
Dupleix,
the French governor of Pondicherry, involved them in the
wars of
the Carnatic, and in the politics of the Indian princes.
After
many signal successes, and equally signal losses, they at
last
lost Madras, at that time their principal settlement in
India.
It was restored to them by the treaty of Aix-la-Chapelle;
and,
about this time the spirit of war and conquest seems to have
taken
possession of their servants in India, and never since to
have
left them. During the French war,
which began in 1755,
their arms
partook of the general good fortune of those of Great
Britain.
They defended Madras, took Pondicherry, recovered
Calcutta,
and acquired the revenues of a rich and extensive
territory,
amounting, it was then said, to upwards of three
millions
a-year. They remained for several
years in quiet
possession
of this revenue; but in 1767, administration laid
claim
to their territorial acquisitions, and the revenue arising
from
them, as of right belonging to the crown ; and the company,
in
compensation for this claim, agreed to pay to government
£400,000
a-year. They had, before this, gradually augmented their
dividend
from about six to ten per cent. ; that is, upon their
capital
of three millions two hundred thousand pounds, they had
increased
it by £128,000, or had raised it from one hundred and
ninety-two
thousand to three hundred and twenty thousand pounds
a-year.
They were attempting about this time to raise it still
further,
to twelve and a-half per cent., which would have made
their
annual payments to their proprietors equal to what they had
agreed
to pay annually to government, or to £400,000 a-year. But
during
the two years in which their agreement with government was
to take
place, they were restrained from any further increase of
dividend
by two successive acts of parliament, of which the
object
was to enable them to make a speedier progress in the
payment
of their debts, which were at this time estimated at
upwards
of six or seven millions sterling. In 1769, they renewed
their
agreement with government for five years more, and
stipulated,
that during the course of that period, they should be
allowed
gradually to increase their dividend to twelve and a-half
per
cent; never increasing it, however, more than one per cent.
in one
year. This increase of dividend, therefore, when it had
risen
to its utmost height, could augment their annual payments,
to
their proprietors and government together, but by £680,000 ,
beyond
what they had been before their late territorial
acquisitions.
What the gross revenue of those territorial
acquisitions
was supposed to amount to, has already been
mentioned
; and by an account brought by the Cruttenden East
Indiaman
in 1769, the neat revenue, clear of all deductions and
military
charges, was stated at two millions forty-eight thousand
seven
hundred and forty-seven pounds. They were said, at the same
time,
to possess another revenue, arising partly from lands, but
chiefly
from the customs established at their different
settlements,
amounting to £439,000. The profits of their trade,
too,
according to the evidence of their chairman before the house
of
commons, amounted, at this time, to at least £400,000 a-year ;
according
to that of their accountant, to at least £500,000;
according
to the lowest account, at least equal to the highest
dividend
that was to be paid to their proprietors. So great a
revenue
might certainly have afforded an augmentation of
£680,000
in their annual payments ; and, at the same time, have
left a
large sinking fund, sufficient for the speedy reduction of
their
debt. In 1773, however, their debts, instead of being
reduced,
were augmented by an arrear to the treasury in the
payment
of the four hundred thousand pounds ; by another to the
custom-house
for duties unpaid; by a large debt to the bank, for
money
borrowed; and by a fourth, for bills drawn upon them from
India,
and wantonly accepted, to the amount of upwards of twelve
hundred
thousand pounds. The distress which these accumulated
claims
brought upon them, obliged them not only to reduce all at
once
their dividend to six per cent. but to throw themselves upon
the
mercy of govermnent, and to supplicate, first, a release from
the
further payment of the stipulated £400,000 a-year ; and,
secondly,
a loan of fourteen hundred thousand, to save them from
immediate
bankruptcy. The great increase of their fortune had, it
seems,
only served to furnish their servants with a pretext for
greater
profusion, and a cover for greater malversation, than in
proportion
even to that increase of fortune. The conduct of their
servants
in India, and the general state of their affairs both in
India
and in Europe, became the subject of a parliamentary
inquiry:
in consequence of which, several very important
alterations
were made in the constitution of their government,
both at
home and abroad. In India, their principal settlements or
Madras,
Bombay, and Calcutta, which had before been altogether
independent
of one another, were subjected to a governor-general,
assisted
by a council of four assessors, parliament assuming to
itself
the first nomination of this governor and council, who
were to
reside at Calcutta ; that city having now become, what
Madras
was before, the most important of the English settlements
in
India. The court of the Mayor of Calcutta, originally
instituted
for the trial of mercantile causes, which arose in the
city
and neighbourlood, had gradually extended its jurisdiction
with
the extension of the empire. It was now reduced and confined
to the
original purpose of its institution. Instead of it, a new
supreme
court of judicature was established, consisting of a
chief
justice and three judges, to be appointed by the crown. In
Europe,
the qualification necessary to entitle a proprietor to
vote at
their general courts was raisted, from five hundred
pounds,
the original price of a share in the stock of the
company,
to a thousand pounds. In order to vote upon this
qualification,
too, it was declared necessary, that he should
have
possessed it, if acquired by his own purchase, and not by
inheritance,
for at least one year, instead of six months, the
term
requisite before. The court of twenty-four directors had
before
been chosen annually; but it was now enacted, that each
director
should, for the future, be chosen for four years ; six
of
them, however, to go out of office by rotation every year, and
not be
capable of being re-chosen at the election of the six new
directors
for the ensuing year. In consequence of these
alterations,
the courts, both of the proprietors and directors,
it was
expected, would be likely to act with more dignity and
steadiness
than they had usually done before. But it seems
impossible,
by any alterations, to render those courts, in any
respect,
fit to govern, or even to share in the government of a
great
empire; because the greater part of their members must
always
have too little interest in the prosperity of that empire,
to give
any serious attention to what may promote it. Frequently
a man
of great, sometimes even a man of small fortune, is willing
to
purchase a thousand pounds share in India stock, merely for
the
influence which he expects to aquire by a vote in the court
of
proprietors. It gives him a share, though not in the plunder,
yet in the
appointment of the plunderers of India; the court of
directors,
though they make that appointment, being necessarily
more or
less under the influence of the proprietors, who not only
elect
those directors, but sometimes over-rule the appointments
of
their servants in India. Provided he
can enjoy this
influence
for a few years, and thereby provide for a certain
number
of his friends, he frequently cares little about the
dividend,
or even about the value of the stock upon which his
vote is
founded. About the prosperity of
the great empire,
in the
government of which that vote gives him a share, he seldom
cares
at all. No other sovereigns ever were, or, from the nature
of
things, ever could be, so perfectly indifferent about the
happiness
or misery of their subjects, the improvement or waste
of
their dominions, the glory or disgrace of their
administration,
as, from irresistible moral causes, the greater
part of
the proprietors of such a mercantile company are, and
necessarily
must be. This indifference, too, was more likely to
be
increased than diminished by some of the new regulations which
were
made in consequence of the parliamentary inquiry. By a
resolution
of the house of commons, for example, it was declared,
that
when the £1,400,000 lent to the company by government,
should
be paid, and their bond-debts be reduced to £1,500,000,
they
might then, and not till then, divide eight per cent. upon
their
capital; and that whatever remained of their revenues and
neat
profits at home should be divided into four parts; three of
them to
be paid into the exchequer for the use of the public, and
the
fourth to be reserved as a fund, either for the further
reduction
of their bond-debts, or for the discharge of other
contingent
exigencies which the company might labour under. But
if the
company were bad stewards and bad sovereigns, when the
whole
of their neat revenue and profits belonged to themselves,
and
were at their own disposal, they were surely not likely to be
better
when three-fourths of them were to belong to other people,
and the
other fourth, though to be laid out for the benefit of
the
company, yet to be so under the inspection and with the
approbation
of other people.
It
might be more agreeable to the company, that their own
servants
and dependants should have either the pleasure of
wasting,
or the profit of embezzling, whatever surplus might
remain,
after paying the proposed dividend of eight per cent.
than
that it should come into the hands of a set of people with
whom
those resolutions could scarce fail to set them in some
measure
at variance. The interest of those servants and
dependants
might so far predominate in the court of proprietors,
as
sometimes to dispose it to support the authors of depredations
which
had been committed in direct violation of its own
authority.
With the majority of proprietors, the support even of
the
authority of their own court might sometimes be a matter of
less
consequence than the support of those who had set that
authority
at defiance.
The
regulations of 1773, accordingly, did not put an end to the
disorder
of the company's government in India. Notwithstanding
that,
during a momentary fit of good conduct, they had at one
time
collected into the treasury of Calcutta more than £3,000,000
sterling
; notwithstanding that they had afterwards extended
either
their dominion or their depredations over a vast accession
of some
of the richest and most fertile countries in India, all
was
wasted and destroyed. They found themselves altogether
unprepared
to stop or resist the incursion of Hyder Ali; and in
consequence
of those disorders, the company is now (1784) in
greater
distress than ever ; and, in order to prevent immediate
bankruptcy,
is once more reduced to supplicate the assistance of
government. Different plans have been proposed by
the
different
parties in parliament for the better management of its
affairs;
and all those plans seem to agree in supposing, what was
indeed
always abundantly evident, that it is altogether unfit to
govern
its territorial possessions. Even the company itself seems
to be
convinced of its own incapacity so far, and seems, upon
that
account willing to give them up to government.
With
the right of possessing forts and garrisons in distant and
barbarous
countries is necessarily connected the right of making
peace
and war in those countries. The
joint-stock companies,
which
have had the one right, have constantly exercised the
other,
and have frequently had it expressly conferred upon them.
How
unjustly, how capriciously, how cruelly, they have commonly
exercised
it, is too well known from recent experience.
When a
company of merchants undertake, at their own risk and
expense,
to establish a new trade with some remote and barbarous
nation,
it may not be unreasonable to incorporate them into a
joint-stock
company, and to grant them, in case of their success,
a
monopoly of the trade for a certain number of years. It is
the
easiest and most natural way in which the state can
recompense
them for hazarding a dangerous and expensive
experiment,
of which the public is afterwards to reap the
benefit.
A temporary monopoly of this kind may be vindicated,
upon
the same principles upon which a like monopoly of a new
machine
is granted to its inventor, and that of a new book to its
author.
But upon the expiration of the term, the monopoly ought
certainly
to determine; the forts and garrisons, if it was found
necessary
to establish any, to be taken into the hands of
government,
their value to be paid to the company, and the trade
to be
laid open to all the subjects of the state.
By a
perpetual
monopoly, all the other subjects of the state are taxed
very
absurdly in two different ways : first, by the high price of
goods,
which, in the case of a free trade, they could buy much
cheaper
; and, secondly, by their total exclusion from a branch
of
business which it might be both convenient and profitable for
many of
them to carry on. It is for the most
worthless of all
purposes,
too, that they are taxed in this manner. It is merely
to
enable the company to support the negligence, profusion, and
malversation
of their own servants, whose disorderly conduct
seldom
allows the dividend of the company to exceed the ordinary
rate of
profit in trades which are altogether free, and very
frequently
makes a fall even a good deal short of that rate.
Without
a monopoly, however, a joint-stock company, it would
appear
from experience, cannot long carry on any branch of
foreign
trade. To buy in one market, in order to sell with profit
in
another, when there are many competitors in both; to watch
over,
not only the occasional variations in the demand, but the
much
greater and more frequent variations in the competition, or
in the
supply which that demand is likely to get from other
people;
and to suit with dexterity and judgment both the quantity
and
quality of each assortment of goods to all these
circumstances,
is a species of warfare, of which the operations
are
continually changing, and which can scarce ever be conducted
successfully,
without such an unremitting exertion of vigilance
and
attention as cannot long be expected from the directors of a
joint-stock
company. The East India company, upon the redemption
of
their funds, and the expiration of their exclusive privilege,
have a
right, by act of parliament, to continue a corporation
with a
joint stock, and to trade in their corporate capacity to
the
East Indies, in common with the rest of their fellow
subjects. But in this situation, the superior
vigilance and
attention
of a private adventurer would, in all probability, soon
make
them weary of the trade.
An
eminent French author, of great knowledge in matters of
political
economy, the Abbe Morellet, gives a list of fifty-five
joint-stock
companies for foreign trade, which have been
established
in different parts of Europe since the year 1600, and
which,
according to him, have all failed from mismanagement,
notwithstanding
they had exclusive privileges. He has been
misinformed
with regard to the history of two or three of them,
which
were not joint-stock companies and have not failed. But, in
compensation,
there have been several joint-stock companies which
have
failed, and which he has omitted.
The
only trades which it seems possible for a joint-stock company
to
carry on successfully, without an exclusive privilege, are
those,
of which all the operations are capable of being reduced
to what
is called a routine, or to such a uniformity of method as
admits
of little or no variation. Of this
kind is, first, the
banking
trade ; secondly, the trade of insurance from fire and
from
sea risk, and capture in time of war ; thirdly, the trade of
making
and maintaining a navigable cut or canal; and, fourthly,
the
similar trade of bringing water for the supply of a great
city.
Though
the principles of the banking trade may appear somewhat
abstruse,
the practice is capable of being reduced to strict
rules.
To depart upon any occasion from those rules, in
consequence
of some flattering speculation of extraordinary gain,
is
almost always extremely dangerous and frequently fatal to the
banking
company which attempts it. But the constitution of
joint-stock
companies renders them in general, more tenacious of
established
rules than any private copartnery. Such companies,
therefore,
seem extremely well fitted for this trade. The
principal
banking companies in Europe, accordingly, are
joint-stock
companies, many of which manage their trade very
successfully
without any exclusive privilege. The bank of England
has no
other exclusive privilege, except that no other banking
company
in England shall consist of more than six persons.
The two
banks of Edinburgh are joint-stock companies, without any
exclusive
privilege.
The
value of the risk, either from fire, or from loss by sea, or
by
capture, though it cannot, perhaps, be calculated very
exactly,
admits, however, of such a gross estimation, as renders
it, in
some degree, reducible to strict rule and method. The
trade
of insurance, therefore, may be carried on successfully by
a
joint-stock company, without any exclusive privilege. Neither
the
London Assurance, nor the Royal Exchange Assurance companies
have
any such privilege.
When a
navigable cut or canal has been once made, the management
of it
becomes quite simple and easy, and it is reducible to
strict
rule and method. Even the making of it is so, as it may be
contracted
for with undertakers, at so much a mile, and so much a
lock.
The same thing may be said of a canal, an aqueduct, or a
great
pipe for bringing water to supply a great city. Such
under-takings,
therefore, may be, and accordingly frequently are,
very
successfully managed by joint-stock companies, without any
exclusive
privilege.
To
establish a joint-stock company, however, for any undertaking,
merely
because such a company might be capable of managing it
successfully
; or, to exempt a particular set of dealers from
some of
the general laws which take place with regard to all
their
neighbours, merely because they might be capable of
thriving,
if they had such an exemption, would certainly not be
reasonable.
To render such an establishment perfectly reasonable,
with
the circumstance of being reducible to strict rule and
method,
two other circumstances ought to concur.
First, it
ought
to appear with the clearest evidence, that the undertaking
is of
greater and more general utility than the greater part of
common
trades ; and, secondly, that it requires a greater capital
than
can easily be collected into a private copartnery. If a
moderate
capital were sufficient, the great utility of the
undertaking
would not be a sufficient reason for establishing a
joint-stock
company; because, in this case, the demand for what
it was
to produce, would readily and easily be supplied by
private
adventurers. In the four trades above mentioned, both
those
circumstances concur.
The
great and general utility of the banking trade, when
prudently
managed, has been fully explained in the second book of
this
Inquiry. But a public bank, which
is to support public
credit,
and, upon particular emergencies, to advance to
government
the whole produce of a tax, to the amount, perhaps, of
several
millions, a year or two before it comes in, requires a
greater
capital than can easily be collected into any private
copartnery.
The
trade of insurance gives great security to the fortunes of
private
people, and, by dividing among a great many that loss
which
would ruin an individual, makes it fall light and easy upon
the
whole society. In order to give this security, however, it is
necessary
that the insurers should have a very large capital.
Before
the establishment of the two joint-stock companies for
insurance
in London, a list, it is said, was laid before the
attorney-general,
of one hundred and fifty private iusurers, who
had
failed in the course of a few years.
That
navigable cuts and canals, and the works which are sometimes
necessary
for supplying a great city with water, are of great and
general
utility, while, at the same time, they frequently require
a
greater expense than suits the fortunes of private people, is
sufficiently
obvious.
Except
the four trades above mentioned, I have not been able to
recollect
any other, in which all the three circumstances
requisite
for rendering reasonable the establislment of a
joint-stock
company concur. The English copper
company of
London,
the lead-smelting company, the glass-grinding company,
have
not even the pretext of any great or singular utility in the
object
which they pursue ; nor does the pursuit of that object
seem to
require any expense unsuitable to the fortunes of many
private
men. Whether the trade which those companies carry on, is
reducible
to such strict rule and method as to render it fit for
the
management of a joint-stock company, or whether they have any
reason
to boast of their extraordinary profits, I do not pretend
to
know. The mine-adventurers company has been long ago bankrupt.
A share
in the stock of the British Linen company of Edinburgh
sells,
at present, very much below par, though less so than it
did
some years ago. The joint-stock companies, which are
established
for the public-spirited purpose of promoting some
particular
manufacture, over and above managing their own affairs
ill, to
the diminution of the general stock of the society, can,
in
other respects, scarce ever fail to do more harm than good.
Notwithstanding
the most upright intentions, the unavoidable
partiality
of their directors to particular branches of the
manufacture,
of which the undertakers mislead and impose upon
them,
is a real discouragement to the rest, and necessarily
breaks,
more or less, that natural proportion which would
otherwise
establish itself between judicious industry and profit,
and
which, to the general industry of the country, is of all
encouragements
the greatest and the most effectual.
ART.
II. ˜ Of the Expense of the Institution for the Education of
Youth.
The
institutions for the education of the youth may, in the same
manner,
furnish a revenue sufficient for defraying their own
expense. The fee or honorary, which the scholar
pays to the
master,
naturally constitutes a revenue of this kind.
Even
where the reward of the master does not arise altogether
from
this natural revenue, it still is not necessary that it
should
be derived from that general revenue of the society, of
which
the collection and application are, in most countries,
assigned
to the executive power. Through the greater part of
Europe,
accordingly, the endowment of schools and colleges makes
either
no charge upon that general revenue, or but a very small
one. It
everywhere arises chiefly from some local or provincial
revenue,
from the rent of some landed estate, or from the
interest
of some sum of money, allotted and put under the
management
of trustees for this particular purpose, sometimes by
the
sovereign himself, and sometimes by some private donor.
Have
those public endowments contributed in general, to promote
the end
of their institution ? Have they contributed to encourage
the
diligence, and to improve the abilities, of the teachers?
Have
they directed the course of education towards objects more
useful,
both to the individual and to the public, than those to
which
it would naturally have gone of its own accord ? It should
not
seem very difficult to give at least a probable answer to
each of
those questions.
In
every profession, the exertion of the greater part of those
who
exercise it, is always in proportion to the necessity they
are
under of making that exertion. This necessity is greatest
with
those to whom the emoluments of their profession are the
only
source from which they expect their fortune, or even their
ordinary
revenue and subsistence. In order to acquire this
fortune,
or even to get this subsistence, they must, in the
course
of a year, execute a certain quantity of work of a known
value;
and, where the competition is free, the rivalship of
competitors,
who are all endeavouring to justle one another out
of
employment, obliges every man to endeavour to execute his work
with a
certain degree of exactness. The greatness of the objects
which
are to be acquired by success in some particular
professions
may, no doubt, sometimes animate the exertions of a
few men
of extraordinary spirit and ambition. Great objects,
however,
are evidently not necessary, in order to occasion the
greatest
exertions. Rivalship and emulation render excellency,
even in
mean professions, an object of ambition, and frequently
occasion
the very greatest exertions. Great
objects, on the
contrary,
alone and unsupported by the necessity of application,
have
seldom been sufficient to occasion any considerable
exertion.
In England, success in the profession of the law leads
to some
very great objects of ambition ; and yet how few men,
born to
easy fortunes, have ever in this country been eminent in
that
profession?
The
endowments of schools and colleges have necessarily
diminished,
more or less, the necessity of application in the
teachers.
Their subsistence, so far as it arises from their
salaries,
is evidently derived from a fund, altogether
independent
of their success and reputation in their particular
professions.
In some
universities, the salary makes but a part, and frequently
but a
small part, of the emoluments of the teacher, of which the
greater
part arises from the honoraries or fees of his pupils.
The necessity
of application, though always more or less
diminished,
is not, in this case, entirely taken away. Reputation
in his
profession is still of some importance to him, and he
still
has some dependency upon the affection, gratitude, and
favourable
report of those who have attended upon his
instructions;
and these favourable sentiments he is likely to
gain in
no way so well as by deserving them, that is, by the
abilities
and diligence with which he discharges every part of
his
duty.
In
other universities, the teacher is prohibited from receiving
any
honorary or fee from his pupils, and his salary constitutes
the
whole of the revenue which he derives from his office.
His
interest is, in this case, set as directly in opposition to
his
duty as it is possible to set it. It
is the interest of
every
man to live as much at his ease as he can; and if his
emoluments
are to be precisely the same, whether he does or does
not
perform some very laborious duty, it is certainly his
interest,
at least as interest is vulgarly understood, either to
neglect
it altogether, or, if he is subject to some authority
which
will not suffer him to do this, to perform it in as
careless
and slovenly a manner as that authority will permit.
If he
is naturally active and a lover of labour, it is his
interest
to employ that activity in any way from which he can
derive
some advantage, rather than in the performarnce of his
duty,
from which he can derive none.
If the
authority to which he is subject resides in the body
corporate,
the college, or university, of which he himself is a
member,
and in which the greater part of the other members are,
like
himself, persons who either are, or ought to be teachers,
they
are likely to make a common cause, to be all very indulgent
to one
another, and every man to consent that his neighbour may
neglect
his duty, provided he himself is allowed to neglect his
own. In
the university of Oxford, the greater part of the public
professors
have, for these many years, given up altogether even
the
pretence of teaching.
If the
authority to which he is subject resides, not so much in
the
body corporate, of which he is a member, as in some other
extraneous
persons, in the bishop of the diocese, for example, in
the
governor of the province, or, perhaps, in some minister of
state,
it is not, indeed, in this case, very likely that he will
be
suffered to neglect his duty altogether.
All that such
superiors,
however, can force him to do, is to attend upon his
pupils
a certain number of hours, that is, to give a certain
number
of lectures in the week, or in the year.
What those
lectures
shall be, must still depend upon the diligence of the
teacher
; and that diligence is likely to be proportioned to the
motives
which he has for exerting it. An extraneous jurisdiction
of this
kind, besides, is liable to be exercised both ignorantly
and
capriciously. In its nature, it is arbitrary and
discretionary;
and the persons who exercise it, neither attending
upon
the lectures of the teacher themselves, nor perhaps
understanding
the sciences which it is his business to teach, are
seldom
capable of exercising it with judgment. From the insolence
of
office, too, they are frequently indifferent how they exercise
it, and
are very apt to censure or deprive him of his office
wantonly
and without any just cause. The person subject to such
jurisdiction
is necessarily degraded by it, and, instead of being
one of
the most respectable, is rendered one of the meanest and
most
contemptible persons in the society. It is by powerful
protection
only, that he can effectually guard himself against
the bad
usage to which he is at all times exposed; and this
protection
he is most likely to gain, not by ability or diligence
in his
profession, but by obsequiousness to the will of his
superiors,
and by being ready, at all times, to sacrifice to that
will
the rights, the interest, and the honour of the body
corporate,
of which he is a member. Whoever has attended for any
considerable
time to the administration of a French university,
must
have had occasion to remark the effects which naturally
result
from an arbitrary and extraneous jurisdiction of this
kind.
Whatever
forces a certain number of students to any college or
university,
independent of the merit or reputation of the
teachers,
tends more or less to diminish the necessity of that
merit
or reputation.
The
privileges of graduates in arts, in law, physic, and
divinity,
when they can be obtained only by residing a certain
number
of years in certain universities, necessarily force a
certain
number of students to such universities, independent of
the
merit or reputation of the teachers. The privileges of
graduates
are a sort of statutes of apprenticeship, which have
contributed
to the improvement of education just as the other
statutes
of apprenticeship have to that of arts and manufactures.
The
charitable foundations of scholarships, exhibitions,
bursaries,
etc. necessarily attach a certain number of students
to certain
colleges, independent altogether of the merit of those
particular
colleges. Were the students upon such charitable
foundations
left free to choose what college they liked best,
such
liberty might perhaps contribute to excite some emulation
among
different colleges. A regulation, on the contrary, which
prohibited
even the independent members of every particular
college
from leaving it, and going to any other, without leave
first
asked and obtained of that which they meant to abandon,
would
tend very much to extinguish that emulation.
If in
each college, the tutor or teacher, who was to instruct
each
student in all arts and sciences, should not be voluntarily
chosen
by the student, but appointed by the head of the college ;
and if,
in case of neglect, inability, or bad usage, the student
should
not be allowed to change him for another, without leave
first
asked and obtained ; such a regulation would not only tend
very
much to extinguish all emulation among the different tutors
of the
same college, but to diminish very much, in all of them,
the
necessity of diligence and of attention to their respective
pupils. Such teachers, though very well paid by
their
students,
might be as much disposed to neglect them, as those who
are not
paid by them at all or who have no other recompense but
their
salary.
If the
teacher happens to be a man of sense, it must be an
unpleasant
thing to him to be conscious, while he is lecturing to
his
students, that he is either speaking or reading nonsense, or
what is
very little better than nonsense. It must, too, be
unpleasant
to him to observe, that the greater part of his
students
desert his lectures ; or perhaps, attend upon them with
plain
enough marks of neglect, contempt, and derision. If he is
obliged,
therefore, to give a certain number of lectures, these
motives
alone, without any other interest, might dispose him to
take
some pains to give tolerably good ones. Several different
expedients,
however, may be fallen upon, which will effectually
blunt
the edge of all those incitements to diligence. The
teacher,
instead of explaining to his pupils himself the science
in
which he proposes to instruct them, may read some book upon
it; and
if this book is written in a foreign and dead language,
by
interpreting it to them into their own, or, what would give
him
still less trouble, by making them interpret it to him, and
by now
and then making an occasional remark upon it, he may
flatter
himself that he is giving a lecture.
The slightest
degree
of knowledge and application will enable him to do this,
without
exposing himself to contempt or derision, by saying any
thing
that is really foolish, absurd, or ridiculous. The
discipline
of the college, at the same time, may enable him to
force
all his pupils to the most regular attendance upon his sham
lecture,
and to maintain the most decent and respectful behaviour
during
the whole time of the performance.
The
discipline of colleges and universities is in general
contrived,
not for the benefit of the students, but for the
interest,
or, more properly speaking, for the ease of the
masters.
Its object is, in all cases, to maintain the authority
of the
master, and, whether he neglects or performs his duty, to
oblige
the students in all cases to behave to him as if he
performed
it with the greatest diligence and ability. It seems to
presume
perfect wisdom and virtue in the one order, and the
greatest
weakness and folly in the other. Where the masters,
however,
really perform their duty, there are no examples, I
believe,
that the greater part of the students ever neglect
theirs. No discipline is ever requisite to force
attendance
upon
lectures which are really worth the attending, as is well
known
wherever any such lectures are given. Force and restraint
may, no
doubt, be in some degree requisite, in order to oblige
children,
or very young boys, to attend to those parts of
education,
which it is thought necessary for them to acquire
during
that early period of life ; but after twelve or thirteen
years
of age, provided the master does his duty, force or
restraint
can scarce ever be necessary to carry on any part of
education.
Such is the generosity of the greater part of young
men,
that so far from being disposed to neglect or despise the
instructions
of their master, provided he shews some serious
intention
of being of use to them, they are generally inclined to
pardon
a great deal of incorrectness in the performance of his
duty,
and sometimes even to conceal from the public a good deal
of
gross negligence.
Those
parts of education, it is to be observed, for the teaching
of
which there are no public institutions, are generally the best
taught.
When a young man goes to a fencing or a dancing school,
he does
not, indeed, always learn to fence or to dance very well;
but he
seldom fails of learning to fence or to dance. The good
effects
of the riding school are not commonly so evident. The
expense
of a riding school is so great, that in most places it is
a public
institution. The three most essential parts of literary
education,
to read, write, and account, it still continues to be
more
common to acquire in private than in public schools; and it
very
seldom happens, that anybody fails of acquiring them to the
degree
in which it is necessary to acquire them.
In
England, the public schools are much less corrupted than the
universities.
In the schools, the youth are taught, or at least
may be
taught, Greek and Latin; that is, everything which the
masters
pretend to teach, or which it is expected they should
teach.
In the universities, the youth neither are taught, nor
always
can find any proper means of being taught the sciences,
which
it is the business of those incorporated bodies to teach.
The
reward of the schoolmaster, in most cases, depends
principally,
in some cases almost entirely, upon the fees or
honoraries
of his scholars. Schools have no exclusive privileges.
In
order to obtain the honours of graduation, it is not necessary
that a
person should bring a certificate of his having studied a
certain
number of years at a public school. If, upon examination,
he
appears to understand what is taught there, no questions are
asked
about the place where he learnt it.
The
parts of education which are commonly taught in universities,
it may
perhaps be said, are not very well taught. But had it not
been
for those institutions, they would not have been commonly
taught
at all; and both the individual and the public would have
suffered
a good deal from the want of those important parts of
education.
The
present universities of Europe were originally, the greater
part of
them, ecclesiastical corporations, instituted for the
education
of churchmen. They were founded by the authority of the
pope;
and were so entirely under his immediate protection, that
their
members, whether masters or students, had all of them what
was
then called the benefit of clergy, that is, were exempted
from
the civil jurisdiction of the countries in which their
respective
universities were situated, and were amenable only to
the
ecclesiastical tribunals. What was taught in the greater part
of
those universities was suitable to the end of their
institution,
either theology, or something that was merely
preparatory
to theology.
When
Christianity was first established by law, a corrupted Latin
had
become the common language of all the western parts of
Europe.
The service of the church, accordingly, and the
translation
of the Bible which were read in churches, were both
in that
corrupted Latin; that is, in the common language of the
country,
After the irruption of the barbarous nations who
overturned
the Roman empire, Latin gradually ceased to be the
language
of any part of Europe. But the reverence of the people
naturally
preserves the established forms and ceremonies of
religion
long after the circumstances which first introduced and
rendered
them reasonable, are no more. Though Latin, therefore,
was no
longer understood anywhere by the great body of the
people,
the whole service of the church still continued to be
performed
in that language. Two different
languages were
thus
established in Europe, in the same manner as in ancient
Egypt:
a language of the priests, and a language of the people; a
sacred
and a profane, a learned and an unlearned language. But it
was
necessary that the priests should understand something of
that
sacred and learned language in which they were to officiate;
and the
study of the Latin language therefore made, from the
beginning,
an essential part of university education.
It was
not so with that either of the Greek or of the Hebrew
language.
The infallible decrees of the church had pronounced the
Latin
translation of the Bible, commonly called the Latin
Vulgate,
to have been equally dictated by divine inspiration, and
therefore
of equal authority with the Greek and Hebrew originals.
The
knowledge of those two languages, therefore, not being
indispensably
requsite to a churchman, the study of them did not
for
along time make a necessary part of the common course of
university
education. There are some Spanish
universities, I
am
assured, in which the study of the Greek language has never
yet
made any part of that course. The first reformers found the
Greek
text of the New Testament, and even the Hebrew text of the
Old,
more favourable to their opinions than the vulgate
translation,
which, as might naturally be supposed, had been
gradually
accommodated to support the doctrines of the Catholic
Church.
They set themselves, therefore, to expose the many errors
of that
translation, which the Roman catholic clergy were thus
put
under the necessity of defending or explaining. But this
could
not well be done without some knowledge of the original
languages,
of which the study was therefore gradually introduced
into
the greater part of universities; both of those which
embraced,
and of those which rejected, the doctrines of the
reformation.
The Greek language was connected with every part of
that
classical learning, which, though at first principally
cultivated
by catholics and Italians, happened to come into
fashion
much about the same time that the doctrines of the
reformation
were set on foot. In the greater part of
universities,
therefore, that language was taught previous to the
study
of philosophy, and as soon as the student had made some
progress
in the Latin. The Hebrew language having no connection
with
classical learning, and, except the Holy Scriptures, being
the
language of not a single book in any esteem the study of it
did not
commonly commence till after that of philosophy, and when
the
student had entered upon the study of theology.
Originally,
the first rudiments, both of the Greek and Latin
languages,
were taught in universities; and in some universities
they
still continue to be so. In others, it is expected that the
student
should have previously acquired, at least, the rudiments
of one
or both of those languages, of which the study continues
to make
everywhere a very considerable part of university
education.
The
ancient Greek philosophy was divided into three great
branches;
physics, or natural philosophy; ethics, or moral
philosophy;
and logic. This general division seems perfectly
agreeable
to the nature of things.
The
great phenomena of nature, the revolutions of the heavenly
bodies,
eclipses, comets; thunder and lightning, and other
extraordinary
meteors; the generation, the life, growth, and
dissolution
of plants and animals; are objects which, as they
necessarily
excite the wonder, so they naturally call forth the
curiosity
of mankind to inquire into their causes.
Superstition
first attempted to satisfy this curiosity, by
referring
all those wonderful appearances to the immediate a
gency
of the gods. Philosophy afterwards endeavoured to account
for
them from more familiar causes, or from such as mankind were
better
acquainted with, than the agency of the gods. As those
great
phenomena are the first objects of human curiosity, so the
science
which pretends to explain them must naturally have been
the
first branch of philosophy that was cuitivated. The first
philosophers,
accordingly, of whom history has preserved any
account,
appear to have been natural philosophers.
In
every age and country of the world, men must have attended to
the
characters, designs, and actions of one another; and many
reputable
rules and maxims for the conduct of human life must
have
been laid down and approved of by common consent. As soon as
writing
came into fashion, wise men, or those who fancied
themselves
such, would naturally endeavour to increase the number
of
those established and respected maxims, and to express their
own
sense of what was either proper or improper conduct,
sometimes
in the more artificial form of apologues, like what are
called
the fables of Aesop; and sometimes in the more simple one
of
apophthegms or wise sayings, like the proverbs of Solmnon, the
verses
of Theognis and Phocyllides, and some part of the works of
Hesiod. They might continue in this manner, for a
long time,
merely
to multiply the number of those maxims of prudence and
morality,
without even attempting to arrange them in any very
distinct
or methodical order, much less to connect them together
by one
or more general principles, from which they were all
deducible,
like effects from their natural causes. The beauty of
a
systematical arrangement of different observations, connected
by a
few common principles, was first seen in the rude essays of
those
ancient times towards a system of natural philosophy.
Something
of the same kind was afterwards attempted in morals.
The
maxims of common life were arranged in some methodical order,
and
connected together by a few common principles, in the same
manner
as they had attempted to arrange and connect the phenomena
of
nature. The science which pretends
to investigate and
explain
those connecting principles, is what is properly called
Moral
Philosophy.
Different
authors gave different systems, both of natural and
moral
philosophy. But the arguments by which they supported those
different
systems, far from being always demonstrations, were
frequently
at best but very slender probabilities, and sometimes
mere
sophisms, which had no other foundation but the inaccuracy
and
ambiguity of common language.
Speculative systems, have,
in all
ages of the world, been adopted for reasons too frivolous
to have
determined the judgment of any man of common sense, in a
matter
of the smallest pecuniary interest. Gross sophistry has
scarce
ever had any influence upon the opinions of mankind,
except
in matters of philosophy and speculation ; and in these it
has
frequently had the greatest. The patrons of each system of
natural
and moral philosophy, naturally endeavoured to expose the
weakness
of the arguments adduced to support the systems which
were
opposite to their own. In examining those arguments, they
were
necessarily led to consider the difference between a
probable
and a demonstrative argument, between a fallacious and a
conclusive
one; and logic, or the science of the general
principles
of good and bad reasoning, necessarily arose out of
the
observations which a scrutiny of this kind gave occasion to ;
though,
in its origin, posterior both to physics and to ethics,
it was
commonly taught, not indeed in all, but in the greater
part of
the ancient schools of philosophy, previously to either
of
those sciences. The student, it seems to have been thought,
ought
to understand well the difference between good and bad
reasoning,
before he was led to reason upon subjects of so great
importance.
This
ancient division of philosophy into three parts was, in the
greater
part of the universities of Europe, changed for another
into
five.
In the
ancient philosophy, whatever was taught concerning the
nature
either of the human mind or of the Deity, made a part of
the
system of physics. Those beings, in
whatever their
essence
might be supposed to consist, were parts of the great
system
of the universe, and parts, too, productive of the most
important
effects. Whatever human reason could
either
conclude
or conjecture concerning them, made, as it were, two
chapters,
though no doubt two very important ones, of the science
which
pretended to give an account of the origin and revolutions
of the
great system of the universe. But in the universities of
Europe,
where philosophy was taught only as subservient to
theology,
it was natural to dwell longer upon these two chapters
than
upon any other of the science. They were gradually more and
more
extended, and were divided into many inferior chapters; till
at last
the doctrine of spirits, of which so little can be known,
came to
take up as much room in the system of philosophy as the
doctrine
of bodies, of which so much can be known. The doctrines
concerning
those two subjects were considered as making two
distinct
sciences. What are called
metaphysics, or
pnemnatics,
were set in opposition to physics, and were
cultivated
not only as the more sublime, but, for the purposes of
a
particular profession, as the more useful science of the two.
The
proper subject of experiment and observation, a subject in
which a
careful attention is capable of making so many useful
discoveries,
was almost entirely neglected. The
subject in
which,
after a very few simple and almost obvious truths, the
most
careful attention can discover nothing but obscurity and
uncertainty,
and can consequently produce nothing but subtlelies
and
sophisms, was greatly cultivated.
When
those two sciences had thus been set in opposition to one
another,
the comparison between them naturally gave birth to a
third,
to what was called ontology, or the science which treated
of the
qualities and attributes which were common to both the
subjects
of the other two sciences. But if subtleties and
sophisms
composed the greater part of the metaphysics or
pneumatics
of the schools, they composed the whole of this cobweb
science
of ontology, which was likewise sometimes called
metaphysics.
Wherein
consisted the happiness and perfection of a man,
considered
not only as an individual, but as the member of a
family,
of a state, and of the great society of mankind, was the
object
which the ancient moral philosophy proposed to
investigate.
In that philosophy, the duties of human life were
treated
of as subservient to the happiness and perfection of
human
life, But when moral, as well as natural philosophy, came
to be
taught only as subservient to theology, the duties of human
life
were treated of as chiefly subservient to the happiness of a
life to
come. In the ancient philosophy, the perfection of virtue
was
represented as necessarily productive, to the person who
possessed
it, of the most perfect happiness in this life. In the
modern
philosophy, it was frequently represented as generally, or
rather
as almost always, inconsistent with any degree of
happiness
in this life; and heaven was to be earned only by
penance
and mortification, by the austerities and abasement of a
monk,
not by the liberal, generous, and spirited conduct of a
man.
Casuistry, and an ascetic morality, made up, in most cases,
the
greater part of the moral philosophy of the schools. By far
the
most important of all the different branches of philosophy
became
in this manner by far the most corrupted.
Such,
therefore, was the common course of philosophical education
in the
greater part of the universities in Europe. Logic was
taught
first; ontology came in the second place; pneumatology,
comprehending
the doctrine concerning the nature of the human
soul
and of the Deity, in the third; in the fourth followed a
debased
system of moral philosophy, which was considered as
immediately
connected with the doctrines of pneumatology, with
the
immortality of the human soul, and with the rewards and
punishments
which, from the justice of the Deity, were to be
expected
in a life to come: a short and superficial system of
physics
usually concluded the course.
The
alterations which the universities of Europe thus introduced
into
the ancient course of philosophy were all meant for the
education
of ecclesiastics, and to render it a more proper
introduction
to the study of theology But the additional quantity
of
subtlety and sophistry, the casuistry and ascetic morality
which
those alterations introduced into it, certainly did not
render
it more for the education of gentlemen or men of the
world,
or more likely either to improve the understanding or to
mend
the heart.
This
course of philosophy is what still continues to be taught in
the
greater part of the universities of Europe, with more or less
diligence,
according as the constitution of each particular
university
happens to render diligence more or less necessary to
the
teachers. In some of the richest and best endowed
universities,
the tutors content themselves with teaching a few
unconnected
shreds and parcels of this corrupted course ; and
even
these they commonly teach very negligently and
superficially.
The
improvements which, in modern times have been made in several
different
branches of philosophy, have not, the greater part of
them,
been made in universities, though some, no doubt, have. The
greater
part of universities have not even been very forward to
adopt
those improvements after they were made; and several of
those
learned societies have chosen to remain, for a long time,
the
sanctuaries in which exploded systems and obsolete prejudices
found
shelter and protection, after they had been hunted out of
every
other corner of the world. In general, the richest and best
endowed
universities have been slowest in adopting those
improvements,
and the most averse to permit any considerable
change
in the established plan of education. Those improvements
were
more easily introduced into some of the poorer universities,
in
which the teachers, depending upon their reputation for the
greater
part of their subsistence, were obliged to pay more
attention
to the current opinions of the world.
But
though the public schools and universities of Europe were
originally
intended only for the education of a particular
profession,
that of churchmen ; and though they were not always
very
diligent in instructing their pupils, even in the sciences
which
were supposed neccessary for that profession; yet they
gradually
drew to themselves the education of almost all other
people,
particularly of almost all gentlemen and men of fortune.
No
better method, it seems, could be fallen upon, of spending,
with
any advantage, the long interval between infancy and that
period
of life at which men begin to apply in good earnest to the
real
business of the world, the business which is to employ them
during
the remainder of their days. The greater part of what is
taught
in schools and universities, however, does not seem to be
the
most proper preparation for that business.
In
England, it becomes every day more and more the custom to send
young
people to travel in foreign countries immediately upon
their
leaving school, and without sending them to any university.
Our
young people, it is said, generally return home much improved
by
their travels. A young man, who goes abroad at seventeen or
eighteen,
and returns home at one-and-twenty, returns three or
four
years older than he was when he went abroad ; and at that
age it
is very difficult not to improve a good deal in three or
four
years. In the course of his travels, he generally acquires
some
knowledge of one or two foreign languages; a knowledge,
however,
which is seldom sufficient to enable him either to speak
or
write them with propriety. In other respects, he commonly
returns
home more conceited, more unprincipled, more dissipated,
and
more incapable of my serious application, either to study or
to
business, than he could well have become in so short a time
had he
lived at home. By travelling so very young, by spending in
the
most frivolous dissipation the most previous years of his
life,
at a distance from the inspection and controul of his
parents
and relations, every useful habit, which the earlier
parts
of his education might have had some tendency to form in
him,
instead of being riveted and confirmed, is almost
necessarily
either weakened or effaced. Nothing but the discredit
into
which the universities are allowing themselves to fall,
could
ever have brought into repute so very absurd a practice as
that of
travelling at this early period of life. By sending his
son
abroad, a father delivers himself, at least for some time,
from so
disagreeable an object as that of a son unemployed,
neglected,
and going to ruin before his eyes.
Such
have been the effects of some of the modern institutions for
education.
Different
plans and different institutions for education seem to
have
taken place in other ages and nations.
In the
republics of ancient Greece, every free citizen was
instructed,
under the direction of the public magistrate, in
gymnastic
exercises and in music. By gynmastic exercises, it was
intended
to harden his body, to sharpen his courage, and to
prepare
him for the fatigues and dangers of war ; and as the
Greek
militia was, by all accounts, one of the best that ever was
in the
world, this part of their public education must have
answered
completely the purpose for which it was intended. By the
other
part, music, it was proposed, at least by the philosophers
and
historians, who have given us an account of those
institutions,
to humanize the mind, to soften the temper, and to
dispose
it for performing all the social and moral duties of
public
and private life.
In
ancient Rome, the exercises of the Campus Martius answered the
same
purpose as those of the Gymnasium in ancient Greece, and
they
seem to have answered it equally well. But among the Romans
there
was nothing which corresponded to the musical education of
the
Greeks. The morals of the Romans, however, both in private
and
public life, seem to have been, not only equal, but, upon the
whole,
a good deal superior to those of the Greeks. That they
were
superior in private life, we have the express testimony of
Polybius,
and of Dionysius of Halicarnassus, two authors well
acquainted
with both nations; and the whole tenor of the Greek
and
Roman history bears witness to the superiority of the public
morals
of the Romans. The good temper and moderation of
contending
factions seem to be the most essential circumstances
in the
public morals of a free people. But the factions of the
Greeks
were almost always violent and sanguinary ; whereas, till
the
time of the Gracchi, no blood had ever been shed in any Roman
faction;
and from the time of the Gracchi, the Roman republic may
be
considered as in reality dissolved. Notwithstanding,
therefore,
the very respectable authority of Plato, Aristotle,
and
Polybius, and notwithstanding the very ingenious reasons by
which
Mr. Montesquieu endeavours to support that authority, it
seems
probable that the musical education of the Greeks had no
great
effect in mending their morals, since, without any such
education,
those of the Romans were, upon the whole, superior.
The
respect of those ancient sages for the institutions of their
ancestors
had probably disposed them to find much political
wisdom
in what was, perhaps, merely an ancient custom, continued,
without
interruption, from the earliest period of those
societies,
to the times in which they had arrived at a
considerable
degree of refinement. Music and dancing are the
great
amusements of almost all barbarous nations, and the great
accomplishments
which are supposed to fit any man for
entertaining
his society. It is so at this day among the negroes
on the
coast of Africa. It was so among the ancient Celtes, among
the
ancient Scandinavians, and, as we may learn from Homer, among
the
ancient Greeks, in the times preceding the Trojan war. When
the
Greek tribes had formed themselves into little republics, it
was
natural that the study of those accomplishments should for a
long
time make a part of the public and common education of the
people.
The
masters who instructed the young people, either in music or
in
military exercises, do not seem to have been paid, or even
appointed
by the state, either in Rome or even at Athens, the
Greek
republic of whose laws and customs we are the best
informed.
The state required that every free citizen should fit
himself
for defending it in war, and should upon that account,
learn
his military exercises. But it left him to learn them of
such
masters as he could find ; and it seems to have advanced
nothing
for this purpose, but a public field or place of
exercise,
in which he should practise and perform them.
In the
early ages, both of the Greek and Roman republics, the
other
parts of education seem to have consisted in learning to
read,
write, and account, according to the arithmetic of the
times.
These accomplishments the richer citizens seem frequently
to have
acquired at home, by the assistance of some demestic
pedagogue,
who was, generally, either a slave or a freedman ; and
the
poorer citizens in the schools of such masters as made a
trade
of teaching for hire. Such parts of education, however,
were
abandoned altogether to the care of the parents or guardians
of each
individual. It does not appear that the state ever
assumed
any inspection or direction of them. By a law of Solon,
indeed,
the children were acquitted from maintaining those
parents
who had neglected to instruct them in some profitable
trade
or business.
In the
progress of refinement, when philosophy and rhetoric came
into
fashion, the better sort of people used to send their
children
to the schools of philosophers and rhetoricians, in
order
to be instructed in these fashionable sciences. But those
schools
were not supported by the public. They were, for a long
time,
barely tolerated by it. The demand for philosophy and
rhetoric
was, for a long time, so small, that the first professed
teachers
of either could not find constant employment in any one
city,
but were obliged to travel about from place to place. In
this
manner lived Zeno of Elea, Protagoras, Gorgias, Hippias, and
many
others. As the demand increased, the school, both of
philosophy
and rhetoric, became stationary, first in Athens, and
afterwards
in several other cities. The state, however, seems
never
to have encouraged them further. than by assigning to some
of them
a particular place to teach in, which was sometimes done,
too, by
private donors. The state seems to have assigned the
Academy
to Plato, the Lyceum to Aristotle, and the Portico to
Zeno of
Citta, the founder of the Stoics. But Epicurus bequeathed
his
gardens to his own school. Till about the time of Marcus
Antoninus,
however, no teacher appears to have had any salary
from
the public, or to have had any other emoluments, but what
arose
from the honorarius or fees of his scholars. The bounty
which
that philosophical emperor, as we learn from Lucian,
bestowed
upon one of the teachers of philosophy, probably lasted
no
longer than his own life. There was nothing equivalent to the
privileges
of graduation; and to have attended any of those
schools
was not necessary, in order to be permitted to practise
any
particular trade or profession. If the opinion of their own
utility
could not draw scholars to them, the law neither forced
anybody
to go to them, nor rewarded anybody for having gone to
them.
The teachers had no jurisdiction over their pupils, nor any
other
authority besides that natural authority which superior
virtue
and abilities never fail to procure from young people
towards
those who are entrusted with any part of their education.
At
Rome, the study of the civil law made a part of the education,
not of
the greater part of the citizens, but of some particular
families.
The young people, however, who wished to acquire
knowledge
in the law, had no public school to go to, and had no
other
method of studying it, than by frequenting the company of
such of
their relations and friends as were supposed to
understand
it. It is, perhaps, worth while to remark, that though
the
laws of the twelve tables were many of them copied from those
of some
ancient Greek republics, yet law never seems to have
grown
up to be a science in any republic of ancient Greece. In
Rome it
became a science very early, and gave a considerable
degree
of illustration to those citizens who had the reputation
of
understanding it. In the republics of ancient Greece,
particularly
in Athens, the ordinary courts of justice consisted
of
numerous, and therefore disorderly, bodies of people, who
frequently
decided almost at random, or as clamour, faction, and
party-spirit,
happened to determine. The ignominy of an unjust
decision,
when it was to be divided among five hundred, a
thousand,
or fifteen hundred people (for some of their courts
were so
very numerous), could not fall very heavy upon any
individual. At Rome, on the contrary, the principal
courts
of
justice consisted either of a single judge, or of a small
number
of judges, whose characters, especially as they
deliberated
always in public, could not fail to be very much
affected
by any rash or unjust decision. In
doubtful cases such
courts,
from their anxiety to avoid blame, would naturally
endeavour
to shelter themselves under the example or precedent of
the
judges who had sat before them, either in the same or in some
other
court. This attention to practice and precedent,
necessarily
formed the Roman law into that regular and orderly
system
in which it has been delivered down to us ; and the like
attention
has had the like effects upon the laws of every other
country
where such attention has taken place. The superiority of
character
in the Romans over that of the Greeks, so much remarked
by
Polybius and Dionysius of Halicarnassus, was probably more
owing
to the better constitution of their courts of justice, than
to any
of the circumstances to which those authors ascribe it.
The
Romans are said to have been particularly distinguished for
their
superior respect to an oath. But the people who were
accustomed
to make oath only before some diligent and well
informed
court of justice, would naturally be much more attentive
to what
they swore, than they who were accustomed to do the same
thing
before mobbish and disorderly assemblies.
The
abilities, both civil and military, of the Greeks and Romans,
will
readily be allowed to have been at least equal to those of
any
modern nation. Our prejudice is perhaps rather to overrate
them.
But except in what related to military exercises, the state
seems
to have been at no pains to form those great abilities; for
I
cannot be induced to believe that the musical education of the
Greeks
could be of much consequence in forming them. Masters,
however,
had been found, it seems, for instructing the better
sort of
people among those nations, in every art and science in
which
the circumstances of their society rendered it necessary or
convenient
for them to be instructed. The demand for such
instruction
produced, what it always produces, the talent for
giving
it; and the emulation which an unrestrained competition
never
fails to excite, appears to have brought that talent to a
very
high degree of perfection. In the attention which the
ancient
philosophers excited, in the empire which they acquired
over
the opinions and principles of their auditors, in the
faculty
which they possessed of giving a certain tone and
character
to the conduct and conversation of those auditors, they
appear
to have been much superior to any modern teachers. In
modern
times, the diligence of public teachers is more or less
corrupted
by the circumstances which render them more or less
independent
of their success and reputation in their particular
professions. Their salaries, too, put the private
teacher, who
would
pretend to come into competition with them, in the same
state
with a merchant who attempts to trade without a bounty, in
competition
with those who trade with a considerable one. If he
sells
his goods at nearly the same price, he cannot have the same
profit
; and poverty and beggary at least, if not bankruptcy and
ruin,
will infallibly be his lot. If he
attempts to sell
them
much dearer, he is likely to have so few customers, that his
circumstances
will not be much mended. The privileges of
graduation,
besides, are in many countries necessary, or at least
extremely
convenient, to most men of learned professions, that
is, to
the far greater part of those who have occasion for a
learned
education. But those privileges can be
obtained only by
attending
the lectures of the public teachers. The most careful
attendance
upon the ablest instructions of any private teacher
cannot
always give any title to demand them.
It is from these
different
causes that the private teacher of any of the sciences,
which
are commonly taught in universities, is, in modern times,
generally
considered as in the very lowest order of men of
letters.
A man of real abilities can scarce find out a more
humiliating
or a more unprofitable employment to turn them to.
The
endowments of schools and colleges have in this manner not
only
corrupted the diligence of public teachers, but have
rendered
it almost impossible to have any good private ones.
Were
there no public institutions for education, no system, no
science,
would be taught, for which there was not some demand, or
which
the circumstances of the times did not render it either
necessary
or convenient, or at least fashionable to learn. A
private
teacher could never find his account in teaching either
an
exploded and antiquated system of a science acknowledged to be
useful,
or a science universally believed to be a mere useless
and
pedantic heap of sophistry and nonsense.
Such systems,
such
sciences, can subsist nowhere but in those incorporated
societies
for education, whose prosperity and revenue are in a
great
measure independent of their industry. Were there no public
institutions
for education, a gentleman, after going through,
with
application and abilities, the most complete course of
education
which the circumstances of the times were supposed to
afford,
could not come into the world completely ignorant of
everything
which is the common subject of conversation among
gentlemen
and men of the world.
There
are no public institutions for the education of women, and
there
is accordingly nothing useless, absurd, or fantastical, in
the
common course of their education. They are taught what their
parents
or guardians judge it necessary or useful for them to
learn,
and they are taught nothing else. Every part of their
education
tends evidently to some useful purpose ; either to
improve
the natural attractions of their person, or to form their
mind to
reserve, to modesty, to chastity, and to economy ; to
render
them both likely to became the mistresses of a family, and
to behave
properly when they have become such. In every part of
her
life, a woman feels some conveniency or advantage from every
part of
her education. It seldom happens
that a man, in any
part of
his life, derives any conveniency or advantage from some
of the
most laborious and troublesome parts of his education.
Ought
the public, therefore, to give no attention, it may be
asked,
to the education of the people ? Or, if it ought to give
any,
what are the different parts of education which it ought to
attend
to in the different orders of the people? and in what
manner
ought it to attend to them ?
In some
cases, the state of society necessarily places the
greater
part of individuals in such situations as naturally form
in
them, without any attention of government, almost all the
abilities
and virtues which that state requires, or perhaps can
admit
of. In other cases, the state of the society does not place
the
greater part of individuals in such situations; and some
attention
of government is necessary, in order to prevent the
almost
entire corruption and degeneracy of the great body of the
people.
In the
progress of the division of labour, the employment of the
far
greater part of those who live by labour, that is, of the
great
body of the people, comes to be confined to a few very
simple
operations; frequently to one or two. But the
understandings
of the greater part of men are necessarily formed
by
their ordinary employments. The man whose whole life is spent
in
performing a few simple operations, of which the effects, too,
are
perhaps always the same, or very nearly the same, has no
occasion
to exert his understanding, or to exercise his
invention,
in finding out expedients for removing difficulties
which
never occur. He naturally loses, therefore, the habit of
such
exertion, and generally becomes as stupid and ignorant as it
is
possible for a human creature to become. The torpor of his
mind
renders him not only incapable of relishing or bearing a
part in
any rational conversation, but of conceiving any
generous,
noble, or tender sentiment, and consequently of forming
any
just judgment concerning many even of the ordinary duties of
private
life. Of the great and extensive interests of his country
he is
altogether incapable of judging; and unless very particular
pains
have been taken to render him otherwise, he is equally
incapable
of defending his country in war. The uniformity of his
stationary
life naturally corrupts the courage of his mind, and
makes
him regard, with abhorrence, the irregular, uncertain, and
adventurous
life of a soldier. It corrupts even
the activity
of his
body, and renders him incapable of exerting his strength
with
vigour and perseverance in any other employment, than that
to
which he has been bred. His dexterity at his own particular
trade
seems, in this manner, to be acquired at the expense of his
intellectual,
social, and martial virtues. But in every improved
and
civilized society, this is the state into which the labouring
poor, that
is, the great body of the people, must necessarily
fall,
unless government takes some pains to prevent it.
It is
otherwise in the barbarous societies, as they are commonly
called,
of hunters, of shepherds, and even of husbandmen in that
rude
state of husbandry which precedes the improvement of
manufactures,
and the extension of foreign commerce. In such
societies,
the varied occupations of every man oblige every man
to
exert his capacity, and to invent expedients for removing
difficulties
which are continually occurring.
Invention is
kept
alive, and the mind is not suffered to fall into that drowsy
stupidity,
which, in a civilized society, seems to benumb the
understanding
of almost all the inferior ranks of people. In
those
barbarous societies, as they are called, every man, it has
already
been observed, is a warrior. Every man, too, is in some
measure
a statesman, and can form a tolerable judgment concerning
the
interest of the society, and the conduct of those who govern
it. How
far their chiefs are good judges in peace, or good
leaders
in war, is obvious to the observation of almost every
single
man among them. In such a society, indeed, no man can well
acquire
that improved and refined understanding which a few men
sometimes
possess in a more civilized state. Though in a rude
society
there is a good deal of variety in the occupations of
every
individual, there is not a great deal in those of the whole
society.
Every man does, or is capable of doing, almost every
thing
which any other man does, or is capable of being. Every man
has a
considerable degree of knowledge, ingenuity, and invention
but
scarce any man has a great degree. The degree, however, which
is
commonly possessed, is generally sufficient for conducting the
whole
simple business of the society. In a civilized state, on
the
contrary, though there is little variety in the occupations
of the
greater part of individuals, there is an almost infinite
variety
in those of the whole society These varied occupations
present
an almost infinite variety of objects to the
contemplation
of those few, who, being attached to no particular
occupation
themselves, have leisure and inclination to examine
the
occupations of other people. The contemplation of so great a
variety
of objects necessarily exercises their minds in endless
comparisons
and combinations, and renders their understandings,
in an
extraordinary degree, both acute anti comprehensive. Unless
those
few, however, happen to be placed in some very particular
situations,
their great abilities, though honourable to
themselves,
may contribute very little to the good government or
happiness
of their society. Notwithstanding the great abilities
of
those few, all the nobler parts of the human character may be,
in a
great measure, obliterated and extinguished in the great
body of
the people.
The
education of the common people requires, perhaps, in a
civilized
and commercial society, the attention of the public,
more
than that of people of some rank and fortune. People of some
rank
and fortune are generally eighteen or nineteen years of age
before
they enter upon that particular business, profession, or
trade,
by which they propose to distinguish themselves in the
world.
They have, before that, full time to acquire, or at least
to fit
themselves for afterwards acquiring, every accomplishment
which
can recommend them to the public esteem, or render them
worthy
of it. Their parents or guardians are generally
sufficiently
anxious that they should be so accomplished, and are
in most
cases, willing enough to lay out the expense which is
necessary
for that purpose. If they are not always properly
educated,
it is seldom from the want of expense laid out upon
their
education, but from the improper application of that
expense.
It is seldom from the want of masters, but from the
negligence
and incapacity of the masters who are to be had, and
from
the difficulty, or rather from the impossibility, which
there
is, in the present state of things, of finding any better.
The
employments, too, in which people of some rank or fortune
spend
the greater part of their lives, are not, like those of the
common
people, simple and uniform. They are almost all of them
extremely
complicated, and such as exercise the head more than
the
hands. The understandings of those who are engaged in such
employments,
can seldom grow torpid for want of exercise. The
employments
of people of some rank and fortune, besides, are
seldom
such as harass them from morning to night. They generally
have a
good deal of leisure, during which they may perfect
themselves
in every branch, either of useful or ornamental
knowledge,
of which they may have laid the foundation, or for
which
they may have acquired some taste in the earlier part of
life.
It is
otherwise with the common people. They have little time to
spare
for education. Their parents can scarce afford to maintain
them,
even in infancy. As soon as they are able to work, they
must
apply to some trade, by which they can earn their
subsistence.
That trade, too, is generally so simple and uniform,
as to
give little exercise to the understanding; while, at the
same
time, their labour is both so constant and so severe, that
it
leaves them little leisure and less inclination to apply to,
or even
to think of any thing else.
But
though the common people cannot, in any civilized society, be
so well
instructed as people of some rank and fortune; the most
essential
parts of education, however, to read, write, and
account,
can be acquired at so early a period of life, that the
greater
part, even of those who are to be bred to the lowest
occupations,
have time to acquire them before they can be
employed
in those occupations. For a very small expense, the
public
can facilitate, can encourage and can even impose upon
almost
the whole body of the people, the necessity of acquiring
those
most essential parts of education.
The
public can facilitate this acquisition, by establishing in
every
parish or district a little school, where children maybe
taught
for a reward so moderate, that even a common labourer may
afford
it ; the master being partly, but not wholly, paid by the
public
; because, if he was wholly, or even principally, paid by
it, he
would soon learn to neglect his business. In Scotland, the
establishment
of such parish schools has taught almost the whole
common
people to read, and a very great proportion of them to
write
and account. In England, the establishment of charity
schools
has had an effect of the same kind, though not so
universally,
because the establishmnent is not so universal. If,
in
those little schools, the books by which the children are
taught
to read, were a little more instructive than they commonly
are;
and if, instead of a little smattering in Latin, which the
children
of the common people are sometimes taught there, and
which
can scarce ever be of any use to them, they were instructed
in the
elementary parts of geometry and mechanics ; the literary
education
of this rank of people would, perhaps, be as complete
as can
be. There is scarce a common trade, which does not afford
some
opportunities of applying to it the principles of geometry
and
mechanics, and which would not, therefore, gradually exercise
and
improve the common people in those principles, the necessary
introduction
to the most sublime, as well as to the most useful
sciences.
The
public can encourage the acquisition of those most essential
parts
of education, by giving small premiums, and little badges
of distinction,
to the children of the common people who excel in
them.
The
public can impose upon almost the whole body of the people
the
necessity of acquiring the most essential parts of education,
by
obliging every man to undergo an examination or probation in
them,
before he can obtain the freedom in any corporation, or be
allowed
to set up any trade, either in a village or town
corporate.
It was
in this manner, by facilitating the acquisition of their
military
and gymnastic exercises, by encouraging it, and even by
imposing
upon the whole body of the people the necessity of
learning
those exercises, that the Greek and Roman republics
maintained
the martial spirit of their respective citizens. They
facilitated
the acquisition of those exercises, by appointing a
certain
place for learning and practising them, and by granting
to
certain masters the privilege of teaching in that place. Those
masters
do not appear to have had eirher salaries or exclusive
privileges
of any kind. Their reward consisted altogether in what
they
got from their scholars ; and a citizen, who had learnt his
exercises
in the public gymnasia, had no sort of legal advantage
over
one who had learnt them privately, provided the latter had
learned
them equally well. Those republics encouraged the
acquisition
of those exercises, by bestowing little premiums and
badges
of distinction upon those who excelled in them. To have
gained
a prize in the Olympic, Isthmian, or Nemaean games, gave
illustration,
not only to the person who gained it, but to his
whole
family and kindred. The obligation which every citizen was
under,
to serve a certain number of years, if called upon, in the
armies
of the republic, sufficiently imposed the necessity of
learning
those exercises, without which he could not be fit for
that
service.
That in
the progress of improvement, the practice of military
exercises,
unless government takes proper pains to support it,
goes
gradually to decay, and, together with it, the martial
spirit
of the great body of the people, the example of modern
Europe
sufficiently demonstrates. But the security of every
society
must always depend, more or less, upon the martial spirit
of the
great body of the people. In the present times, indeed,
that
martial spirit alone, and unsupported by a well-disciplined
standing
army, would not, perhaps, be sufficient for the defence
and
security of any society. But where every citizen had the
spirit
of a soldier, a smaller standing army would surely be
requisite.
That spirit, besides, would necessarily diminish very
much
the dangers to liberty, whether real or imaginary, which are
commonly
apprehended from a standing army. As it would very much
facilitate
the operations of that army against a foreign invader;
so it
would obstruct them as much, if unfortunately they should
ever be
directed against the constitution of the state.
The
ancient institutions of Greece and Rome seem to have been
much
more effectual for maintaining the martial spirit of the
great
body of the people, than the establishment of what are
called
the militias of modern times. They were much more simple.
When
they were once established, they executed themselves, and it
required
little or no attention from government to maintain them
in the
most perfect vigour. Whereas to maintain, even in
tolerable
execution, the complex regulations of any modern
militia,
requires the continual and painful attention of
government,
without which they are constantly falling into total
neglect
and disuse. The influence, besides, of the ancient
institutions,
was much more universal. By means of them, the
whole
body of the people was completely instructed in the use of
arms ;
whereas it is but a very small part of them who can ever
be so
instructed by the regulations of any modern militia,
except,
perhaps, that of Switzerland. But a coward, a man
incapable
either of defending or of revenging himself, evidently
wants
one of the most essential parts of the character of a man.
He is
as much mutilated and deformed in his mind as another is in
his
body, who is either deprived of some of its most essential
members,
or has lost the use of them. He is evidently the more
wretched
and miserable of the two; because happiness and misery,
which
reside altogether in the mind, must necessarily depend more
upon
the healthful or unhealthful, the mutilated or entire state
of the
mind, than upon that of the body. Even though the martial
spirit
of the people were of no use towards the defence of the
society,
yet, to prevent that sort of mental mutilation,
deformity,
and wretchedness, which cowardice necessarily involves
in it,
from spreading themselves through the great body of the
people,
would still deserve the most serious attention of
government;
in the same manner as it would deserve its most
serious
attention to prevent a leprosy, or any other loathsome
and
offensive disease, though neither mortal nor dangerous, from
spreading
itself among them; though, perhaps, no other public
good
might result from such attention, besides the prevention of
so
great a public evil.
The
same thing may be said of the gross ignorance and stupidity
which,
in a civilized society, seem so frequently to benumb the
understandings
of all the inferior ranks of people. A man without
the
proper use of the intellectual faculties of a man, is, if
possible,
more contemptible than even a coward, and seems to be
mutilated
and deformed in a still more essential part of the
character
of human nature. Though the state was to derive no
advantage
from the instruction of the inferior ranks of people,
it
would still deserve its attention that they should not be
altogether
uninstructed. The state, however, derives no
inconsiderable
advantage from their instruction. The more they
are
instructed, the less liable they are to the delusions of
enthusiasm
and superstition, which, among ignorant nations
frequently
occasion the most dreadful disorders. An instructed
and
intelligent people, besides, are always more decent and
orderly
than an ignorant and stupid one. They feel themselves,
each
individually, more respectable, and more likely to obtain
the
respect of their lawful superiors, and they are, therefore,
more
disposed to respect those superiors. They are more disposed
to
examine, and more capable of seeing through, the interested
complaints
of faction and sedition; and they are, upon that
account,
less apt to be misled into any wanton or unnecessary
opposition
to the measures of government. In free countries,
where
the safety of government depends very much upon the
favourable
judgment which the people may form of its conduct, it
must
surely be of the highest importance, that they should not be
disposed
to judge rashly or capriciously concerning it.
Art.
III. ˜ Of the Expense of the Institutions for the
Instruction
of People of all Ages.
The
institutions for the instruction of people of all ages, are
chiefly
those for religious instruction. This is a species of
instruction,
of which the object is not so much to render the
people
good citizens in this world, as to prepare them for
another
and a better world in the life to come.
The teachers
of the
doctrine which contains this instruction, in the same
manner
as other teachers, may either depend altogether for their
subsistence
upon the voluntary contributions of their hearers; or
they
may derive it from some other fund, to which the law of
their
country may entitle them ; such as a landed estate, a tythe
or land
tax. an established salary or stipend. Their exertion,
their
zeal and industry, are likely to be much greater in the
former
situation than in the latter. In this respect, the
teachers
of a new religion have always had a considerable
advantage
in attacking those ancient and established systems, of
which
the clergy, reposing themselves upon their benefices, had
neglected
to keep up the fervour of faith and devotion in the
great
body of the people; and having given themselves up to
indolence,
were become altogether incapable of making any
vigorous
exertion in defence even of their own establishment. The
clergy
of an established and well endowed religion frequently
become
men of learning and elegance, who possess all the virtues
of
gentlemen, or which can recommend them to the esteem of
gentlemen;
but they are apt gradually to lose the qualities, both
good
and bad, which gave them authority and influence with the
inferior
ranks of people, and which had perhaps been the original
causes
of the success and establishment of their religion. Such a
clergy,
when attacked by a set of popular and bold, though
perhaps
stupid and ignorant enthusiasts, feel themselves as
perfectly
defenceless as the indolent, effeminate, and full fed
nations
of the southern parts of Asia, when they were invaded by
the
active, hardy, and hungry Tartars of the north. Such a
clergy,
upon such an emergency, have commonly no other resource
than to
call upon the civil magistrate to persecute, destroy, or
drive
out their adversaries, as disturbers of the public peace.
It was
thus that the Roman catholic clergy called upon the civil
magistrate
to persecute the protestants, and the church of
England
to persecute the dissenters; and that in general every
religious
sect, when it has once enjoyed, for a century or two,
the
security of a legal establishment, has found itself incapable
of
making any vigorous defence against any new sect which chose
to
attack its doctrine or discipline. Upon such occasions, the
advantage,
in point of learning and good writing, may sometimes
be on
the side of the established church. But the arts of
popularity,
all the arts of gaining proselytes, are constantly on
the
side of its adversaries. In England,
those arts have been
long
neglected by the well endowed clergy of the established
church,
and are at present chiefly cultivated by the dissenters
and by
the methodists. The independent
provisions, however,
which
in many places have been made for dissenting teachers, by
means
of voluntary subscriptions, of trust rights, and other
evasions
of the law, seem very much to have abated the zeal and
activity
of those teachers. They have many of them become very
learned,
ingenious, and respectable men; but they have in general
ceased
to be very popular preachers. The methodists, without half
the
learning of the dissenters, are much more in vogue.
In the
church of Rome the industry and zeal of the inferior
clergy
are kept more alive by the powerful motive of
self-interest,
than perhaps in any established protestant church.
The
parochial clergy derive many of them, a very considerable
part of
their subsistence from the voluntary oblations of the
people;
a source of revenue, which confession gives them many
opportunities
of improving. The mendicant orders derive their
whole
subsistence from such oblations. It is with them as with
the
hussars and light infantry of some armies; no plunder, no
pay.
The parochial clergy are like those teachers whose reward
depends
partly upon their salary, and partly upon the fees or
honoraries
which they get from their pupils ; and these must
always
depend, more or less, upon their industry and reputation.
The
mendicant orders are like those teachers whose subsistence
depends
altogether upon their industry. They
are obliged,
therefore,
to use every art which can animate the devotion of the
common
people. The establishment of the two great mendicant
orders
of St Dominic and St. Francis, it is observed by
Machiavel,
revived, in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries,
the
languishing faith and devotion of the catholic church. In
Roman
catholic countries, the spirit of devotion is supported
altogether
by the monks, and by the poorer parochial clergy. The
great
digititartes of the church, with all the accomplishments of
gentlemen
and men of the world, and sometimes with those of men
of
learning, are careful to maintain the necessary discipline
over
their inferiors, but seldom give themselves any trouble
about
the instruction of the people.
"Most
of the arts and professions in a state," says by far the
most
illustrious philosopher and historian of the present age,
"are
of such a nature, that, while they promote the interests of
the
society, they are also useful or agreeable to some
individuals;
and, in that case, the constant rule of the
magistrate,
except, perhaps, on the first introduction of any
art,
is, to leave the profession to itself, and trust its
encouragement
to the individuals who reap the benefit of it. The
artizans,
finding their profits to rise by the favour of their
customers,
increase, as much as possible, their skill and
industry
; and as matters are not disturbed by any injudicious
tampering,
the commodity is always sure to be at all times nearly
proportioned
to the demand.
"
But there are also some callings which, though useful and even
necessary
in a state, bring no advantage or pleasure to any
individual;
and the supreme power is obliged to alter its conduct
with
regard to the retainers of those professions. It must
give
them public encouragement in order to their subsistence; and
it must
provide against that negligence to which they will
naturally
be subject, either by annexing particular ho0nours to
profession,
by establishing a long subordination of ranks, and a
strict
dependence, or by some other expedient.
The persons
employed
in the finances, fleets, and magistracy, are instances
of this
order of men.
"It
may naturally be thought, at first sight, that the
ecclesiastics
belong to the first class, and that their
encouragement,
as well as that of lawyers and physicians, may
safely
be entrusted to the liberality of individuals, who are
attached
to their doctrines. and who find benefit or consolation
from
their spiritual ministry and assistance. Their industry and
vigilance
will, no doubt, be whetted by such an additional
motive;
and their skill in the profession, as well as their
address
in governing the minds of the people, must receive daily
increase,
from their increasing practice, study, and attention.
"
But if we consider the matter more closely, we shall find that
this
interested diligence of the clergy is what every wise
legislator
will study to prevent ; because, in every religion
except
the true. it is highly pernicious, and it has even a
natural
tendency to pervert the truth, by infusing into it a
strong
mixture of superstition, folly, and delusion. Each
ghostly
practitioner, in order to render himself more precious
and
sacred in the eyes of his retainers, will inspire them with
the
most violent abhorrence of all other sects, and continually
endeavour,
by some novelty, to excite the languid devotion of his
audience.
No regard will be paid to truth, morals, or decency, in
the
doctrines inculcated. Every tenet will be adopted that best
suits
the disorderly affections of the human frame. Customers
will be
drawn to each conventicle by new industry and address, in
practising
on the passions and credulity of the populace. And, in
the
end, the civil magistrate will find that he has dearly paid
for his
intended frugality, in saving a fixed establishment for
the
priests ; and that, in reality, the most decent and
advantageous
composition, which he can make with the spiritual
guides,
is to bribe their indolence, by assigning stated salaries
to
their profession, and rendering it superfluous for them to be
farther
active, than merely to prevent their flock from straying
in
quest of new pastors. And in this manner ecclesiastical
establishments,
though commonly they arose at first from
religious
views, prove in the end advantageous to the political
interests
of society."
But
whatever may have been the good or bad effects of the
independent
provision of the clergy, it has, perhaps, been very
seldom
bestowed upon them from any view to those effects.
Times
of violent religious controversy have generally been times
of
equally violent political faction. Upon such occasions, each
political
party has either found it, or imagined it, for his
interest,
to league itself with some one or other of the
contending
religious sects. But this could be done only by
adopting,
or, at least, by favouring the tenets of that
particular
sect. The sect which had the good
fortune to be
leagued
with the conquering party necessarily shared in the
victory
of its ally, by whose favour and protection it was soon
enabled,
in some degree, to silence and subdue all its
adversaries. Those adversaries had generally leagued
themselves
with the enemies of the conquering party, and were,
therefore
the enemies of that party. The clergy of this
particular
sect having thus become complete masters of the field,
and
their influence and authority with the great body of the
people
being in its highest vigour, they were powerful enough to
overawe
the chiefs and leaders of their own party, and to oblige
the
civil magistrate to respect their opinions and inclinations.
Their
first demand was generally that he should silence and
subdue
all their adversaries; and their second, that he should
bestow
an independent provision on themselves. As they had
generally
contributed a good deal to the victory, it seemed not
unreasonable
that they should have some share in the spoil.
They
were weary, besides, of humouring the people, and of
depending
upon their caprice for a subsistence. In making this
demand,
therefore, they consulted their own ease and comfort,
without
troubling themselves about the effect which it might
have,
in future times, upon the influence and authority of their
order. The civil magistrate, who could comply
with their
demand
only by giving them something which he would have chosen
much
rather to take, or to keep to himself, was seldom very
forward
to grant it. Necessity, however,
always forced him
to
submit at last, though frequently not till after many delays,
evasions,
and affected excuses.
But if
politics had never called in the aid of religion, had the
conquering
party never adopted the tenets of one sect more than
those
of another, when it had gained the victory, it would
probably
have dealt equally and impartially with all the
different
sects, and have allowed every man to choose his own
priest,
and his own religion, as he thought proper. There would,
and, in
this case, no doubt, have been, a great multitude of
religious
sects. Almost every different congregation might
probably
have had a little sect by itself, or have entertained
some
peculiar tenets of its own. Each teacher, would, no doubt,
have
felt himself under the necessity of making the utmost
exertion,
and of using every art, both to preserve and to
increase
the number of his disciples. But as every other teacher
would
have felt himself under the same necessity, the success of
no one
teacher, or sect of teachers, could have been very great.
The
interested and active zeal of religious teachers can be
dangerous
and troublesome only where there is either but one sect
tolerated
in the society, or where the whole of a large society
is
divided into two or three great sects; the teachers of each
acting
by concert, and under a regular discipline and
subordination. But that zeal must be altogether
innocent,
where
the society is divided into two or three hundred, or,
perhaps,
into as many thousand small sects, of which no one could
be
considerable enough to disturb the public tranquillity.
The
teachers of each sect, seeing themselves surrounded on all
sides
with more adversaries than friends, would be obliged to
learn
that candour and moderation which are so seldom to be found
among
the teachers of those great sects, whose tenets, being
supported
by the civil magistrate, are held in veneration by
almost
all the inhabitants of extensive kingdoms and empires, and
who,
therefore, see nothing round them but followers, disciples,
and
humble admirers. The teachers of each little sect, finding
themselves
almost alone, would be obliged to respect those of
almost
every other sect; and the concessions which they would
mutually
find in both convenient and agreeable to make one to
another,
might in time, probably reduce the doctrine of the
greater
part of them to that pure and rational religion, free
from
every mixture of absurdity, imposture, or fanaticism, such
as wise
men have, in all ages of the world, wished to see
established
; but such as positive law has, perhaps, never yet
established,
and probably never will establish in any country ;
because,
with regard to religion, positive law always has been,
and
probably always will be, more or less influenced by popular
superstition
and enthusiasm. This plan of ecclesiastical
government,
or, more properly, of no ecclesiastical government,
was
what the sect called Independents (a sect, no doubt, of very
wild
enthusiasts), proposed to establish in England towards the
end of
the civil war. If it had been established, though of a
very
unphilosophical origin, it would probably, by this time,
have
been productive of the most philosophical good temper and
moderation
with regard to every sort of religious principle. It
has
been established in Pennsylvania, where, though the quakers
happen
to be the most numerous, the law, in reality, favours no
one
sect more than another ; and it is there said to have been
productive
of this philosophical good temper and
moderation,
But
though this equality of treatment should not be productive of
this
good temper and moderation in all, or even in the greater
part of
the religious sects of a particular country; yet,
provided
those sects were sufficiently numerous, and each of them
consequently
too small to disturb the public tranquillity, the
excessive
zeal of each for its particular tenets could not well
be
productive of any very hurtful effects, but, on the contrary,
of
several good ones; and if the government was perfectly
decided,
both to let them all alone, and to oblige them all to
let
alone one another, there is little danger that they would not
of
their own accord, subdivide themselves fast enough, so as soon
to
become sufficiently numerous.
In
every civilized society, in every society where the
distinction
of ranks has once been completely established, there
have
been always two different schemes or systems of morality
current
at the same time; of which the one may be called the
strict
or austere; the other the liberal, or, if you will, the
loose
system. The former is generally admired and revered by the
common
people; the latter is commonly more esteemed and adopted
by what
are called the people of fashion. The degree of
disapprobation
with which we ought to mark the vices of levity,
the
vices which are apt to arise from great prosperity, and from
the
excess of gaiety and good humour, seems to constitute the
principal
distinction between those two opposite schemes or
systems.
In the liberal or loose system, luxury, wanton, and even
disorderly
mirth, the pursuit of pleasure to some degree of
intemperance,
the breach of chastity, at least in one of the two
sexes,
etc. provided they are not accompanied with gross
indecency,
and do not lead to falsehood and injustice, are
generally
treated with a good deal of indulgence, and are easily
either
excused or pardoned altogether. In the austere system, on
the
contrary, those excesses are regarded with the utmost
abhorrence
and detestation. The vices of levity are always
ruinous
to the common people, and a single week's thoughtlessness
and
dissipation is often sufficient to undo a poor workman for
ever,
and to drive him, through despair, upon committing the most
enormous
crimes. The wiser and better sort of the common people,
therefore,
have always the utmost abhorrence and detestation of
such
excesses, which their experience tells them are so
immediately
fatal to people of their condition. The disorder and
extravagance
of several years, on the contrary, will not always
ruin a man
of fashion ; and people of that rank are very apt to
consider
the power of indulging in some degree of excess, as one
of the
advantages of their fortune ; and the liberty of doing so
without
censure or reproach, as one of the privileges which
belong
to their station. In people of their own station,
therefore,
they regard such excesses with but a small degree of
disapprobation,
and censure them either very slightly or not at
all.
Almost
all religious sects have begun among the common people,
from
whom they have generally drawn their earliest, as well as
their
most numerous proselytes. The austere system of morality
has,
accordingly, been adopted by those sects almost constantly,
or with
very few exceptions; for there have been some. It was the
system
by which they could best recommend themselves to that
order
of people, to whom they first proposed their plan of
reformation
upon what had been before established. Many of them,
perhaps
the greater part of them, have even endeavoured to gain
credit
by refining upon this austere system, and by carrying it
to some
degree of folly and extravagance; and this excessive
rigour
has frequently recommended them, more than any thing else,
to the
respect and veneration of the common people.
A man of
rank and fortune is, by his station, the distinguished
member
of a great society, who attend to every part of his
conduct,
and who thereby oblige him to attend to every
part of
it
himself. His authority and consideration depend very much upon
the respect
which this society bears to him. He dares not do
anything
which would disgrace or discredit him in it; and he is
obliged
to a very strict observation of that species of morals,
whether
liberal or austere, which the general consent of this
society
prescribes to persons of his rank and fortune. A man of
low
condition, on the contrary, is far from being a distinguished
member
of any great society. While he remains in a country
village,
his conduct may be attended to, and he may be obliged to
attend
to it himself. In this situation, and in this situation
only,
he may have what is called a character to lose. But as soon
as he
comes into a great city, he is sunk in obscurity and
darkness.
His conduct is observed and attended to by nobody; and
he is,
therefore, very likely to neglect it himself, and to
abandon
himself to every sort of low profligacy and vice. He
never
emerges so effectually from this obscurity, his conduct
never
excites so much the attention of any respectable society,
as by his
becoming the member of a small religious sect. He from
that
moment acquires a degree of consideration which he never had
before.
All his brother sectaries are, for the credit of the
sect,
interested to observe his conduct; and, if he gives
occasion
to any scandal, if he deviates very much from those
austere
morals which they almost always require of one another,
to
punish him by what is always a very severe punishment, even
where
no evil effects attend it, expulsion or excommunication
from
the sect. In little religious sects, accordingly, the morals
of the
common people have been almost always remarkably regular
and
orderly ; generally much more so than in the established
church.
The morals of those little sects, indeed, have frequently
been rather
disagreeably rigorous and unsocial.
There
are two very easy and effectual remedies, however, by whose
joint
operation the state might, without violence, correct
whatever
was unsocial or disagreeably rigorous in the morals of
all the
little sects into which the country was divided.
The
first of those remedies is the study of science and
philosophy,
which the state might render almost universal among
all
people of middling or more than middling rank and fortune ;
not by
giving salaries to teachers in order to make them
negligent
and idle, but by instituting some sort of probation,
even in
the higher and more difficult sciences, to be undergone
by
every person before he was permitted to exercise any liberal
profession,
or before he could be received as a candidate for any
honourable
office, of trust or profit. if the state imposed upon
this
order of men the necessity of learning, it would have no
occasion
to give itself any trouble about providing them with
proper
teachers. They would soon find
better teachers for
themselves,
than any whom the state could provide for them.
Science
is the great antidote to the poison of enthusiasm and
superstition;
and where all the superior ranks of people were
secured
from it, the inferior ranks could not be much exposed to
it.
The
second of those remedies is the frequency and gaiety of
public
diversions. The state, by encouraging, that is, by giving
entire
liberty to all those who, from their own interest, would
attempt,
without scandal or indecency, to amuse and divert the
people
by painting, poetry, music, dancing; by all sorts of
dramatic
representations and exhibitions; would easily dissipate,
in the
greater part of them, that melancholy and gloomy humour
which
is almost always the nurse of popular superstition and
enthusiasm.
Public diversions have always been the objects of
dread
and hatred to all the fanatical promoters of those popular
frenzies.
The gaiety and good humour which those diversions
inspire,
were altogether inconsistent with that temper of mind
which
was fittest for their purpose, or which they could best
work
upon. Dramatic representations, besides, frequently exposing
their
artifices to public ridicule, and sometimes even to public
execration,
were, upon that account, more than all other
diversions,
the objects of their peculiar abhorrence.
In a
country where the law favoured the teachers of no one
religion
more than those of another, it would not be necessary
that
any of them should have any particular or immediate
dependency
upon the sovereign or executive power ; or that he
should
have anything to do either in appointing or in dismissing
them
from their offices. In such a situation, he would have no
occasion
to give himself any concern about them, further than to
keep
the peace among them, in the same manner as among the rest
of his
subjects, that is, to hinder them from persecuting,
abusing,
or oppressing one another. But it
is quite
otherwise
in countries where there is an established or governing
religion. The sovereign can in this case never be
secure,
unless
he has the means of influencing in a considerable degree
the
greater part of the teachers of that religion.
The
clergy of every established church constitute a great
incorporation.
They can act in concert, and pursue their interest
upon
one plan, and with one spirit as much as if they were under
the
direction of one man ; and they are frequently, too, under
such
direction. Their interest as an
incorporated body is
never
the same with that of the sovereign, and is sometimes
directly
opposite to it. Their great interest is to maintain
their
authority with the people, and this authority depends upon
the
supposed certainty and importance of the whole doctrine which
they
inculcate, and upon the supposed necessity of adopting every
part of
it with the most implicit faith, in order to avoid
eternal
misery. Should the sovereign have the imprudence to
appear
either to deride, or doubt himself of the most trifling
part of
their doctrine, or from humanity, attempt to protect
those
who did either the one or the other, the punctilious honour
of a
clergy, who have no sort of dependency upon him, is
immediately
provoked to proscribe him as a profane person, and to
employ
all the terrors of religion, in order to oblige the people
to
transfer their allegiance to some more orthodox and obedient
prince.
Should he oppose any of their pretensions or usurpations,
the
danger is equally great. The princes who have dared in this
manner
to rebel against the church, over and above this crime of
rebellion,
have generally been charged, too, with the additional
crime
of heresy, notwithstanding their solemn protestations of
their
faith, and humble submission to every tenet which she
thought
proper to prescribe to them. But the authority of
religion
is superior to every other authority. The fears which it
suggests
conquer all other fears. When the authorized teachers of
religion
propagate through the great body of the people,
doctrines
subversive of the authority of the sovereign, it is by
violence
only, or by the force of a standing army, that he can
maintain
his authority. Even a standing army cannot in this case
give
him any lasting security ; because if the soldiers are not
foreigners,
which can seldom be the case, but drawn from the
great
body of the people, which must almost always be the case,
they
are likely to be soon corrupted by those very doctrines. The
revolutions
which the turbulence of the Greek clergy was
continually
occasioning at Constantinople, as long as the eastern
empire
subsisted; the convulsions which, during the course of
several
centuries, the turbulence of the Roman clergy was
continually
occasioning in every part of Europe, sufficiently
demonstrate
how precarious and insecure must always be the
situation
of the sovereign, who has no proper means of
influencing
the clergy of the established and governing religion
of his
country.
Articles
of faith, as well as all other spiritual matters, it is
evident
enough, are not within the proper department of a
temporal
sovereign, who, though he may be very well qualified for
protecting,
is seldom supposed to be so for instructing the
people.
With regard to such matters, therefore, his authority can
seldom
be sufficient to counterbalance the united authority of
the
clergy of the established church.
The public
tranquillity,
however, and his own security, may frequently
depend
upon the doctrines which they may think proper to
propagate
concerning such matters. As he can seldom directly
oppose
their decision, therefore, with proper weight and
authority,
it is necessary that he should be able to influence it
; and
he can influence it only by the fears and expectations
which
he may excite in the greater part of the individuals of the
order.
Those fears and expectations may consist in the fear of
deprivation
or other punishment, and in the expectation of
further
preferment.
In all
Christian churches, the benefices of the clergy are a sort
of
freeholds, which they enjoy, not during pleasure, but during
life or
good behaviour. If they held them by
a more
precarious
tenure, and were liable to be turned out upon every
slight
disobligation either of the sovereign or of his ministers,
it
would perhaps be impossible for them to maintain their
authority
with the people, who would then consider them as
mercenary
dependents upon the court, in the sincerity of whose
instructions
they could no longer have any confidence. But should
the
sovereign attempt irregularly, and by violence, to deprive
any
number of clergymen of their freeholds, on account, perhaps,
of
their having propagated, with more than ordinary zeal, some
factious
or seditious doctrine, he would only render, by such
persecution,
both them and their doctrine ten times more popular,
and
therefore ten times more troublesome and dangerous, than they
had
been before. Fear is in almost all cases a wretched
instrument
of govermnent, and ought in particular never to be
employed
against any order of men who have the smallest
pretensions
to independency. To attempt to terrify them, serves
only to
irritate their bad humour, and to confirm them in an
opposition,
which more gentle usage, perhaps, might easily induce
them
either to soften, or to lay aside altogether. The violence
which
the French government usually employed in order to oblige
all
their parliaments, or sovereign courts of justice, to
enregister
any unpopular edict, very seldom succeeded. The means
commonly
employed, however, the imprisonment of all the
refractory
members, one would think, were forcible enough. The
princes
of the house of Stuart sometimes employed the like means
in
order to influence some of the members of the parliament of
England,
and they generally found them equally intractable. The
parliament
of England is now managed in another manner ; and a
very
small experiment, which the duke of Choiseul made, about
twelve
years ago, upon the parliament of Paris, demonstrated
sufficiently
that all the parliaments of France might have been
managed
still more easily in the same manner. That experiment was
not
pursued. For though management and
persuasion are always
the
easiest and safest instruments of government as force and
violence
are the worst and the most dangerous; yet such, it
seems,
is the natural insolence of man, that he almost always
disdains
to use the good instrument, except when he cannot or
dare
not use the bad one. The French government could and durst
use
force, and therefore disdained to use management and
persuasion.
But there is no order of men, it appears I believe,
from
the experience of all ages, upon whom it is so dangerous or
rather
so perfectly ruinous, to employ force and violence, as
upon
the respected clergy of an established church. The
rights,
the privileges, the personal liberty of every individual
ecclesiastic,
who is upon good terms with his own order, are,
even in
the most despotic governments, more respected than those
of any
other person of nearly equal rank and fortune. It is so in
every
gradation of despotism, from that of the gentle and mild
government
of Paris, to that of the violent and furious
government
of Constantinople. But though this order of men can
scarce
ever be forced, they may be managed as easily as any other
; and
the security of the sovereign, as well as the public
tranquillity,
seems to depend very much upon the means which he
has of
managing them ; and those means seem to consist altogether
in the
preferment which he has to bestow upon them.
In the
ancient constitution of the Christian church, the bishop
of each
diocese was elected by the joint votes of the clergy and
of the
people of the episcopal city. The people did not long
retain
their right of election; and while they did retain it,
they
almost always acted under the influence of the clergy, who,
in such
spiritual matters, appeared to be their natural guides.
The
clergy, however, soon grew weary of the trouble of managimg
them,
and found it easier to elect their own bishops themselves.
The
abbot, in the same manner, was elected by the monks of the
monastery,
at least in the greater part of abbacies. All the
inferior
ecclesiastical benefices comprehended within the diocese
were
collated by the bishop, who bestowed them upon such
ecclesiastics
as he thought proper. All church preferments were
in this
manner in the disposal of the church.
The sovereign,
though
he might have some indirect influence in those elections,
and
though it was sometimes usual to ask both his consent to
elect,
and his approbation of the election, yet had no direct or
sufficient
means of managing the clergy. The ambition of every
clergyman
naturally led him to pay court, not so much to his
sovereign
as to his own order, from which only he could expect
preferment.
Through
the greater part of Europe, the pope gradually drew to
himself,
first the collation of almost all bishoprics and
abbacies,
or of what were called consistorial benefices, and
afterwards,
by various machinations and pretences, of the greater
part of
inferior benefices comprehended within each diocese,
little
more being left to the bishop than what was barely
necessary
to give him a decent authority with his own clergy. By
this
arrangement the condition of the sovereign was still worse
than it
had been before. The clergy of all the different
countries
of Europe were thus formed into a sort of spiritual
army,
dispersed in different quarters indeed, but of which all
the
movements and operations could now be directed by one head,
and
conducted upon one uniform plan. The clergy of each
particular
country might be considered as a particular detachment
of that
army, of which the operations could easily be supported
and
seconded by all the other detachments quartered in the
different
countries round about. Each detachment was not only
independent
of the sovereign of the country in which it was
quartered,
and by which it was maintained, but dependent upon a
foreign
sovereign, who could at any time turn its arms against
the
sovereign of that particular country, and support them by the
arms of
all the other detachments.
Those
arms were the most formidable that can well be imagined. In
the
ancient state of Europe, before the establishment of arts and
manufactures,
the wealth of the clergy gave them the same sort of
influence
over the common people which that of the great barons
gave
them over their respective vassals, tenants, and retainers.
In the
great landed estates, which the mistaken piety both of
princes
and private persons had bestowed upon the church,
jurisdictions
were established, of the same kind with those of
the
great barons, and for the same reason. In those great landed
estates,
the clergy, or their bailiffs, could easily keep the
peace,
without the support or assistance either of the king or of
any
other person; and neither the king nor any other person could
keep
the peace there without the support and assistance of the
clergy.
The jurisdictions of the clergy, therefore, in their
particular
baronies or manors, were equally independent, and
equally
exclusive of the authority of the king's courts, as those
of the
great temporal lords. The tenants of the clergy were, like
those
of the great barons, almost all tenants at will, entirely
dependent
upon their immediate lords, and, therefore, liable to
be
called out at pleasure, in order to fight in any quarrel in
which
the clergy might think proper to engage them. Over and
above
the rents of those estates, the clergy possessed in the
tithes
a very large portion of the rents of all the other estates
in
every kingdom of Europe. The revenues arising from both those
species
of rents were, the greater part of them, paid in kind, in
corn,
wine, cattle, poultry, etc. The quantity exceeded greatly
what
the clergy could themselves consume; and there were neither
arts
nor manufactures, for the produce of which they could
exchange
the surplus. The clergy could derive advantage from this
immense
surplus in no other way than by employing it, as the
great
barons employed the like surplus of their revenues, in the
most
profuse hospitality, and in the most extensive charity. Both
the
hospitality and the charity of the ancient clergy,
accordingly,
are said to have been very great. They not only
maintained
almost the whole poor of every kingdom, but many
knights
and gentlemen had frequently no other means of
subsistence
than by travelling about from monastery to monastery,
under
pretence of devotion, but in reality to enjoy the
hospitality
of the clergy. The retainers of some particular
prelates
were often as numerous as those of the greatest
lay-lords
; and the retainers of all the clergy taken together
were,
perhaps, more numerous than those of all the lay-lords.
There
was always much more union among the clergy than among the
lay-lords.
The former were under a regular discipline and
subordination
to the papal authority. The latter were under no
regular
discipline or subordination, but almost always equally
jealous
of one another, and of the king. Though the tenants and
retainers
of the clergy, therefore, had both together been less
numerous
than those of the great lay-lords, and their tenants
were
probably much less numerous, yet their union would have
rendered
them more formidable. The hospitality and charity of the
clergy,
too, not only gave them the command of a great temporal
force,
but increased very much the weight of their spiritual
weapons.
Those virtues procured them the highest respect and
veneration
among all the inferior ranks of people, of whom many
were
constantly, and almost all occasionally, fed by them.
Everything
belonging or related to so popular an order, its
possessions,
its privileges, its doctrines, necessarily appeared
sacred
in the eyes of the common people; and every violation of
them,
whether real or pretended, the highest act of sacrilegious
wickedness
and profaneness. In this state of things, if the
sovereign
frequently found it difficult to resist the confederacy
of a few
of the great nobility, we cannot wonder that he should
find it
still more so to resist the united force of the clergy of
his own
dominions, supported by that of the clergy of all the
neighbouring
dominions. In such circumstances, the wonder is, not
that he
was sometimes obliged to yield, but that he ever was able
to
resist.
The
privileges of the clergy in those ancient times (which to
us, who
live in the present times, appear the most absurd), their
total
exemption from the secular jurisdiction, for example, or
what in
England was called the benefit ofclergy, were the
natural,
or rather the necessary, consequences of this state of
things.
How dangerous must it have been for the sovereign to
attempt
to punish a clergyman for any crime whatever, if his
order
were disposed to protect him, and to represent either the
proof
as insufficient for convicting so holy a man, or the
punishment
as too severe to be inflicted upon one whose person
had
been rendered sacred by religion ? The sovereign could, in
such
circumstances, do no better than leave him to be tried by
the
ecclesiastical courts, who, for the honour of their own
order,
were interested to restrain, as much as possible, every
member
of it from committing enormous crimes, or even from giving
occasion
to such gross scandal as might disgust the minds of the
people.
In the
state in which things were, through the greater part of
Europe,
during the tenth, eleventh, twelfth, and thirteenth
centuries,
and for some time both before and after that period,
the
constitution of the church of Rome may be considered as the
most
formidable combination that ever was formed against the
authority
and security of civil government, as well as against
the
liberty, reason, and happiness of mankind, which can flourish
only
where civil government is able to protect them. In that
constitution,
the grossest delusions of superstition were
supported
in such a manner by the private interests of so great a
number
of people, as put them out of all danger from any assault
of
human reason; because, though human reason might, perhaps,
have
been able to unveil, even to the eyes of the common people,
some of
the delusions of superstition, it could never have
dissolved
the ties of private interest. Had this constitution
been
attacked by no other enemies but the feeble efforts of human
reason,
it must have endured for ever. But that immense and
well-built
fabric, which all the wisdom and virtue of man could
never
have shaken, much less have overturned, was, by the natural
course
of things, first weakened, and afterwards in part
destroyed;
and is now likely, in the course of a few centuries
more,
perhaps, to crumble into ruins altogether.
The
gradual improvements of arts, manufactures, and commerce, the
same
causes which destroyed the power of the great barons,
destroyed,
in the same manner, through the greater part of
Europe,
the whole temporal manufactures, and commerce, the
clergy,
like the great barons, found something for which they
could
exchange their rude produce, and thereby discovered the
means
of spending their whole revenues upon their own persons,
without
giving any considerable share of them to other people.
Their
charity became gradually less extensive, their hospitality
less
liberal, or less profuse. Their retainers became
consequently
less numerous, and, by degrees, dwindled away
altogether.
The clergy, too, like the great barons, wished to get
a
better rent from their landed estates, in order to spend it, in
the
same manner, upon the gratification of their own private
vanity
and folly. But this increase of rent could be got only by
granting
leases to their tenants, who thereby became, in a great
measure,
independent of them. The ties of interest, which bound
the
inferior ranks of people to the clergy, were in this manner
gradually
broken and dissolved. They were even broken and
dissolved
sooner than those which bound the same ranks of people
to the
great barons ; because the benefices of the church being,
the
greater part of them, much smaller than the estates of the
great
barons, the possessor of each benefice was much sooner able
to
spend the whole of its revenue upon his own person. During the
greater
part of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, the power
of the
great barons was, through the greater part of Europe, in
full
vigour. But the temporal power of the clergy, the absolute
command
which they had once had over the great body of the people
was
very much decayed. The power of the church was, by that time,
very
nearly reduced, through the greater part of Europe, to what
arose
from their spiritual authority ; and even that spiritual
authority
was much weakened, when it ceased to he supported by
the
charity and hospitality of the clergy. The inferior ranks of
people
no longer looked upon that order as they had done before;
as the
comforters of their distress, and the relievers of their
indigence.
On the contrary, they were provoked and disgusted by
the
vanity, luxury, and expense of the richer clergy, who
appeared
to spend upon their own pleasures what had always before
been
regarded as the patrimony of the poor.
In this
situation of things, the sovereigns in the different
states
of Europe endeavoured to recover the influence which they
had once
had in the disposal of the great benefices of the
church;
by procuring to the deans and chapters of each diocese
the
restoration of their ancient right of electing the bishop ;
and to
the monks of each abbacy that of electing the abbot. The
re-establishing
this ancient order was the object of several
statutes
enacted in England during the course of the fourteenth
century,
particularly of what is called the statute of provisors
; and
of the pragmatic sanction, established in France in the
fifteenth
century. In order to render the election valid, it was
necessary
that the sovereign should both consent to it before
hand,
and afterwards approve of the person elected; and though
the
election was still supposed to be free, he had, however all
the indirect
means which his situation necessarily afforded him,
of
influencing the clergy in his own dominions. Other
regulations,
of a similar tendency, were established in other
parts
of Europe. But the power of the pope, in the collation of
the
great benefices of the church, seems, before the reformation,
to have
been nowhere so effectually and so universally restrained
as in
France and England. The concordat afterwards, in the
sixteenth
century, gave to the kings of France the absolute right
of
presenting to all the great, or what are called the
consistorial,
benefices of the Gallican church.
Since
the establishment of the pragmatic sanction and of the
concordat,
the clergy of France have in general shewn less
respect
to the decrees of the papal court, than the clergy of any
other
catholic country. In all the disputes which their sovereign
has had
with the pope, they have almost constantly taken part
with
the former. This independency of the clergy of France upon
the
court of Rome seems to be principally founded upon the
pragmatic
sanction and the concordat. In the earlier periods of
the
monarchy, the clergy of France appear to have been as much
devoted
to the pope as those of any other country. When Robert,
the
second prince of the Capetian race, was most unjustly
excommunicated
by the court of Rome, his own servants, it is
said,
threw the victuals which came from his table to the dogs,
and
refused to taste any thing themselves which had been polluted
by the
contact of a person in his situation. They were taught to
do so,
it may very safely be presumed, by the clergy of his own
dominions.
The
claim of collating to the great benefices of the church, a
claim
in defence of which the court of Rome had frequently
shaken,
and sometimes overturned, the thrones of some of the
greatest
sovereigns in Christendom, was in this manner either
restrained
or modified, or given up altogether, in many different
parts
of Europe, even before the time of the reformation. As the
clergy
had now less influence over the people, so the state had
more
influence over the clergy. The clergy, therefore, had both
less
power, and less inclination, to disturb the state.
The
authority of the church of Rome was in this state of
declension,
when the disputes which gave birth to the reformation
began
in Germany, and soon spread themselves through every part
of
Europe. The new doctrines were everywhere received with a high
degree
of popular favour. They were propagated with all that
enthusiastic
zeal which commonly animates the spirit of party,
when it
attacks established authority. The teachers of those
doctrines,
though perhaps, in other respects, not more learned
than
many of the divines who defended the established church,
seem in
general to have been better acquainted with
ecclesiastical
history, and with the origin and progress of that
system
of opinions upon which the authority of the church was
established
; and they had thereby the advantage in almost every
dispute.
The austerity of their manners gave them authority with
the
common people, who contrasted the strict regularity of their
conduct
with the disorderly lives of the greater part of their
own
clergy. They possessed, too, in a much higher degree than
their
adversaries, all the arts of popularity and of gaining
proselytes;
arts which the lofty and dignified sons of the church
had
long neglected, as being to them in a great measure useless.
The
reason of the new doctrines recommended them to some, their
novelty
to many; the hatred and contempt of the established
clergy
to a still greater number: but the zealous, passionate,
and
fanatical, though frequently coarse and rustic eloquence,
with
which they were almost everywhere inculcated, recommended
them to
by far the greatest number.
The
success of the new doctrines was almost everywhere so great,
that
the princes, who at that time happened to be on bad terms
with
the court of Rome, were, by means of them, easily enabled,
in
their own dominions, to overturn the church, which having lost
the
respect and veneration of the inferior ranks of people, could
make
scarce any resistance. The court of Rome had disobliged some
of the
smaller princes in the northern parts of Germany, whom it
had
probably considered as too insignificant to be worth the
managing.
They universally, therefore, established the
reformation
in their own dominions. The tyranny of Christiern
II.,
and of Troll archbishop of Upsal, enabled Gustavus Vasa to
expel
them both from Sweden. The pope favoured the tyrant and the
archbishop,
and Gustavus Vasa found no difficulty in establishing
the
reformation in Sweden. Christiern II. was afterwards deposed
from
the throne of Denmark, where his conduct had rendered him as
odious
as in Sweden. The pope, however, was still disposed to
favour
him; and Frederic of Holstein, who had mounted the throne
in his
stead, revenged himself, by following the example of
Gustavus
Vasa. The magistrates of Berne and Zurich, who had no
particular
quarrel with the pope, established with great ease the
reformation
in their respective cantons, where just before some
of the
clergy had, by an imposture somewhat grosser than
ordinary,
rendered the whole order both odious and contemptible.
In this
critical situation of its affairs the papal court was at
sufficient
pains to cultivate the friendship of the powerful
sovereigns
of France and Spain, of whom the latter was at that
time
emperor of Germany. With their assistance, it was enabled,
though
not without great difficulty, and much bloodshed, either
to
suppress altogether, or to obstruct very much, the progress of
the
reformation in their dominions. It was well enough inclined,
too, to
be complaisant to the king of England. But from the
circumstances
of the times, it could not be so without giving
offence
to a still greater sovereign, Charles V., king of Spain
and
emperor of Germany. Henry VIII., accordingly, though he did
not
embrace himself the greater part of the doctrines of the
reformation,
was yet enabled, by their general prevalence, to
suppress
all the monasteries, and to abolish the authority of the
church
of Rome in his dominions. That he
should go so far,
though
he went no further, gave some satisfaction to the patrons
of the
reformation, who, having got possession of the government
in the
reign of his son and successor completed, without any
difficulty,
the work which Henry VIII. had begun.
In some
countries, as in Scotland, where the government was weak,
unpopular,
and not very firmly established, the reformation was
strong
enough to overturn, not only the church, but the state
likewise,
for attempting to support the church.
Among
the followers of the reformation, dispersed in all the
different
countries of Europe, there was no general tribunal,
which,
like that of the court of Rome, or an oecumenical council,
could
settle all disputes among them, and, with irresistible
authority,
prescribe to all of them the precise limits of
orthodoxy.
When the followers of the reformation in one country,
therefore,
happened to differ from their brethren in another, as
they
had no common judge to appeal to, the dispute could never be
decided;
and many such disputes arose among them.
Those
concerning
the government of the church, and the right of
conferring
ecclesiastical benefices, were perhaps the most
interesting
to the peace and welfare of civil society.
They
gave
birth, accordingly, to the two principal parties or sects
among
the followers of the reformation, the Lutheran and
Calvinistic
sects, the only sects among them, of which the
doctrine
and discipline have ever yet been established by law in
any
part of Europe.
The
followers of Luther, together with what is called the church
of
England, preserved more or less of the episcopal government,
established
subordination among the clergy, gave the sovereign
the
disposal of all the bishoprics, and other consistorial
benefices
within his dominions, and thereby rendered him the real
head of
the church; and without depriving the bishop of the right
of
collating to the smaller benefices within his diocese, they,
even to
those benefices, not only admitted, but favoured the
right
of presentation, both in the sovereign and in all other lay
patrons.
This system of church government was, from the
beginning,
favourable to peace and good order, and to submission
to the
civil sovereign. It has never,
accordingly, been the
occasion
of any tumult or civil commotion in any country in which
it has
once been established. The church of
England, in
particular,
has always valued herself, with great reason, upon
the
unexceptionable loyalty of her principles. Under such a
government,
the clergy naturally endeavour to recommend
themselves
to the sovereign, to the court, and to the nobility
and
gentry of the country, by whose influence they chiefly expect
to
obtain preferment. They pay court to those patrons, sometimes,
no
doubt, by the vilest flattery and assentation ; but
fruquently,
too, by cultivating all those arts which best
deserve,
and which are therefore most likely to gain them, the
esteem
of people of rank and fortune; by their knowledge in all
the
different branches of useful and ornamental learning, by the
decent
liberality of their manners, by the social good humour of
their
conversation, and by their avowed contempt of those absurd
and
hypocritical austerities which fanatics inculcate and pretend
to
practise, in order to draw upon themselves the veneration, and
upon
the greater part of men of rank and fortune, who avow that
they do
not practise them, the abhorrence of the common people.
Such a
clergy, however, while they pay their court in this manner
to the
higher ranks of life, are very apt to neglect altogether
the
means of maintaining their influence and authority with the
lower.
They are listened to, esteemed, and respected by their
superiors;
but before their inferiors they are frequently
incapable
of defending, effectually, and to the conviction of
such
hearers, their own sober and moderate doctrines, against the
most
ignorant enthusiast who chooses to attack them.
The
followers of Zuinglius, or more properly those of Calvin, on
the
contrary, bestowed upon the people of each parish, whenever
the
church became vacant, the right of electing their own pastor;
and
established, at the same time, the most perfect equality
among
the clergy. The former part of this institution, as long as
it
remained in vigour, seems to have been productive of nothing
but
disorder and confusion, and to have tended equally to corrupt
the
morals both of the clergy and of the people. The latter part
seems
never to have had any effects but what were perfectly
agreeable.
As long
as the people of each parish preserved the right of
electing
their own pastors, they acted almost always under the
influence
of the clergy, and generally of the most factious and
fanatical
of the order. The clergy, in order to preserve their
influence
in those popular elections, became, or affected to
become,
many of them, fanatics themselves, encouraged fanaticism
among
the people, and gave the preference almost always to the
most
fanatical candidate. So small a matter as the appointment of
a
parish priest, occasioned almost always a violent contest, not
only in
one parish, but in all the neighbouring parishes who
seldom
failed to take part in the quarrel. When the parish
happened
to be situated in a great city, it divided all the
inhabitants
into two parties; and when that city happened, either
to
constitute itself a little republic, or to be the head and
capital
of a little republic, as in the case with many of the
considerable
cities in Switzerland and Holland, every paltry
dispute
of this kind, over and above exasperating the animosity
of all
their other factions, threatened to leave behind it, both
a new
schism in the church, and a new faction in the state.
In
those small republics, therefore, the magistrate very soon
found
it necessary, for the sake of preserving the public peace,
to
assume to himself the right of presenting to all vacant
benefices. In Scotland, the most extensive country
in which
this
presbyterian form of church government has ever been
established,
the rights of patronage were in effect abolished by
the act
which established presbytery in the beginning of the
reign
of William III. That act, at least, put in the power of
certain
classes of people in each parish to purchase, for a very
small
price, the right of electing their own pastor. The
constitution
which this act established, was allowed to subsist
for
about two-and-twenty years, but was abolished by the 10th of
queen
Anne, ch.12, on account of the confusions and disorders
which
this more popular mode of election had almost everywhere
occasioned.
In so extensive a country as Scotland, however, a
tumult
in a remote parish was not so likely to give disturbance
to
government as in a smaller state. The 10th of queen Anne
restored
the rights of patronage. But though, in Scotland, the
law
gives the benefice, without any exception to the person
presented
by the patron; yet the church requires sometimes (for
she has
not in this respect been very uniform in her decisions) a
certain
concurrence of the people, before she will confer upon
the
presentee what is called the cure of souls, or the
ecclesiastical
jurisdiction in the parish. She sometimes, at
least,
from an affected concern for the peace of the parish,
delays
the settlement till this concurrence can be procured. The
private
tampering of some of the neighbouring clergy, sometimes
to
procure, but more frequently to prevent this concurrence, and
the
popular arts which they cultivate, in order to enable them
upon
such occasions to tamper more effectually, are perhaps the
causes
which principally keep up whatever remains of the old
fanatical
spirit, either in the clergy or in the people of
Scotland.
The
equality which the presbyterian form of church government
establishes
among the clergy, consists, first, in the equality of
authority
or ecclesiastical jurisdiction; and, secondly, in the
equality
of benefice. In all presbyterian churches, the equality
of
authority is perfect; that of benefice is not so. The
difference,
however, between one benefice and another, is seldom
so
considerable, as commonly to tempt the possessor even of the
small
one to pay court to his patron, by the vile arts of
flattery
and assentation, in order to get a better. In all the
presbyterian
churches, where the rights of patronage are
thoroughly
established, it is by nobler and better arts, that the
established
clergy in general endeavour to gain the favour of
their
superiors; by their learning, by the irreproachable
regularity
of their life, and by the faithful and diligent
discharge
of their duty. Their patrons even frequently complain
of the
independency of their spirit, which they are apt to
construe
into ingratitude for past favours, but which, at worse,
perhaps,
is seldom anymore than that indifference which naturally
arises
from the consciousness that no further favours of the kind
are
ever to be expected. There is
scarce, perhaps, to be
found
anywhere in Europe, a more learned, decent, independent,
and
respectable set of men, than the greater part of the
presbyterian
clergy of Holland, Geneva, Switzerland, and
Scotland.
Where
the church benefices are all nearly equal, none of them can
be very
great; and this mediocrity of benefice, though it may be,
no
doubt, carried too far, has, however, some very agreeable
effects. Nothing but exemplary morals can give dignity
to a
man of
small fortune. The vices of levity
and vanity
necessarily
render him ridiculous, and are, besides, almost as
ruinous
to him as they are to the common people. In his own
conduct,
therefore, he is obliged to follow that system of morals
which
the common people respect the most. He gains their esteem
and
affection, by that plan of life which his own interest and
situation
would lead him to follow. The common people look upon
him
with that kindness with which we naturally regard one who
approaches
somewhat to our own condition, but who, we think,
ought
to be in a higher. Their kindness
naturally provokes
his
kindness. He becomes careful to instruct them, and attentive
to
assist and relieve them. He does not even despise the
prejudices
of people who are disposed to be so favourable to him,
and
never treats them with those contemptuous and arrogant airs,
which
we so often meet with in the proud dignitaries of opulent
and
well endowed churches. The presbyterian clergy, accordingly,
have
more influence over the minds of the common people, than
perhaps
the clergy of any other established church. It is,
accordingly,
in presbyterian countries only, that we ever find
the
common people converted, without persecution completely, and
almost
to a man, to the established church.
In
countries where church benefices are, the greater part of
them,
very moderate, a chair in a university is generally a
better
establishment than a church benefice.
The
universities
have, in this case, the picking and chusing of their
members
from all the churchmen of the country, who, in every
country,
constitute by far the most numerous class of men of
letters.
Where church benefices, on the contrary, are many of
them
very considerable, the church naturally draws from the
universities
the greater part of their eminent men of letters;
who
generally find some patron, who does himself honour by
procuring
them church preferment. In the
former situation, we
are
likely to find the universities filled with the most eminent
men of
letters that are to be found in the country. In the
latter,
we are likely to find few eminent men among them, and
those
few among the youngest members of the society, who are
likely,
too, to be drained away from it, before they can have
acquired
experience and knowledge enough to be of much use to it.
It is
observed by Mr. de Voltaire, that father Porée, a jesuit of
no
great eminence in the republic of letters, was the only
professor
they had ever had in France, whose works were worth the
reading.
In a country which has produced so many eminent men of
letters,
it must appear somewhat singular, that scarce one of
them
should have been a professor in a university. The famous
Cassendi
was, in the beginning of his life, a professor in the
university
of Aix. Upon the first dawning of his genius, it was
represented
to him, that by going into the church he could easily
find a
much more quiet and comfortable subsistence, as well as a
better
situation for pursuing his studies; and he immediately
followed
the advice. The observation of Mr.
de Voltaire may
be
applied, I believe, not only to France, but to all other Roman
Catholic
countries. We very rarely find in any of them an eminent
man of
letters, who is a professor in a university, except,
perhaps,
in the professions of law and physic; professions from
which
the church is not so likely to draw them. After the church
of
Rome, that of England is by far the richest and best endowed
church
in Christendom. In England, accordingly, the church is
continually
draining the universities of all their best and
ablest
members; and an old college tutor who is known and
distinguished
in Europe as an eminent man of letters, is as
rarely
to be found there as in any Roman catholic country, In
Geneva,
on the contrary, in the protestant cantons of
Switzerland,
in the protestant countries of Germany, in Holland,
in
Scotland, in Sweden, and Denmark, the most eminent men of
letters
whom those countries have produced, have, not all indeed,
but the
far greater part of them, been professors in
universities.
In those countries, the universities are
continually
draining the church of all its most eminent men of
letters.
It may,
perhaps, be worth while to remark, that, if we except the
poets,
a few orators, and a few historians, the far greater part
of the
other eminent men of letters, both of Greece and Rome,
appear
to have been either public or private teachers; generally
either
of philosophy or of rhetoric. This remark will be
found
to hold true, from the days of Lysias and Isocrates, of
Plato
and Aristotle, down to those of Plutarch and Epictetus,
Suetonius,
and Quintilian. To impose upon any man the necessity
of
teaching, year after year, in any particular branch of science
seems
in reality to be the most effectual method for rendering
him
completely master of it himself. By
being obliged to go
every
year over the same ground, if he is good for any thing, he
necessarily
becomes, in a few years, well acquainted with every
part of
it. and if, upon any particular point, he should form too
hasty
an opinion one year, when he comes, in the course of his
lectures
to reconsider the same subject the year thereafter, he
is very
likely to correct it. As to be a teacher of science is
certainly
the natural employment of a mere man of letters ; so is
it
likewise, perhaps, the education which is most likely to
render
him a man of solid learning and knowledge. The mediocrity
of
church benefices naturally tends to draw the greater part of
men of
letters in the country where it takes place, to the
employment
in which they can be the most useful to the public,
and at
the same time to give them the best education, perhaps,
they
are capable of receiving. It tends to render their learning
both as
solid as possible, and as useful as possible.
The
revenue of every established church, such parts of it
excepted
as may arise from particular lands or manors, is a
branch,
it ought to be observed, of the general revenue of the
state,
which is thus diverted to a purpose very different from
the
defence of the state. The tithe, for example, is a real land.
tax,
which puts it out of the power of the proprietors of land to
contribute
so largely towards the defence of the state as they
otherwise
might be able to do. The rent of land, however, is,
according
to some, the sole fund; and, according to others, the
principal
fund, from which, in all great monarchies, the
exigencies
of the state must be ultimately supplied. The more of
this
fund that is given to the church, the less, it is evident,
can be
spared to the state. It may be laid down as a certain
maxim,
that all other things being supposed equal, the richer the
church,
the poorer must necessarily be, either the sovereign on
the one
hand, or the people on the other; and, in all cases, the
less
able must the state be to defend itself. In several
protestant
countries, particularly in all the protestant cantons
of
Switzerland, the revenue which anciently belonged to the Roman
catholic
church, the tithes and church lands, has been found a
fund
sufficient, not only to afford competent salaries to the
established
clergy, but to defray, with little or no addition,
all the
other expenses of the state. The magistrates of the
powerful
canton of Berne, in particular, have accumulated, out of
the
savings from this fund, a very large sum, supposed to amount
to
several millions; part or which is deposited in a public
treasure,
and part is placed at interest in what are called the
public
funds of the different indebted nations of Europe; chiefly
in
those of France and Great Britain. What may be the amount of
the
whole expense which the church, either of Berne, or of any
other
protestant canton, costs the state, I do not pretend to
know.
By a very exact account it appears, that, in 1755, the
whole
revenue of the clergy of the church of Scotland, including
their
glebe or church lands, and the rent of their manses or
dwelling-houses,
estimated according to a reasonable valuation,
amounted
only to £68,514:1:5 1/12d. This very moderate revenue
affords
a decent subsistence to nine hundred and fortyfour
ministers. The whole expense of the church,
including what is
occasionally
laid out for the building and reparation of
churches,
and of the manses of ministers, cannot well be supposed
to
exceed eighty or eighty-five thousand pounds a-year. The most
opulent
church in Christendom does not maintain better the
uniformity
of faith, the fervour of devotion, the spirit of
order,
regularity, and austere morals, in the great body of the
people,
than this very poorly endowed church of Scotland. All the
good
effects, both civil and religious, which an established
church
can be supposed to produce, are produced by it as
completely
as by any other. The greater part of the protestant
churches
of Switzerland, which, in general, are not better
endowed
than the church of Scotland, produce those effects in a
still
higher degree. In the greater part of the protestant
cantons.
there is not a single person to be found. who does not
profess
himself to be of the established church. If he professes
himself
to be of any other, indeed, the law obliges him to leave
the
canton. But so severe, or, rather, indeed, so oppressive a
law,
could never have been executed in such free countries, had
not the
diligence of the clergy beforehand converted to the
established
church the whole body of the people, with the
exception
of, perhaps, a few individuals only. In some parts of
Switzerland,
accordingly, where, from the accidental union of a
protestant
and Roman catholic country, the conversion has not
been so
complete, both religions are not only tolerated, but
established
by law.
The
proper performance of every service seems to require, that
its pay
or recompence should be, as exactly as possible,
proportioned
to the nature of the service. If any service is very
much
underpaid, it is very apt to suffer by the meanness and
incapacity
of the greater part of those who are employed in it.
If it
is very much overpaid, it is apt to suffer, perhaps still
more,
by their negligence and idleness. A man of a large revenue,
whatever
may be his profession, thinks he ought to live like
other
men of large revenues; and to spend a great part of his
time in
festivity, in vanity, and in dissipation. But in a
clergyman,
this train of life not only consumes the time which
ought
to be employed in the duties of his function, but in the
eyes of
the common people, destroys almost entirely that sanctity
of
character, which can alone enable him to perform those duties
with
proper weight and authority.
PART
IV.
Of the
Expense of supporting the Dignity of the Sovereign.
Over
and above the expenses necessary for enabling the sovereign
to
perform his several duties, a certain expense is requisite for
the
support of his dignity. This expense varies, both with the
different
periods of improvement, and with the different forms of
government.
In an
opulent and improved society, where all the different
orders
of people are growing every day more expensive in their
houses,
in their furniture, in their tables, in their dress, and
in
their equipage; it cannot well be expected that the sovereign
should
alone hold out against the fashion. He naturally,
therefore,
or rather necessarily, becomes more expensive in all
those
different articles too. His dignity even seems to require
that he
should become so.
As, in
point of dignity, a monarch is more raised above his
subjects
than the chief magistrate of any republic is ever
supposed
to be above his fellow-citizens ; so a greater expense
is
necessary for supporting that higher dignity. We naturally
expect
more splendour in the court of a king, than in the
mansion-house
of a doge or burgo-master.
CONCLUSION.
The
expense of defending the society, and that of supporting the
dignity
of the chief magistrate, are both laid out for the
general
benefit of the whole society. It is reasonable,
therefore,
that they should be defrayed by the general
contribution
of the whole society ; all the different members
contributing,
as nearly as possible, in proportion to their
respective
abilities.
The
expense of the administration of justice, too, may no doubt
be
considered as laid out for the benefit of the whole society.
There
is no impropriety, therefore, in its being defrayed by the
general
contribution of the whole society. The persons, however,
who
give occasion to this expense, are those who, by their
injustice
in one way or another, make it necessary to seek
redress
or protection from the courts of justice. The persons,
again,
most immediately benefited by this expense, are those whom
the
courts of justice either restore to their rights, or maintain
in
their rights. The expense of the administration of justice,
therefore,
may very properly be defrayed by the particular
contribution
of one or other, or both, of those two different
sets of
persons, according as different occasions may require,
that
is, by the fees of court. It cannot be necessary to have
recourse
to the general contribution of the whole society, except
for the
conviction of those criminals who have not themselves any
estate
or fund sufficient for paying those fees.
Those
local or provincial expenses, of which the benefit is local
or
provincial (what is laid out, for example, upon the police of
a
particular town or district), ought to be defrayed by a local
or
provincial revenue, and ought to be no burden upon the general
revenue
of the society. It is unjust that the whole society
should
contribute towards an expense, of which the benefit is
confined
to a part of the society.
The
expense of maintaining good roads and communications is, no
doubt,
beneficial to the whole society, and may, therefore,
without
any injustice, be defrayed by the general contributions
of the
whole society. This expense, however, is most immediately
and
directly beneficial to those who travel or carry goods from
one
place to another, and to those who consume such goods. The
turnpike
tolls in England, and the duties called peages in other
countries,
lay it altogether upon those two different sets of
people,
and thereby discharge the general revenue of the society
from a
very considerable burden.
The
expense of the institutions for education and religious
instruction,
is likewise, no doubt, beneficial to the whole
society,
and may, therefore, without injustice, be defrayed by
the
general contribution of the whole society. This expense,
however,
might, perhaps, with equal propriety, and even with some
advantage,
be defrayed altogether by those who receive the
immediate
benefit of such education and instruction, or by the
voluntary
contribution of those who think they have occasion for
either
the one or the other.
When
the institutions, or public works, which are beneficial to
the
whole society, either cannot be maintained altogether, or are
not
maintained altogether, by the contribution of such particular
members
of the society as are most immediately benefited by them
; the
deficiency must, in most cases, be made up by the general
contribution
of the whole society. The general revenue of the
society,
over and above defraying the expense of defending the
society,
and of supporting the dignity of the chief magistrate,
must
make up for the deficiency of many particular branches of
revenue.
The sources of this general or public revenue, I shall
endeavour
to explain in the following chapter.
CHAPTER II.
OF THE
SOURCES OF THE GENERAL OR PUBLIC REVENUE OF THE SOCIETY.
The
revenue which must defray, not only the expense of defending
the
society and of supporting the dignity of the chief
magistrate,
but all the other necessary expenses of government,
for
which the constitution of the state has not provided any
particular
revenue may be drawn, either, first, from some fund
which
peculiarly belongs to the sovereign or commonwealth, and
which
is independent of the revenue of the people ; or, secondly,
from
the revenue of the people.
PART I.
Of the
Funds, or Sources, of Revenue, which may peculiarly belong
to the
Sovereign or Commowealth.
The
funds, or sources, of revenue, which may peculiarly belong to
the
sovereign or commonwealth, must consist, either in stock, or
in land.
The
sovereign, like, any other owner of stock, may derive a
revenue
from it, either by employing it himself, or by lending
it. His
revenue is, in the one case, profit, in the other
interest.
The
revenue of a Tartar or Arabian chief consists in profit. It
arises
principally from the milk and increase of his own herds
and
flocks, of which he himself superintends the management, and
is the
principal shepherd or herdsman of his own horde or tribe.
It is,
however, in this earliest and rudest state of civil
government
only, that profit has ever made the principal part of
the
public revenue of a monarchical state.
Small
republics have sometimes derived a considerable revenue
from
the profit of mercantile projects. The republic of Hamburgh
is said
to do so from the profits of a public wine-cellar and
apothecary's
shop.{See Memoires concernant les Droits et
Impositions
en Europe, tome i. page 73. This work was compiled by
the
order of the court, for the use of a commision employed for
some years
past in considering the proper means for reforming the
finances
of France. The account of the French taxes, which takes
up
three volumes in quarto, may be regarded as perfectly
authentic.
That of those of other European nations was compiled
from such
information as the French ministers at the different
courts
could procure. It is much shorter, and probably not quite
so
exact as that of the French taxes.} That state cannot be very
great,
of which the sovereign has leisure to carry on the trade
of a
wine-merchant or an apothecary. The profit of a public bank
has
been a source of revenue to more considerable states. It
has
been so, not only to Hamhurgh, but to Venice and Amsterdam. A
revenue
of this kind has even by some people been thought not
below
the attention of so great an empire as that of Great
Britain.
Reckoning the ordinary dividend of the bank of England
at five
and a-half per cent., and its capital at ten millions
seven
hundred and eighty thousand pounds, the neat annual profit,
after
paying the expense of management, must amount, it is said,
to five
hundred and ninety-two thousand nine hundred pounds.
Government,
it is pretended, could borrow this capital at three
per
cent. interest, and, by taking the management of the bank
into
its own hands, might make a clear profit of two hundred and
sixty-nine
thousand five hundred pounds a-year. The orderly,
vigilant,
and parsimonious administration of such aristocracies
as
those of Venice and Amsterdam, is extremely proper, it appears
from
experience, for the management of a mercantile project of
this
kind. But whether such a government us that of England,
which,
whatever may be its virtues, has never been famous for
good
economy; which, in time of peace, has generally conducted
itself
with the slothful and negligent profusion that is,
perhaps,
natural to monarchies ; and, in time of war, has
constantly
acted with all the thoughtless extravagance that
democracies
are apt to fall into, could be safely trusted with
the
management of such a project, must at least be a good deal
more
doubtful.
The
post-office is properly a mercantile project. The government
advances
the expense of establishing the different offices, and
of
buying or hiring the necessary horses or carriages, and is
repaid,
with a large profit, by the duties upon what is carried.
It is,
perhaps, the only mercantile project which has been
successfully
managed by, I believe, every sort of government. The
capital
to be advanced is not very considerable. There is no
mystery
in the business. The returns are not only certain but
immediate.
Princes,
however, have frequently engaged in many other
mercantile
projects, and have been willing, like private persons,
to mend
their fortunes, by becoming adventurers in the common
branches
of trade. They have scarce ever succeeded. The profusion
with
which the affairs of princes are always managed, renders it
almost
impossible that they should. The agents of a prince regard
the
wealth of their master as inexhaustible; are careless at what
price
they buy, are careless at what price they sell, are
careless
at what expense they transport his goods from one place
to
another. Those agents frequently live with the profusion of
princes
; and sometimes, too, in spite of that profusion, and by
a
proper method of making up their accounts, acquire the fortunes
of
princes. It was thus, as we are told
by Machiavel, that
the
agents of Lorenzo of Medicis, not a prince of mean abilities,
carried
on his trade. The republic of
Florence was several
times
obliged to pay the debt into which their extravagance had
involved
him. He found it convenient, accordingly to give up the
business
of merchant, the business to which his family had
originally
owed their fortune, and, in the latter part of his
life,
to employ both what remained of that fortune, and the
revenue
of the state, of which he had the disposal, in projects
and
expenses more suitable to his station.
No two
characters seem more inconsistent than those of trader and
sovereign.
If the trading spirit of the English East India
company
renders them very bad sovereigns, the spirit of
sovereignty
seems to have rendered them equally bad traders.
While
they were traders only, they managed their trade
successfully,
and were able to pay from their profits a moderate
dividend
to the proprietors of their stock. Since they became
sovereigns,
with a revenue which, it is said, was originally more
than
three millions sterling, they have been obliged to beg the
ordinary
assistance of government, in order to avoid immediate
bankruptcy.
In their former situation, their servants in India
considered
themselves as the clerks of merchants ; in their
present
situation, those servants consider themselves as the
ministers
of sovereigns.
A state
may sometimes derive some part of its public revenue from
the
interest of money, as well as from the profits of stock. If
it has
amassed a treasure, it may lend a part of that treasure,
either
to foreign states, or to its own subjects.
The
canton of Berne derives a considerable revenue by lending a
part of
its treasure to foreign states, that is, by placing it in
the
public funds of the different indebted nations of Europe,
chiefly
in those of France and England. The security of this
revenue
must depend, first, upon the security of the funds in
which
it is placed, or upon the good faith of the government
which
has the management of them; and, secondly, upon the
certainty
or probability of the continuance of peace with the
debtor
nation. In the case of a war, the very first act of
hostility
on the part of the debtor nation might be the
forfeiture
of the funds of its credit or. This policy of lending
money
to foreign states is, so far as I know peculiar to the
canton
of Berne.
The
city of Hamburgh {See Memoire concernant les Droites et
Impositions
en Europe tome i p. 73.}has established a sort of
public
pawn-shop, which lends money to the subjects of the state,
upon
pledges, at six per cent. interest. This pawn-shop, or
lombard,
as it is called, affords a revenue, it is pretended, to
the
state, of a hundred and fifty thousand crowns, which, at four
and
sixpence the crown, amounts to £33,750 sterling.
The
government of Pennsylvania, without amassing any treasure,
invented
a method of lending, not money, indeed, but what is
equivalent
to money, to its subjects. By advancing to private
people,
at interest, and upon land security to double the value,
paper
bills of credit, to be redeemed fifteen years after their
date ;
and, in the mean time, made transferable from hand to
hand,
like banknotes, and declared by act of assembly to be a
legal
tender in all payments from one inhabitant of the province
to
another, it raised a moderate revenue, which went a
considerable
way towards defraying an annual expense of about
£4,500,
the whole ordinary expense of that frugal and orderly
government. The success of an expedient of this kind
must
have
depended upon three different circumstances: first, upon the
demand
for some other instrument of commerce, besides gold and
silver
money, or upon the demand for such a quantity of
consumable
stock as could not be had without sending abroad the
greater
part of their gold and silver money, in order to purchase
it;
secondly, upon the good credit of the government which made
use of
this expedient ; and, thirdly, upon the moderation with
which
it was used, the whole value of the paper bills of credit
never
exceeding that of the gold and silver money which would
have
been necessary for carrying on their circulation, had there
been no
paper bills of credit. The same expedient was, upon
different
occations, adopted by several other American colonies;
but,
from want of this moderation, it produced, in the greater
part of
them, much more disorder than conveniency.
The
unstable and perishable nature of stock and credit, however,
renders
them unfit to be trusted to as the principal funds of
that
sure, steady, and permanent revenue, which can alone give
security
and dignity to government. The government of no great
nation,
that was advanced beyond the shepherd state, seems ever
to have
derived the greater part of its public revenue from such
sources.
Land is
a fund of more stable and permanent nature ; and the rent
of
public lands, accordingly, has been the principal source of
the
public revenue of many a great nation that was much advanced
beyond
the shepherd state. From the produce or rent of the public
lands,
the ancient republics of Greece and Italy derived for a
long
the the greater part of that revenue which defrayed the
necessary
expenses of the commonwealth. The rent of the crown
lands
constituted for a long time the greater part of the revenue
of the
ancient sovereigns of Europe.
War,
and the preparation for war, are the two circumstances
which,
in modern times, occasion the greater part of the
necessary
expense or all great states. But in
the ancient
republics
of Greece and Italy, every citizen was a soldier, and
both
served, and prepared himself for service, at his own
expense.
Neither of those two circumstances, therefore, cou1d
occasion
any very considerable expense to the state. The rent of
a very
moderate landed estate might be fully sufficient for
defraying
all the other necessary expenses of government.
In the
ancient monarchies of Europe, the manners and customs of
the
time sufficiently prepared the great body of the people for
war;
and when they took the field, they were, by the condition of
their
feudal tenures, to be maintained either at their own
expense,
or at that of their immediate lords, without bringing
any new
charge upon the sovereign. The other expenses of
government
were, the greater part of them, very moderate. The
administration
of justice, it has been shewn, instead of being a
cause
of expense was a source of revenue. The labour of the
country
people, for three days before, and for three days after,
harvest,
was thought a fund sufficient for making and maintaining
all the
bridges, highways, and other public works, which the
commerce
of the country was supposed to require.
In those
days
the principal expense of the sovereign seems to have
consisted
in the maintenance of his own family and household. The
officers
of his household, accordingly, were then the great
officers
of state. The lord treasurer
received his rents.
The
lord steward and lord chamberlain looked after the expense of
his
family. The care of his stables was committed to the lord
constable
and the lord marshal. His houses were all built in the
form of
castles, and seem to have been the principal fortresses
which
he possessed. The keepers of those houses or castles might
be
considered as a sort of military governors. They seem to have
been
the only military officers whom it was necessary to maintain
in time
of peace. In these circumstances, the rent of a great
landed
estate might, upon ordinary occasions, very well defray
all the
necessary expenses of government.
In the
present state of the greater part of the civilized
monarchies
of Europe, the rent of all the lands in the country,
managed
as they probably would be, if they all belonged to one
proprietor,
would scarce, perhaps, amount to the ordinary revenue
which
they levy upon the people even in peaceable times. The
ordinary
revenue of Great Britain, for example, including not
only
what is necessary for defraying the current expense of the
year,
but for paying the interest of the public debts, and for
sinking
a part of the capital of those debts, amounts to upwards
of ten
millions a-year. But the land tax,
at four shillings
in the
pound, falls short of two millions a-year.
This land
tax, as
it is called however, is supposed to be one-fifth, not
only of
the rent of all the land, but of that of all the houses,
and of
the interest of all the capital stock of Great Britain,
that
part of it only excepted which is either lent to the public,
or
employed as farming stock in the cultivation of land. A very
considerable
part of the produce of this tax arises from the rent
of
houses and the interest of capital stock. The land tax of the
city of
London, for example, at four shillings in the pound,
amounts
to £123,399: 6: 7; that of the city of Westminster to
£63,092:
1: 5; that of the palaces of Whitehall and St. James's,
to
£30,754: 6: 3. A certain proportion of
the land tax is, in
the
same manner, assessed upon all the other cities and towns
corporate
in the kingdom ; and arises almost altogether, either
from
the rent of houses, or from what is supposed to be the
interest
of trading and capital stock. According to the
estimation,
therefore, by which Great Britain is rated to the
land
tax, the whole mass of revenue arising from the rent of all
the
lands, from that of all the houses, and from the interest of
all the
capital stock, that part of it only excepted which is
either
lent to the public, or employed in the cultivation of
land,
does not exceed ten millions sterling a-year, the ordinary
revenue
which government levies upon the people, even in
peaceable
times. The estimation by which Great Britain is rated
to the
land tax is, no doubt, taking the whole kingdom at an
average,
very much below the real value ; though in several
particular
counties and districts it is said to be nearly equal
to that
value. The rent of the lands alone, exclusive of that of
houses
and of the interest of stock, has by many people been
estimated
at twenty millions; an estimation made in a great
measure
at random, and which, I apprehend, is as likely to be
above
as below the truth. But if the
lands of Great Britain,
in the
present state of their cultivation, do not afford a rent
of more
than twenty millions a-year, they could not well afford
the
half, most probably not the fourth part of that rent, if they
all
belonged to a single proprietor, and were put under the
negligent,
expensive, and oppressive management of his factors
and
agents. The crown lands of Great Britain do not at present
afford
the fourth part of the rent which could probably be drawn
from
them if they were the property of private persons. If the
crown
lands were more extensive, it is probable, they would be
still
worse managed.
The
revenue which the great body of the people derives from land
is, in
proportion, not to the rent, but to the produce of the
land. The whole annual produce of the land of
every country,
if we
except what is reserved for seed, is either annually
consumed
by the great body of the people, or exchanged for
something
else that is consumed by them. Whatever keeps down the
produce
of the land below what it would otherwise rise to, keeps
down
the revenue of the great body of the people, still more than
it does
that of the proprietors of land. The rent of land, that
portion
of the produce which belongs to the proprietors, is
scarce
anywhere in Great Britain supposed to be more than a third
part of
the whole produce. If the land which, in one state of
cultivation,
affords a revenue of ten millions sterling a-year,
would
in another afford a rent of twenty millions ; the rent
being,
in both cases, supposed a third part of the produce, the
revenue
of the proprietors would be less than it otherwise might
be, by
ten millions a-year only; but the revenue of the great
hotly
of the people would be less than it otherwise might be, by
thirty
millions a-year, deducting only what would be necessary
for
seed. The population of the country would be less by the
number
of people which thirty millions a-year, deducting always
the
seed, could maintain, according to the particular mode of
living,
and expense which might take place in the different ranks
of men,
among whom the remainder was distributed.
Though
there is not at present in Europe, any civilized state of
any
kind which derives the greater part of its public revenue
from
the rent of lands which are the property of the state; yet,
in all
the great monarchies of Europe, there are still many large
tracts
of land which belong to the crown. They are generally
forest,
and sometimes forests where, after travelling several
miles,
you will scarce find a single tree; a mere waste and loss
of
country, in respect both of produce and population. In every
great
monarchy of Europe, the sale of the crown lands would
produce
a very large sum of money, which, if applied to the
payment
of the public debts, would deliver from mortgage a much
greater
revenue than any which those lands have even afforded to
the
crown. In countries where lands, improved and cultivated very
highly,
and yielding, at the time of sale, as great a rent as can
easily
be got from them, commonly sell at thirty years purchase;
the
unimproved, uncultivated, and low-rented crown lands, might
well be
expected to sell at forty, fifty, or sixty years
purchase. The crown might immediately enjoy the
revenue
which
this great price would redeem from mortgage. In the course
of a
few years, it would probably enjoy another revenue. When the
crown
lands had become private property, they would, in the
course
of a few years, become well improved and well cultivated.
The
increase of their produce would increase the population of
the
country, by augmenting the revenue and consumption of the
people.
But the revenue which the crown derives from the duties
or
custom and excise, would necessarily increase with the revenue
and
consumption of the people.
The
revenue which, in any civilized monarchy, the crown derives
from
tlhe crown lands, though it appears to cost nothing to
individuals,
in reality costs more to the society than perhaps
any
other equal revenue which the crown enjoys. It would, in
all
cases, be for the interest of the society, to replace this
revenue
to the crown by some other equal revenue, and to divide
the
lands among the people, which could not well be done better,
perhaps,
than by exposing them to public sale.
Lands,
for the purposes of pleasure and magnificence, parks,
gardens,
public walks, etc. possessions which are everywhere
considered
as causes of expense, not as sources of revenue, seem
to be
the only lands which, in a great and civilized monarchy,
ought
to belong to the crown.
Public
stock and public lands, therefore, the two sources of
revenue
which may peculiarly belong to the sovereign or
commonwealth,
being both improper and insufficient funds for
defraying
the necessary expense of any great and civilized state
; it
remains that this expense must, the greater part of it, be
defrayed
by taxes of one kind or another; the people contributing
a part
of their own private revenue, in order to make up a public
revenue
to the sovereign or commonwealth.
PART II.
Of Taxes.
The
private revenue of individuals, it has been shown in the
first
book of this Inquiry, arises, ultimately from three
different
sources ; rent, profit, and wages.
Every tax must
finally
be paid from some one or other of those three different
sources
of revenue, or from all of them indifferently. I shall
endeavour
to give the best account I can, first, of those taxes
which,
it is intended should fall upon rent; secondly, of those
which,
it is intended should fall upon profit ; thirdly, of those
which,
it is intended should fall upon wages ; and fourthly, of
those
which, it is intended should fall indifferently upon all
those
three different sources of private revenue. The particular
consideration
of each of these four different sorts of taxes will
divide
the second part of the present chapter into four articles,
three
of which will require several other subdivisions. Many of
these
taxes, it will appear from the following review, are not
finally
paid from the fund, or source of revenue, upon which it
is
intended they should fall.
Before
I enter upon the examination of particular taxes,it is
necessary
to premise the four following maximis with regard to
taxes
in general.
1. The
subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the
support
of the government, as nearly as possible, in proportion
to
their respective abilities; that is, in proportion to the
revenue
which they respectively enjoy under the protection of the
state.
The expense of government to the individuals of a great
nation,
is like the expense of management to the joint tenants of
a great
estate, who are all obliged to contribute in proportion
to their
respective interests in the estate. In the obsevation or
neglect
of this maxim, consists what is called the equality or
inequality
of taxation. Every tax, it must be
observed once
for
all, which falls finally upon one only of the three sorts of
revenue
above mentioned, is necessarily unequal, in so far as it
does
not affect the other two. In the following examination of
different
taxes, I shall seldom take much farther notice of this
sort of
inequality; but shall, in most cases, confine my
observations
to that inequality which is occasioned by a
particular
tax falling unequally upon that particular sort of
private
revenue which is affected by it.
2. The
tax which each individual is bound to pay, ought to be
certain
and not arbitrary. The time of payment, the manner of
payment,
the quantity to be paid, ought all to be clear and plain
to the
contributor, and to every other person. Where it is
otherwise,
every person subject to the tax is put more or less in
the
power of the tax-gatherer, who can either aggravate the tax
upon
any obnoxious contributor, or extort, by the terror of such
aggravation,
some present or perquisite to himself. The
uncertainty
of taxation encourages the insolence, and favours the
corruption,
of an order of men who are naturally unpopular, even
where
they are neither insolent nor corrupt. The certainty of
what
each individual ought to pay is, in taxation, a matter of so
great
importance, that a very considerable degree of inequality,
it
appears, I believe, from the experience of all nations, is not
near so
great an evil as a very small degree of uncertainty.
3.
Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in
which
it is most likely to be convenient for the contributor to
pay it.
A tax upon the rent of land or of houses, payable at the
same
term at which such rents are usually paid, is levied at the
time
when it is most likely to be convenient for the contributor
to pay
; or when he is most likely to have wherewithall to pay.
Taxes
upon such consumable goods as are articles of luxury, are
all
finally paid by the consumer, and generally in a manner that
is very
convenient for him. He pays them by little and little, as
he has
occasion to buy the goods. As he is at liberty too, either
to buy
or not to buy, as he pleases, it must be his own fault if
he ever
suffers any considerable inconveniecy from such taxes.
4.
Every tax ought to be so contrived, as both to take out and to
keep
out of the pockets of the people as little as possible, over
and
above what it brings into the public treasury of the state. A
tax may
either take out or keep out of the pockets of the people
a great
deal more than it brings into the public treasury, in the
four
following ways. First, the levying of it may require a great
number
of officers, whose salaries may eat up the greater part of
the
produce of the tax, and whose perquisites may impose another
additional
tax upon the people. Secondly, it may obstruct the
industry
of the people, and discourage them from applying to
certain
branches of business which might give maintenance and
employment
to great multitudes. While it
obliges the people
to pay,
it may thus diminish, or perhaps destroy, some of the
funds
which might enable them more easily to do so. Thirdly, by
the
forfeitures and other penalties which those unfortunate
individuals
incur, who attempt unsuccessfully to evade the tax,
it may
frequently ruin them, and thereby put an end to the
benefit
which the community might have received from the
employment
of their capitals. An injudicious tax offers a great
temptation
to smuggling. But the penalties of
smuggling must
arise
in proportion to the temptation. The law, contrary to all
the
ordinary principles of justice, first creates the temptation,
and
then punishes those who yield to it; and it commonly enhances
the
punishment, too, in proportion to the very circumstance which
ought
certainly to alleviate it, the temptation to commit the
crime.{
See Sketches of the History of Man page 474, and Seq.}
Fourthly,
by subjecting the people to the frequent visits and the
odious
examination of the tax-gatherers, it may expose them to
much
unnecessary trouble, vexation, and oppression ; and though
vexation
is not, strictly speaking, expense, it is certainly
equivalent
to the expense at which every man would be willing to
redeem
himself from it. It is in some one or other of these four
different
ways, that taxes are frequently so much more burdensome
to the
people than they are beneficial to the sovereign.
The
evident justice and utility of the foregoing maxims have
recommended
them, more or less, to the attention of all nations.
All
nations have endeavoured, to the best of their judgment, to
render
their taxes as equal as they could contrive ; as certain,
as
convenient to the contributor, both the time and the mode of
payment,
and in proportion to the revenue which they brought to
the
prince, as little burdensome to the people. The following
short
review of some of the principal taxes which have taken
place
in different ages and countries, will show, that the
endeavours
of all nations have not in this respect
been equally
successful.
ARTICLE I. ˜ Taxes upon Rent ˜ Taxes upon the Rent
of Land.
A tax
upon the rent of land may either be imposed according to a
certain
canon, every district being valued at a curtain rent,
which
valuation is not afterwards to be altered; or it may be
imposed
in such a manner, as to vary with every variation in the
real
rent of the land, and to rise or fall with the improvement
or
declension of its cultivation.
A land
tax which, like that of Great Britain, is assessed upon
each
district according to a certain invariable canon, though it
should
be equal at the time of its first establishment,
necessarily
becomes unequal in process of time, according to the
unequal
degrees of improvement or neglect in the cultivation of
the
different parts of the country. In England, the valuation,
according
to which the different counties and parishes were
assessed
to the land tax by the 4th of William and Mary, was very
unequal
even at its first establishment. This tax, therefore, so
far
offends against the first of the four maxims above mentioned.
It is
perfectly agreeable to the other three. It is perfectly
certain.
The time of payment for the tax, being the same as that
for the
rent, is as convenient as it can be to the contributor.
Though
the landlord is, in all cases, the real contributor, the
tax is
commonly advanced by the tenant, to whom the landlord is
obliged
to allow it in the payment of the rent. This tax is
levied
by a much smaller number of officers than any other which
affords
nearly the same revenue. As the tax upon each district
does
not rise with the rise of the rent, the sovereign does not
share
in the profits of the landlord's improvements. Those
improvements
sometimes contribute, indeed, to the discharge of
the
other landlords of the district. But the aggravation of the
tax,
which this may sometimes occasion upon a particular estate,
is
always so very small, that it never can discourage those
improvements,
nor keep down the produce of the land below what it
would
otherwise rise to. As it has no tendency to diminish the
quantity,
it can have none to raise the price of that produce.
It does
not obstruct the industry of the people; it subjects the
landlord
to no other inconveniency besides the unavoidable one of
paying
the tax.
The
advantage, however, which the land-lord has derived from the
invariable
constancy of the valuation. by which all the lands of
Great
Britain are rated to the land-tax, has been principally
owing
to some circumstances altogether extraneous to the nature
of the
tax
It has
been owing in part, to the great prosperity of almost
every
part of the country, the rents of almost all the estates of
Great
Britain having, since the time when this valuation was
first
established, been continually rising, and scarce any of
them
having fallen. The landlords, therefore, have almost all
gained
the difference between the tax which they would have paid,
according
to the present rent of their estates, and that which
they
actually pay according to the ancient valuation. Had the
state
of the country been different, had rents been gradually
falling
in consequence of the declension of cultivation, the
landlords
would almost all have lost this difference. In the
state
of things which has happened to take place since the
revolution,
the constancy of the valuation has been advantageous
to the
landlord and hurtful to the sovereign. In a different
state
of things it might have been advantageous to the sovereign
and
hurtful to the landlord.
As the
tax is made payable in money, so the valuation of the land
is
expressed in money. Since the establishment of this valuation,
the
value of silver has been pretty uniform, and there has been
no
alteration in the standard of the coin, either as to weight or
fineness.
Had silver risen considerably in its value, as it seems
to have
done in the course of the two centuries which preceded
the
discovery of the mines of America, the constancy of the
valuation
might have proved very oppressive to the landlord. Had
silver
fallen considerably in its value, as it certainly did for
about a
century at least after the discovery of those mines, the
same
constancy of valuation would have reduced very much this
branch
of the revenue of the sovereign. Had any considerable
alteration
been made in the standard of the money, either by
sinking
the same quantity of silver to a lower denomination, or
by
raising it to a higher ; had an ounce of silver, for example,
instead
of being coined into five shillings and two pence, been
coined
either into pieces which bore so low a denomination as two
shillings
and seven pence, or into pieces which bore so high a
one as
ten shillings and four pence, it would, in the one case,
have
hurt the revenue of the proprietor, in the other that of the
sovereign.
In
circumstances, therefore, somewhat different from those which
have
actually taken place, this constancy of valuation might have
been a
very great inconveniency, either to the contributors or to
the
commonwealth. In the course of ages, such circumstances,
however,
must at some time or other happen. But though empires,
like
all the other works of men, have all hitherto proved mortal,
yet
every empire aims at immortality. Every constitution,
therefore,
which it is meant should be as permanent as the empire
itseif,
ought to be convenient, not in certain circumstances
only,
but in all circumstances; or ought to be suited, not to
those
circumstances which are transitory, occasional, or
accidental,
but to those which are necessary, and therefore
always
the same.
A tax
upon the rent of land, which varies with every variation of
the
rent, or which rises and falls according to the improvement
or
neglect of cultivation, is recommended by that sect of men of
letters
in France, who call themselves the economists, as the
most
equitable of all taxes. All taxes, they pretend, fall
ultimately
upon the rent of land, and ought, therefore, to be
imposed
equally upon the fund which must finally pay them. That
all
taxes ought to fall as equally as possible upon the fund
which
must finally pay them, is certainly true. But without
entering
into the disagreeable discussion of the metaphysical
arguments
by which they support their very ingenious theory, it
will
sufficiently appear, from the following review, what are the
taxes
which fall finally upon the rent of the land, and what are
those
which fall finally upon some other fund.
In the
Venetian territory, all the arable lands which are given
in
lease to farmers are taxed at a tenth of the rent. { Memoires
concernant
les Droits, p. 240, 241.} The leases are recorded in a
public
register, which is kept by the officers of revenue in each
province
or district. When the proprietor cultivates his own
lands,
they are valued according to an equitable estimation, and
he is
allowed a deduction of one-fifth of the tax; so that for
such
land he pays only eight instead of ten per cent. of the
supposed
rent.
A
land-tax of this kind is certainly more equal than the land-tax
of
England. It might not, perhaps, be altogether so certain, and
the
assessment of the tax might freqnently occasion a good deal
more
trouble to the landlord. It might, too, be a good deal more
expensive
in the levying.
Such a
system of administration, however, might, perhaps, be
contrived,
as would in a great measure both prevent this
uncertainty,
and moderate this expense.
The
landlord and tenant, for example, might jointly be obliged to
record
their lease in a public register. Proper penalties might
be
enacted against concealing or misrepresenting any of the
conditions;
and if part of those penalties were to be paid to
either
of the two parties who informed against and convicted the
other
of such concealment or misrepresentation, it would
effectually
deter them from combining together in order to
defraud
the public revenue. All the conditions of the lease might
be
sufficiently known from such a record.
Some
landlords, instead of raising the rent, take a fine for the
renewal
of the lease. This practice is, in most cases, the
expedient
of a spendthrift, who, for a sum of ready money sells a
future
revenue of much greater value. It is, in most cases,
therefore,
hurtful to the landlord; it is frequently hurtful to
the
tenant ; and it is always hurtful to the community. It
frequently
takes from the tenant so great a part of his capital,
and
thereby diminishes so much his ability to cultivate the land,
that he
finds it more difficult to pay a small rent than it would
otherwise
have been to pay a great one. Whatever diminishes his
ability
to cultivate, necessarily keeps down, below what it would
otherwise
have been, the most important part of the revenue of
the
community. By rendering the tax upon such fines a good deal
heavier
than upon the ordinary rent, this hurtful practice might
be
discouraged, to the no small advantage of all the different
parties
concerned, of the landlord, of the tenant, of the
sovereign,
and of the whole community.
Some
leases prescribe to the tenant a certain mode of
cultivation,
and a certain succession of crops, during the whole
continuance
of the lease. This condition, which is generally the
effect
of the landlord's conceit of his own superior knowledge (a
conceit
in most cases very ill-founded), ought always to be
considered
as an additional rent, as a rent in service, instead
of a rent
in money. In order to discourage the practice, which is
generally
a foolish one, this species of rent might be valued
rather
high, and consequently taxed somewhat higher than common
money-rents.
Some
landlords, instead of a rent in money, require a rent in
kind,
in corn, cattle, poultry, wine, oil, etc. ; others, again,
require
a rent in service. Such rents are always more hurtful to
the
tenant than beneficial to the landlord. They either take
more,
or keep more out of the pocket of the former, than they put
into
that of the latter. In every country
where they take
place,
the tenants are poor and beggarly, pretty much according
to the
degree in which they take place. By valuing, in the same
manner,
such rents rather high, and consequently taxing them
somewhat
higher than common money-rents, a practice which is
hurtful
to the whole community, might, perhaps, be sufficiently
discouraged.
When
the landlord chose to occupy himself a part of his own
lands,
the rent might be valued according to an equitable
arbitration
of the farmers and landlords in the neighbourhood,
and a
moderate abatement of the tax might be granted to him, in
the
same manner as in the Venetian territory, provided the rent
of the
lands which he occupied did not exceed a certain sum. It
is of
importance that the landlord should be encouraged to
cultivate
a part of his own land. His capital is generally
greater
than that of the tenant, and, with less skill, he can
frequently
raise a greater produce. The landlord can afford to
try
experiments, and is generally disposed to do so. His
unsuccessful
experiments occasion only a moderate loss to
himself.
His successful ones contribute to the improvement and
better
cultivation of the whole country. It
might be of
importance,
however, that the abatement of the tax should
encourage
him to cultivate to a certain extent only. If the
landlords
should, the greater part of them, be tempted to farm
the
whole of their own lands, the country (instead of sober and
industrious
tenants, who are bound by their own interest to
cultivate
as well as their capital and skill will allow them)
would
be filled with idle and profligate bailiffs, whose abusive
management
would soon degrade the cultivation, and reduce the
annual
produce of the land, to the diminution, not only of the
revenue
of their masters, but of the most important part of that
of the
whole society.
Such a
system of administration might, perhaps, free a tax of
this
kind from any degree of uncertainty, which could occasion
either
oppression or inconveniency to the contributor ; and
might,
at the same time, serve to introduce into the common
management
of land such a plan of policy as might contribute a
good
deal to the general improvement and good cultivation of the
country.
The
expense of levying a land-tax, which varied with every
variation
of the rent, would, no doubt, be somewhat greater than
that of
levying one which was always rated according to a fixed
valuation.
Some additional expense would necessarily be incurred,
both by
the different register-offices which it would be proper
to
establish in the different districts of the country, and by
the
different valuations which might occasionally be made of the
lands
which the proprietor chose to occupy himself. The expense
of all
this, however, might be very moderate, and much below what
is
incurred in the levying of many other taxes, which afford a
very
inconsiderable revenue in comparison of what might easily be
drawn
from a tax of this kind.
The
discouragement which a variable land-tax of this kind might
give to
the improvement of land, seems to be the most important
objection
which can be made to it. The landlord would certainly
be less
disposed to improve, when the sovereign, who contributed
nothing
to the expense, was to share in the profit of the
improvement.
Even this objection might, perhaps, be obviated, by
allowing
the landlord, before he began his improvement, to
ascertain,
in conjunction with the officers of revenue, the
actual
value of his lands, according to the equitable arbitration
of a
certain number of landlords and farmers in the
neighbourhood,
equally chosen by both parties: and by rating him,
according
to this valuation, for such a number of years as might
be
fully sufficient for his complete indemnification. To draw the
attention
of the sovereign towards the improvement of the land,
from a
regard to the increase of his own revenue, is one or the
principal
advantages proposed by this species of land-tax. The
term,
therefore, allowed, for the indemnification of the
landlord,
ought not to he a great deal longer than what was
necessary
for that purpose, lest the remoteness of the interest
should
discourage too much this attention. It had better,
however,
be somewhat too long, than in any respect too short. No
incitement
to the attention of the sovereign can ever
counterbalance
the smallest discouragement to that of the
landlord.
The attention of the sovereign can be, at best, but a
very
general and vague consideration of what is likely to
contribute
to the better cultivation of the greater part of his
dominions.
The attention of the landlord is a particular and
minute
consideration of what is likely to be the most
advantageous
application of every inch of ground upon his estate.
The
principal attention of the sovereign ought to be, to
encourage,
by every means in his power, the attention both of the
landlord
and of the farmer, by allowing both to pursue their own
interest
in their own way, and according to their own judgment ;
by
giving to both the most perfect security that they shall enjoy
the
full recompence of their own industry ; and by procuring to
both
the most extensive market for every part of their produce,
in
consequence of establishing the easiest and safest
communications,
both by land and by water, through every part of
his own
dominions, as well as the most unbounded freedom of
exportation
to the dominions of all other princes.
If, by
such a system of administration, a tax of this kind could
be so
managed as to give, not only no discouragement, but, on the
contrary,
some encouragement to the improvement or land, it does
not
appear likely to occasion any other inconveniency to the
landlord,
except always the unavoidable one of being obliged to
pay the
tax.
In all
the variations of the state of the society, in the
improvement
and in the declension of agriculture ; in all the
variations
in the value of silver, and in all those in the
standard
of the coin, a tax of this kind would, of its own
accord,
and without any attention of government, readily suit
itself
to the actual situation of things, and would be equally
just
and equitable in all those different changes. It would,
therefore,
be much more proper to be established as a perpetual
and
unalterable regulation, or as what is called a fudamental law
of the
commonwealth, than any tax which was always to be levied
according
to a certain valuation.
Some
states, instead of the simple and obvious expedient of a
register
of leases, have had recourse to the laborious and
expensive
one of an actual survey and valuation of all the lands
in the
country. They have suspected, probably, that the lessor
and
lessee, in order to defraud the public revenue, might combine
to
conceal the real terms of the lease. Doomsday-book seems to
have
been the result of a very accurate survey of this kind.
In the
ancient dominions of the king of Prussia, the land-tax is
assessed
according to an actual survey and valuation, which is
reviewed
and altered from time to time.{ Memoires concurent les
Droits,
etc. tom, i. p. 114, 115, 116, etc.} According to that
valuation,
the lay proprietors pay from twenty to twenty-five per
cent.
of their revenue; ecclesiastics from forty to forty-five
per
cent. The survey and valuation of Silesia was made by order
of the
present king, it is said, with great accuracy. According
to that
valuation, the lands belonging to the bishop of Breslaw
are
taxed at twenty-five per cent. of their rent. The other
revenues
of the ecclesiastics of both religions at fifty per
cent.
The commanderies of the Teutonic order, and of that of
Malta,
at forty per cent. Lands held by a noble tenure, at
thirty-eight
and one-third per cent. Lands held
by a base
tenure,
at thirty-five and one-third per cent.
The
survey and valuation of Bohemia is said to have been the work
of more
than a hundred years. It was not perfected till after the
peace
of 1748, by the orders of the present empress queen. {
Id.tom
i p.85,84.} The survey of the duchy of Milan, which was
begun
in the time of Charles VI., was not perfected till after
1760 It
is esteemed one of the most accurate that has ever been
made.
The survey of Savoy and Piedmont was executed under the
orders
of the late king of Sardinia. {Id. p. 280, etc. ; also p,
287.
etc. to 316.}
In the
dominions of the king of Prussia, the revenue of the
church
is taxed much higher than that of lay proprietors. The
revenue
of the church is, the greater part of it, a burden upon
the
rent of land. It seldom happens that any part of it is
applied
towards the improvement of land; or is so employed as to
contribute,
in any respect, towards increasing the revenue of the
great
body of the people. His Prussian majesty had probably, upon
that
account, thought it reasonable that it should contribute a
good
deal more towards relieving the exigencies of the state. In
some
countries, the lands of the church are exempted from all
taxes.
In others, they are taxed more lightly than other lands.
In the
duchy of Milan, the lands which the church possessed
before
1575, are rated to the tax at a third only or their value.
In
Silesia, lands held by a noble tenure are taxed three per
cent.
higher than those held by a base tenure. The honours and
privileges
of different kinds annexed to the former, his Prussian
majesty
had probably imagined, would sufficiently compensate to
the
proprietor a small aggravation of the tax; while, at the same
time,
the humiliating inferiority of the latter would be in some
measure
alleviated, by being taxed somewhat more lightly. In
other
countries, the system of taxation, instead of alleviating,
aggravates
this inequality. In the dominions of the king of
Sardinia,
and in those provinces of France which are subject to
what is
called the real or predial taille, the tax falls
altogether
upon the lands held by a base tenure. Those held by a
noble
one are exempted.
A land
tax assessed according to a general survey and valuation,
how
equal soever it may be at first, must, in the course of a
very
moderate period of time, become unequal. To prevent its
becoming
so would require the continual and painful attention of
government
to all the variations in the state and produce of
every
different farm in the country. The governments of Prussia,
of
Bohemia, of Sardinia, and of the duchy of Milan, actually
exert
an attention of this kind ; an attention so unsuitable to
the
nature of government, that it is not likely to be of long
continuance,
and which, if it is continued, will probably, in the
long-run,
occasion much more trouble and vexation than it can
possibly
bring relief to the contributors.
In
1666, the generality of Montauban was assessed to the real or
predial
taille, according, it is said, to a very exact survey and
valuation.
{ Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. tom. ii p. 139,
etc.}
By 1727, this assessment had become altogether unequal. In
order
to remedy this inconveniency, government has found no
better
expedient, than to impose upon the whole generality an
additional
tax of a hundred and twenty thousand livres. This
additional
tax is rated upon all the different districts subject
to the
taille according to the old assessment. But it is levied
only
upon those which, in the actual state of things, are by that
assessment
under-taxed ; and it is applied to the relief of those
which,
by the same assessment, are over-taxed. Two districts, for
example,
one of which ought, in the actual state of things, to be
taxed
at nine hundred, the other at eleven hundred livres, are,
by the
old assessment, both taxed at a thousand livres. Both
these
districts are, by the additional tax, rated at eleven
hundred
livres each. But this additional tax is levied only upon
the
district under-charged, and it is applied altogether to the
relief
of that overcharged, which consequently pays only nine
hundred
livres. The government neither gains nor loses by the
additional
tax, which is applied altogether to remedy the
inequalities
arising from the old assessment. The
application
is
pretty much regulated according to the discretion of the
intendant
of the generality, and must, therefore, be in a great
measure
arbitrary.
Taxes which are proportioned, not in the
Rent, but to the
Produce
of Land.
Taxes upon the produce of land are, In
reality, taxes upon
the
rent ; and though they may be originally advanced by the
farmer,
are finally paid by the landlord. When a certain portion
of the
produce is to be paid away for a tax, the farmer computes
as well
as he can, what the value of this portion is, one year
with
another, likely to amount to, and he makes a proportionable
abatement
in the rent which he agrees to pay to the landlord.
There
is no farmer who does not compute beforehand what the
church
tythe, which is a land tax of this kind, is, one year with
another,
likely to amount to.
The
tythe, and every other land tax of this kind, under the
appearance
of perfect equality, are very unequal taxes; a certain
portion
of the produce being in differrent situations, equivalent
to a
very different portion of the rent.
In some very rich
lands,
the produce is so great, that the one half of it is fully
sufficient
to replace to the farmer his capital employed in
cultivation,
together with the ordinary profits of farming stock
in the
neighbourhood. The other half, or,
what comes to the
same
thing, the value of the other half, he could afford to pay
as rent
to the landlord, if there was no tythe. But if a tenth of
the
produce is taken from him in the way of tythe, he must
require
an abatement of the fifth part of his rent, otherwise he
cannot
get back his capital with the ordinary profit. In
this
case, the rent of the landlord, instead of amounting to a
half,
or five-tenths of the whole produce, will amount only to
four-tenths
of it. In poorer lands, on the contrary, the produce
is
sometimes so small, and the expense of cultivation so great,
that it
requires four-fifths of the whole produce, to replace to
the
farmer his capital with the ordinary profit. In this
case,
though there was no tythe, the rent of the landlord could
amount
to no more than one-fifth or two-tenths of the whole
produce. But if the farmer pays one-tenth of the
produce in
the way
of tythe, he must require an equal abatement of the rent
of the
landlord, which will thus be reduced to one-tenth only of
the
whole produce. Upon the rent of rich lands the tythe may
sometimes
be a tax of no more than one-fifth part, or four
shillings
in the pound ; whereas upon that of poorer lands, it
may
sometimes be a tax of one half, or of ten shillings in the
pound.
The
tythe, as it is frequently a very unequal tax upon the rent,
so it
is always a great discouragement, both to the improvements
of the
landlord, and to the cultivation of the farmer. The one
cannot
venture to make the most important, which are generally
the
most expensive improvements; nor the other to raise the most
valuable,
which are generally, too, the most expensive crops;
when
the church, which lays out no part of the expense, is to
share
so very largely in the profit. The cultivation of madder
was,
for a long time, confined by the tythe to the United
Provinces,
which, being presbyterian countries, and upon that
account
exempted from this destructive tax, enjoyed a sort of
monopoly
of that useful dyeing drug against the
rest of Europe.
The
late attempts to introduce the culture of this plant into
England,
have been made only in consequence of the statute, which
enacted
that five shillings an acre should be received in lieu of
all
manner of tythe upon madder.
As
through the greater part of Europe, the church, so in many
different
countries of Asia, the state, is principally supported
by a
land tax, proportioned not to the rent, but to the produce
of the
land. In China, the principal revenue of the sovereign
consists
in a tenth part of the produce of all the lands of the
empire.
This tenth part, however, is estimated so very
moderately,
that, in many provinces, it is said not to exceed a
thirtieth
part of the ordinary produce. The land tax or land rent
which
used to be paid to the Mahometan government of Bengal,
before
that country fell into the hands of the English East India
company,
is said to have amounted to about a fifth part of the
produce.
The land tax of ancient Egypt is said likewise to have
amounted
to a fifth part.
In
Asia, this sort of land tax is said to interest the sovereign
in the
improvement and cultivation of land. The sovereigns
of
China, those of Bengal while under the Mahometan govermnent,
and
those of ancient Egypt, are said, accordingly, to have been
extremely
attentive to the making and maintaining of good roads
and
navigable canals, in order to increase, as much as possible,
both
the quantity and value of every part of the produce of the
land,
by procuring to every part of it the most extensive market
which
their own dominions could afford. The tythe of the church
is
divided into such small portions that no one of its
proprietors
can have any interest of this kind. The parson of a
parish
could never find his account. in making a road or canal to
a
distant part of the country, in order to extend the market for
the
produce of his own particular parish. Such taxes, when
destined
for the maintenance of the state, have some advantages,
which
may serve in some measure to balance their inconveniency.
When
destined for the maintenance of the church, they are
attended
with nothing but inconveniency.
Taxes
upon the produce of land may be levied, either in kind, or,
according
to a certain valuation in money.
The
parson of a parish, or a gentleman of small fortune who lives
upon
his estate, may sometimes, perhaps find some advantage in
receiving,
the one his tythe, and the other his rent, in kind.
The
quantity to be collected, and the district within which it is
to be
collected, are so small, that they both can oversee, with
their
own eyes, the collection and disposal of every part of what
is due
to them. A gentleman of great fortune, who lived in the
capital,
would be in danger of suffering much by the neglect, and
more by
the fraud, of his factors and agents, if the rents of an
estate
in a distant province were to be paid to him in this
manner.
The loss of the sovereign, from the abuse and depredation
of his
tax-gatherers, would necessarily be much greater. The
servants
of the most careless private person are, perhaps, more
under
the eye of their master than those of the most careful
prince;
and a public revenue, which was paid in kind, would
suffer
so much from the mismanagement of the collectors, that a
very
small part of what was levied upon the people would ever
arrive
at the treasury of the prince. Some part of the public
revenue
of China, however, is said to be paid in this manner. The
mandarins
and other tax-gatherers will, no doubt, find their
advantage
in continuing the practice of a payment, which is so
much
more liable to abuse than any payment in money.
A tax
upon the produce of land, which is levied in money, may be
levied,
either according to a valuation, which varies with all
the
variations of the market price ; or according to a fixed
valuation,
a bushel of wheat, for example, being always valued at
one and
the same money price, whatever may be the state of the
market.
The produce of a tax levied in the former way will vary
only
according to the variations in the real produce of the land,
according
to the improvement or neglect of cultivation. The
produce
of a tax levied in the latter way will vary, not only
according
to the variations in the produce of the land, but
according
both to those in the value of the precious metals, and
those
in the quantity of those metals which is at different times
contained
in coin of the same denomination. The produce of the
former
will always bear the same proportion to the value of the
real
produce of the land. The produce of the latter may, at
different
times, bear very different proportions to that value.
When,
instead either of a certain portion of the produce of land,
or of
the price of a certain portion, a certain sum of money is
to be
paid in full compensation for all tax or tythe; the tax
becomes,
in this case, exactly of the same nature with the land
tax of
England. It neither rises nor falls with the rent of the
land.
It neither encourages nor discourages improvement. The
tythe
in the greater part of those parishes which pay what is
called
a modus, in lieu of all other tythe is a tax of this kind.
During
the Mahometan government of Bengal, instead of the payment
in kind
of the fifth part of the produce, a modus, and, it is
said, a
very moderate one, was established in the greater part of
the
districts or zemindaries of the country. Some of the servants
of the
East India company, under pretence of restoring the public
revenue
to its proper value, have, in some provinces, exchanged
this
modus for a payment in kind. Under
their management,
this
change is likely both to discourage cultivation, and to give
new
opportunities for abuse in the collection of the public
revenue,
which has fallen very much below what it was said to
have
been when it first fell under the management of the company.
The
servants of the company may, perhaps, have profited by the
change,
but at the expense, it is probable, both of their masters
and of
the country.
Taxes
upon the Rent of Houses.
The
rent of a house may be distinguished into two parts, of which
the one
may very properly be called the building-rent; the other
is
commonly called the ground-rent.
The
building-rent is the interest or profit of the capital
expended
in building the house. In order to put the trade of a
builder
upon a level with other trades, it is necessary that this
rent
should be sufficient, first, to pay him the same interest
which
he would have got for his capital, if he had lent it upon
good
security ; and, secondly, to keep the house in constant
repair,
or, what comes to the same thing, to replace, within a
certain
term of years, the capital which had been employed in
building
it. The building-rent, or the
ordinary profit of
building,
is, therefore, everywhere regulated by the ordinary
interest
of money. Where the market rate of interest is four per
cent.
the rent of a house, which, over and above paying the
ground-rent,
affords six or six and a-half per cent. upon the
whole
expense of building, may, perhaps, afford a sufficient
profit
to the builder. Where the market rate of interest is five
per
cent. it may perhaps require seven or seven and a half per
cent.
If, in proportion to the interest of money, the trade of
the
builders affords at any time much greater profit than this,
it will
soon draw so much capital from other trades as will
reduce
the profit to its proper level. If it affords at any time
much
less than this, other trades will soon draw so much capital
from it
as will again raise that profit.
Whatever
part of the whole rent of a house is over and above what
is
sufficient for affording this reasonable profit, naturally
goes to
the ground-rent; and, where the owner of the ground and
the
owner of the building are two different persons, is, in most
cases,
completely paid to the former. This surplus rent is the
price
which the inhabitant of the house pays for some real or
supposed
advantage of the situation. In country houses, at a
distance
from any great town, where there is plenty of ground to
chuse
upon, the ground-rent is scarce anything, or no more than
what
the ground which the house stands upon would pay, if
employed
in agriculture. In country villas, in the neighbourhood
of some
great town, it is sometimes a good deal higher; and the
peculiar
conveniency or beauty of situation is there frequently
very
well paid for. Ground-rents are generally highest in the
capital,
and in those particular parts of it where there happens
to be
the greatest demand for houses, whatever be the reason of
that
demand, whether for trade and business, for pleasure and
society,
or for mere vanity and fashion.
A tax
upon house-rent, payable by the tenant, and proportioned to
the
whole rent of each house, could not, for any considerable
time at
least, affect the building-rent. If the builder did not
get his
reasonable profit, he would be obliged to quit the trade;
which,
by raising the demand for building, would, in a short
time,
bring back his profit to its proper level with that of
other
trades. Neither would such a tax fall altogether upon the
ground-rent;
but it would divide itself in such a manner, as to
fall
partly upon the inhabitant of the house. and partly upon the
owner
of the ground.
Let us
suppose, for example, that a particular person judges that
he can
afford for house-rent all expense of sixty pounds a-year;
and let
us suppose, too, that a tax of four shillings in the
pound,
or of one-fifth, payable by the inhabitant, is laid upon
house-rent.
A house of sixty pounds rent will, in that case, cost
him
seventy-two pounds a-year, which is twelve pounds more than
he
thinks he can afford. He will, therefore, content himself with
a worse
house, or a house of fifty pounds rent, which, with the
additional
ten pounds that he must pay for the tax, will make up
the sum
of sixty pounds a-year, the expense which he judges he
can
afford, and, in order to pay the tax, he will give up a part
of the
additional conveniency which he might have had from a
house
of ten pounds a-year more rent. He will give up, I say, a
part of
this additional conveniency; for he will seldom be
obliged
to give up the whole, but will, in consequence of the
tax,
get a better house for fifty pounds a-year, than he could
have
got if there had been no tax for as a tax of this kind, by
taking
away this particular competitor, must diminish the
competition
for houses of sixty pounds rent, so it must likewise
diminish
it for those of fifty pounds rent, and in the same
manner
for those of all other rents, except the lowest rent, for
which
it would for some time increase the competition. But
the
rents of every class of houses for which the competition was
diminished,
would necessarily be more or less reduced. As no part
of this
reduction, however, could for any considerable time at
least,
affect the building-rent, the whole of it must, in the
long-run,
necessarily fall upon the ground-rent. The final
payment
of this tax, therefore, would fall partly upon the
inhabitant
of the house, who, in order to pay his share, would be
obliged
to give up a part of his conveniency ; and partly upon
the
owner of the ground, who, in order to pay his share, would be
obliged
to give up a part of his revenue. In what proportion this
final
payment would be divided between them, it is not, perhaps,
very
easy to ascertain. The division would probably be very
different
in different circumstances, and a tax of this kind
might,
according to those different circumstances, affect very
unequally,
both the inhabitant of the house and the owner of the
ground.
The
inequality with which a tax of this kind might fall upon the
owners
of different ground-rents, would arise altogether from the
accidental
inequality of this division. But the
inequality
with
which it might fall upon the inhabitants of different
houses,
would arise, not only from this, but from another cause.
The
proportion of the expense of house-rent to the whole expense
of
living, is different in the different degrees of fortune. It
is,
perhaps, highest in the highest degree, and it diminishes
gradually
through the inferior degrees, so as in general to be
lowest
in the lowest degree. The necessaries of life occasion the
great
expense of the poor. They find it difficult to get food,
and the
greater part of their little revenue is spent in getting
it. The luxuries and vanities of life occasion
the principal
expense
of the rich ; and a magnificent house embellishes and
sets
off to the best advantage all the other luxuries and
vanities
which they possess. A tax upon house-rents, therefore,
would
in general fall heaviest upon the rich ; and in this sort
of
inequality there would not, perhaps, be any thing very
unreasonable It is not very unreasonable that the rich
should
contribute
to the public expense, not only in proportion to their
revenue,
but something more than in that proportion.
The
rent of houses, though it in some respects resembles the rent
of
land, is in one respect essentially different from it. The
rent of
land is paid for the use of a productive subject. The
land
which pays it produces it. The rent of houses is paid for
the use
of an unproductive subject. Neither the house, nor the
ground
which it stands upon, produce anything. The person who
pays
the rent, therefore, must draw it from some other source of
revenue,
distinct from and independent of this subject. A tax
upon
the rent of houses, so far as it falls upon the inhabitants,
must be
drawn from the same source as the rent itself, and must
be paid
from their revenue, whether derived from the wages of
labour,
the profits of stock, or the rent of land. So far as it
falls
upon the inhabitants, it is one of those taxes which fall,
not
upon one only, but indifferently upon all the three different
sources
of revenue ; and is, in every respect, of the same nature
as a
tax upon any other sort of consumable commodities. In
general,
there is not perhaps, any one article of expense or
consumption
by which the liberality or narrowness of a man's
whole
expense can be better judged of than by his house-rent. A
proportional
tax upon this particular article of expense might,
perhaps,
produce a more considerable revenue than any which has
hitherto
been drawn from it in any part of Europe. If the tax,
indeed,
was very high, the greater part of people would endeavour
to
evade it as much as they could, by contenting themselves with
smaller
houses, and by turning the greater part of their expense
into
some other channel.
The
rent of houses might easily be ascertained with sufficient
accuracy,
by a policy of the same kind with that which would be
necesary
for ascertaining the ordinary rent of land. Houses not
inhabited
ought to pay no tax. A tax upon them would fall
altogether
upon the proprietor, who would thus be taxed for a
subject
which afforded him neither conveniency nor revenue.
Houses
inhabited by the proprietor ought to be rated, not
according
to the expense which they might have cost in building,
but
according to the rent which an equitable arbitration might
judge
them likely to bring if leased to a tenant. If rated
according
to the expense which they might have cost in building,
a tax
of three or four shillings in the pound, joined with other
taxes,
would ruin almost all the rich and great families of this,
and, I
believe, of every other civilized country. Whoever will
examine
with attention the different town and country houses of
some of
the richest and greatest families in this country, will
find
that, at the rate of only six and a-half, or seven per cent.
upon
the original expense of building, their house-rent is nearly
equal
to the whole neat rent of their estates. It is the
accumulated
expense of several successive generations, laid out
upon
objects of great beauty and magnificence, indeed, but, in
proportion
to what they cost, of very small exchangeable value.{
Since
the first publication of this book, a tax nearly upon the
above-mentioned
principles thas been imposed.}
Ground-rents
are a still more proper subject of taxation than the
rent of
houses. A tax upon ground-rents would not raise the rent
of
houses; it would fall altogether upon the owner of the
ground-rent,
who acts always as a monopolist, and exacts the
greatest
rent which can be got for the use of his ground. More or
less
can be got for it, according as the competitors happen to be
richer
or poorer, or can afford to gratify their fancy for a
particular
spot of ground at a greater or smaller expense.
In
every country, the greatest number of rich competitors is in
the
capital, and it is there accordingly that the highest
ground-rents
are always to be found. As the wealth of those
competitors
would in no respect be increased by a tax upon
ground-rents,
they would not probably be disposed to pay more for
the use
of the ground. Whether the tax was to be advanced by the
inhabitant
or by the owner of the ground, would be of little
importance.
The more the inhabitant was obliged to pay for the
tax,
the less he would incline to pay for the ground ; so that
the
final payment of the tax would fall altogether upon the owner
of the
ground-rent. The ground-rents of uninhabited houses ought
to pay
no tax.
Both
ground-rents, and the ordinary rent of land, are a species
of
revenue which the owner, in many cases, enjoys without any
care or
attention of his own. Though a part
of this revenue
should
be taken from him in order to defray the expenses of the
state,
no discouragement will thereby be given to any sort of
iudustry.
The annual produce of the land and labour of the
society,
the real wealth and revenue of the great body of the
people,
might be the same after such a tax as before.
Ground-rents,
and the ordinary rent of land, are therefore,
perhaps,
the species of revenue which can best bear to have a
peculiar
tax imposed upon them.
Ground-rents
seem, in this respect, a more proper subject of
peculiar
taxation, than even the ordinary rent of land. The
ordinary
rent of land is, in many cases, owing partly, at least,
to the
attention and good management of the landlord. A very
heavy
tax might discourage, too much, this attention and good
management.
Ground-rents, so far as they exceed the ordinary rent
of
land, are altogether owing to the good government of the
sovereign,
which, by protecting the industry either of the whole
people
or of the inhabitants of some particular place, enables
them to
pay so much more than its real value for the ground which
they
build their houses upon; or to make to its owner so much
more
than compensation for the loss which he might sustain by
this
use of it. Nothing can be more reasonable, than that a fund,
which
owes its existence to the good government of the state,
should
be taxed peculiarly, or should contribute something more
than
the greater part of other funds, towards the support of that
government.
Though,
in many different countries of Europe, taxes have been
imposed
upon the rent of houses, I do not know of any in which
ground-rents
have been considered as a separate subject of
taxation.
The contrivers of taxes have, probably, found some
difficulty
in ascertaining what part of the rent ought to be
considered
as ground-rent, and what part ought to be considered
as
building-rent. It should not, however, seem very difficult to
distinguish
those two parts of the rent from one another.
In
Great Britain the rent of houses is supposed to be taxed in
the
same proportion as the rent of land, by what is called the
annual
land tax. The valuation, according to which each different
parish
and district is assessed to this tax, is always the same.
It was
originally extremely unequal, and it still continues to be
so.
Through the greater part of the kingdom this tax falls still
more
lightly upon the rent of houses than upon that of land.
In some
few districts only, which were originally rated high, and
in
which the rents of houses have fallen considerably, the land
tax of
three or four shillings in the pound is said to amount to
an
equal proportion of the real rent of houses. Untenanted
houses,
though by law subject to the tax, are, in most districts,
exempted
from it by the favour of the assessors; and this
exemption
sometimes occasions some little variation in the rate
of
particular houses, though that of the district is always the
same.
Improvements of rent, by new buildings, repairs, etc. go to
the
discharge of the district, which occasions still further
variations
in the rate of particular houses.
In the
province of Holland,{ Memoires concernant les Droits, etc.
p.
223.} every house is taxed at two and a-half per cent. of its
value,
without any regard, either to the rent which it actually
pays,
or to the circumstance of its being tenanted or untenanted.
There
seems to be a hardship in obliging the proprietor to pay a
tax for
an untenanted house, from which he can derive no revenue,
especially
so very heavy a tax. In Holland, where the market rate
of
interest does not exceed three per cent., two and a-half per
cent.
upon the whole value of the house must, in most cases,
amount
to more than a third of the building-rent, perhaps of the
whole
rent. The valuation, indeed, according to which the houses
are
rated, though very unequal, is said to be always below the
real
value. When a house is rebuilt, improved, or enlarged, there
is a
new valuation, and the tax is rated accordingly.
The
contrivers of the several taxes which in England have, at
different
times, been imposed upon houses, seem to have imagined
that
there was some great difficulty in ascertaining, with
tolerable
exactness, what was the real rent of every house. They
have
regulated their taxes, therefore, according to some more
obvious
circumstance, such as they had probably imagined would,
in most
cases, bear some proportion to the rent.
The
first tax of this kind was hearth-money; or a tax of two
shillings
upon every hearth. In order to ascertain how many
hearths
were in the house, it was necessary that the tax-gatherer
should
enter every room in it. This odious visit rendered the tax
odious.
Soon after the Revolution, therefore, it was abolished as
a badge
of slavery.
The
next tax of this kind was a tax of two shillings upon every
dwelling-house
inhabited. A house with ten windows to pay four
shillings
more. A house with twenty windows and upwards to pay
eight
shillings. This tax was afterwards so far altered, that
houses
with twenty windows, and with less than thirty, were
ordered
to pay ten shillings, and those with thirty windows and
upwards
to pay twenty shillings. The number of windows can, in
most
cases, be counted from the outside, and, in all cases,
without
entering every room in the house. The visit of the
tax-gatherer,
therefore, was less offensive in this tax than in
the
hearth-money.
This
tax was afterwards repealed, and in the room of it was
established
the window-tax, which has undergone two several
alterations
and augmentations. The window tax, as it stands at
present
(January 1775), over and above the duty of three
shillings
upon every house in England, and of one shilling upon
every
house in Scotland, lays a duty upon every window, which in
England
augments gradually from twopence, the lowest rate upon
houses
with not more than seven windows, to two shillings, the
highest
rate upon houses with twenty-five windows and upwards.
The
principal objection to all such taxes is their inequality; an
inequality
of the worst kind, as they must frequently fall much
heavier
upon the poor than upon the rich. A house of ten pounds
rent in
a country town, may sometimes have more windows than a
house
of five hundred pounds rent in London ; and though the
inhabitant
of the former is likely to be a much poorer man than
that of
the latter, yet, so far as his contribution is regulated
by the
window tax, he must contribute more to the support of the
state.
Such taxes are, therefore, directly contrary to the first
of the
four maxims above mentioned. They do not seem to offend
much
against any of the other three.
The
natural tendency of the window tax, and of all other taxes
upon
houses, is to lower rents. The more a man pays for the tax,
the
less, it is evident, he can afford to pay for the rent. Since
the
imposition of the window tax, however, the rents of houses
have,
upon the whole, risen more or less, in almost every town
and
village of Great Britain, with which I am acquainted.
Such
has been, almost everywhere, the increase of the demand for
houses,
that it has raised the rents more than the window tax
could
sink them ; one of the many proofs of the great prosperity
of the
country, and of the increasing revenue of its inhabitants.
Had it
not been for the tax, rents would probably have risen
still
higher.
ARTICLE II. ˜ Taxes upon Profit, or upon the
Revenue arising
from
Stock.
The
revenue or profit arising from stock naturally divides itself
into
two parts; that which pays the interest, and which belongs
to the
owner of the stock ; and that surplus part which is over
and
above what is necessary for paying the interest.
This
latter part of profit is evidently a subject not taxable
directly.
It is the compensation, and, in most cases, it is no
more than
a very moderate compensation for the risk and trouble
of
employing the stock. The employer must have this compensation,
otherwise
he cannot, consistently with his own interest, continue
the
employment. If he was taxed directly, therefore, in
proportion
to the whole profit, he would be obliged either to
raise
the rate of his profit, or to charge the tax upon the
interest
of money ; that is, to pay less interest. If he raised
the
rate of his profit in proportion to the tax, the whole tax,
though
it might be advanced by him, would be finally paid by one
or
other of two different sets of people, according to the
different
ways in which he might employ the stock of which he had
the
management. If he employed it as a farming stock, in the
cultivation
of land, he could raise the rate of his profit only
by
retaining a greater portion, or, what comes to the same thing,
the
price of a greater portion, of the produce of the land; and
as this
could be done only by a reduction of rent, the final
payment
of the tax would fall upon the landlord. If he employed
it as a
mercantile or manufacturing stock, he could raise the
rate of
his profit only by raising the price of his goods; in
which
case, the final payment of the tax would fall altogether
upon the
consumers of those goods. If he did not raise the rate
of his
profit, he would be obliged to charge the whole tax upon
that
part of it which was allotted for the interest of money. He
could
afford less interest for whatever stock he borrowed, and
the
whole weight of the tax would, in this case, fall ultimately
upon
the interest of money. So far as he could not relieve
himself
from the tax in the one way, he would be obliged to
relieve
himself in the other.
The
interest of money seems, at first sight, a subject equally
capable
of being taxed directly as the rent of land. Like the
rent of
land, it is a neat produce, which remains, after
completely
compensating the whole risk and trouble of employing
the
stock. As a tax upon the rent of land cannot raise rents,
because
the neat produce which remains, after replacing the stock
of the
farmer, together with his reasonable profit, cannot be
greater
after the tax than before it, so, for the same reason, a
tax
upon the interest of money could not raise the rate of
interest;
the quantity of stock or money in the country, like the
quantity
of land, being supposed to remain the same after the tax
as
before it. The ordinary rate of profit, it has been shewn, in
the
first book, is everywhere regulated by the quantity of stock
to be
employed, in proportion to the quantity of the employment,
or of
the business which must be done by it.
But the quantity
of the
employment, or of the business to be done by stock, could
neither
be increased nor diminished by any tax upon the interest
of
money. If the quantity of the stock to be employed, therefore,
was
neither increased nor diminished by it, the ordinary rate of
profit
would necessarily remain the same. But the portion of this
profit,
necessary for compensating the risk and trouble of the
employer,
would likewise remain the same ; that risk and trouble
being
in no respect altered. The residue, therefore, that portion
which
belongs to the owner of the stock, and which pays the
interest
of money, would necessarily remain the same too. At
first
sight, therefore, the interest of money seems to be a
subject
as fit to be taxed directly as the rent of land.
There
are, however, two different circumstances, which render the
interest
of money a much less proper subject of direct taxation
than
the rent of land.
First,
the quantity and value of the land which any man
possesses,
can never be a secret, and can always be ascertained
with
great exactness. But the whole amount of the capital stock
which
he possesses is almost always a secret, and can scarce ever
be
ascertained with tolerable exactness. It is liable, besides,
to
almost continual variations. A year seldom passes away,
frequently
not a month, sometimes scarce a single day, in which
it does
not rise or fall more or less. An inquisition into every
man's
private circumstances, and an inquisition which, in order
to
accommodate the tax to them, watched over all the fluctuations
of his
fortune, would be a source of such continual and endless
vexation
as no person could support.
Secondly,
land is a subject which cannot be removed; whereas
stock
easily may. The proprietor of land is necessarily a citizen
of the
particular country in which his estate lies. The
proprietor
of stock is properly a citizen of the world, and is
not
necessarily attached to any particular country. He would be
apt to
abandon the country in which he was exposed to a vexatious
inquisition,
in order to be assessed to a burdensome tax ; and
would
remove his stock to some other country, where he could
either
carry on his business, or enjoy his fortune more at his
ease.
By removing his stock, he would put an end to all the
industry
which it had maintained in the country which he left.
Stock
cultivates land ; stock employs labour. A tax which tended
to
drive away stock from any particular country, would so far
tend to
dry up every source of revenue, both to the sovereign and
to the
society. Not only the profits of stock, but the rent of
land,
and the wages of labour, would necessarily be more or less
diminished
by its removal.
The
nations, accordingly, who have attempted to tax the revenue
arising
from stock, instead of any severe inquisition of this
kind,
have been obliged to content themselves with some very
loose,
and, therefore, more or less arbitrary estimation. The
extreme
inequality and uncertainty of a tax assessed in this
manner,
can be compensated only by its extreme moderation; in
consequence
of which, every man finds himself rated so very much
below
his real revenue, that he gives himself little disturbance
though
his neighbour should be rated somewhat lower.
By what
is called the land tax in England, it was intended that
the
stock should be taxed in the same proportion as land. When
the tax
upon land was at four shillings in the pound, or at
one-fifth
of the supposed rent, it was intended that stock should
be
taxed at one-fifth of the supposed interest. When the present
annual
land tax was first imposed, the legal rate of interest was
six per
cent. Every hundred pounds stock, accordingly, was
supposed
to be taxed at twenty-four shillings, the fifth part of
six
pounds. Since the legal rate of interest has been reduced to
five
per cent. every hundred pounds stock is supposed to be taxed
at
twenty shillings only. The sum to be raised, by what is called
the
land tax, was divided between the country and the principal
towns.
The greater part of it was laid upon the country; and of
what
was laid upon the towns, the greater part was assessed upon
the
houses. What remained to be assessed upon the stock or trade
of the
towns (for the stock upon the land was not meant to be
taxed)
was very much below the real value of that stock or trade.
Whatever
inequalities, therefore, there might be in the original
assessment,
gave little disturbance. Every parish and district
still
continues to be rated for its land, its houses, and its
stock,
according to the original assessment; and the almost
universal
prosperity of the country, which, in most places, has
raised
very much the value of all these, has rendered those
inequalities
of still less importance now. The rate, too, upon
each
district, continuing always the same, the uncertainty of
this
tax, so far as it might he assessed upon the stock of any
individual,
has been very much diminished, as well as rendered of
much
less consequence. If the greater part of the lands of
England
are not rated to the land tax at half their actual value,
the
greater part of the stock of England is, perhaps, scarce
rated
at the fiftieth part of its actual value. In some towns,
the
whole land tax is assessed upon houses; as in Westminster,
where
stock and trade are free. It is otherwise in London.
In all
countries, a severe inquisition into the circumstances of
private
persons has been carefully avoided.
At
Hamburg, {Memoires concernant les Droits, tom. i, p.74} every
inhabitant
is obliged to pay to the state one fourth per cent. of
all
that he possesses; and as the wealth of the people of Hamburg
consists
principally in stock, this tax maybe considered as a tax
upon
stock. Every man assesses himself,
and, in the presence
of the
magiatrate, puts annually into the public coffer a certain
sum of
money, which he declares upon oath, to be one fourth per
cent.
of all that he possesses, but without declaring what it
amounts
to, or being liable to any examination upon that subject.
This
tax is generally suppused to be paid with great fidelity. In
a small
republic, where the people have entire confidence in
their
magistrates, are convinced of the necessity of the tax for
the
support of the state, and believe that it will be faithfully
applied
to that purpose, such conscientious and voluntary payment
may
sometimes be expected. It is not peculiar to the people of
Hamburg.
The
canton of Underwald, in Switzerland, is frequently ravaged by
storms
and inundations, and it is thereby exposed to
extraordinary
expenses. Upon such occasions the
people
assemble,
and every one is said to declare with the greatest
frankness
what he is worth, in order to be taxed accordingly. At
Zurich,
the law orders, that in cases of necessity, every one
should
be taxed in proportion to his revenue; the amount of which
he is
obliged to declare upon oath. They have no suspicion, it is
said,
that any of their fellow citizens will deceive them.
At
Basil, the principal revenue of the state arises from a small
custom
upon goods exported. All the
citizens make oath, that
they
will pay every three months all the taxes imposed by law.
All
merchants, and even all inn-keepers, are trusted with keeping
themselves
the account of the goods which they sell, either
within
or without the territory. At the end of every three
months,
they send this account to the treasurer, with the amount
of the
tax computed at the bottom of it. It
is not suspected
that
the revenue suffers by this confidence.{ Memoires concernant
les
Droits, tom. i p. 163, 167,171.}
To
oblige every citizen to declare publicly upon oath, the amount
of his
fortune, must not, it seems, in those Swiss cantons, be
reckoned
a hardship. At Hamburg it would be
reckoned the
greatest.
Merchants engaged in the hazardous projects of trade,
all
tremble at the thoughts of being obliged, at all times, to
expose
the real state of their circumstances. The ruin of their
credit,
and the miscarriage of their projects, they foresee,
would
too often be the consequence. A sober and parsimonious
people,
who are strangers to all such projects, do not feel that
they
have occasion for any such concealment.
In
Holland, soon after the exaltation of the late prince of
Orange
to the stadtholdership, a tax of two per cent. or the
fiftieth
penny, as it was called, was imposed upon the whole
substance
of every citizen. Every citizen assesed himself, and
paid
his tax, in the same manner as at Hamburg, and it was in
general
supposed to have been paid with great fidelity. The
people
had at that time the greatest affection for their new
government,
which they had just established by a general
insurrection.
The tax was to be paid but once, in order to
relieve
the state in a particular exigency. It was, indeed, too
heavy
to be permanent. In a country where
the market rate of
interest
seldom exceeds three per cent., a tax of two per cent.
amounts
to thirteen shillings and four pence in the pound, upon
the
highest neat revenue which is commonly drawn from stock. It
is a
tax which very few people could pay, without encroaching
more or
less upon their capitals. In a particular exigency, the
people
may, from great public zeal, make a great effort, and give
up even
a part of their capital, in order to relieve the state.
But it
is impossible that they should continue to do so for any
considerable
time; and if they did, the tax would soon ruin them
so
completely, as to render them altogether incapable of
supporting
the state.
The tax
upon stock, imposed by the land tax bill in England,
though
it is proportioned to the capital, is not intended to
diminish
or, take away any part of that capital.
It is meant
only to
be a tax upon the interest of money, proportioned to that
upon
the rent of land; so that when the latter is at four
shillings
in the pound, the former may be at four shillings in
the
pound too. The tax at Hamburg, and the still more moderate
taxes
of Underwald and Zurich, are meant, in the same manner, to
be
taxes, not upon the capital, but upon the interest or neat
revenue
of stock. That of Holland was meant to be a tax upon the
capital.
Taxes
upon the Profit of particular Employments.
In some
countries, extraordinary taxes are imposed upon the
profits
of stock ; sometimes when employed in particular branches
of
trade, and sometimes when employed in agriculture.
Of the
former kind, are in England, the tax upon hawkers and
pedlars,
that upon hackney-coaches and chairs, and that which the
keepers
of ale-houses pay for a licence to retail ale and
spiritous
liquors. During the late war, another tax of the same
kind
was proposed upon shops. The war having been undertaken, it
was
said, in defence of the trade of the country, the merchants,
who
were to profit by it, ought to contribute towards the support
of it.
A tax,
however, upon the profits of stock employed in any
particular
branch of trade, can never fall finally upon the
dealers
(who must in all ordinary cases have their reasonable
profit,
and, where the competition is free, can seldom have more
than
that profit), but always upon the consumers, who must be
obliged
to pay in the price of the goods the tax which the dealer
advances
; and generally with some overcharge.
A tax
of this kind, when it is proportioned to the trade of the
dealer,
is finally paid by the consumer, and occasions no
oppression
to the dealer. When it is not so proportioned, but is
the
same upon all dealers, though in this case, too, it is
finally
paid by the consumer, yet it favours the great, and
occasions
some oppression to the small dealer.
The tax of
five
shillings a-week upon every hackney coach, and that of ten
shillings
a-year upon every hackney chair, so far as it is
advanced
by the different keepers of such coaches and chairs, is
exactly
enough proportioned to the extent of their respective
dealings.
It neither favours the great, nor oppresses the smaller
dealer. The tax of twenty shillings a-year for a
licence to
sell
ale; of forty shillings for a licence to sell spiritous
liquors
; and of forty shillings more for a licence to sell wine,
being
the same upon all retailers, must necessarily give some
advantage
to the great, and occasion some oppression to the small
dealers.
The former must find it more easy to get back the tax in
the
price of their goods than the latter. The moderation of the
tax, however,
renders this inequality of less importance; and it
may to
many people appear not improper to give some
discouragement
to the multiplication of little ale-houses.
The tax
upon shops, it was intended, should be the same upon all
shops.
It could not well have been otherwise. It would have been
impossible
to proportion, with tolerable exactness, the tax upon
a shop
to the extent of the trade carried on in it, without such
an
inquisition as would have been altogether insupportable in a
free
country. If the tax had been considerable, it would have
oppressed
the small, and forced almost the whole retail trade
into
the hands of the great dealers. The competition of the
former
being taken away, the latter would have enjoyed a monopoly
of the
trade ; and, like all other monopolists, would soon have
combined
to raise their profits much beyond what was necessary
for the
payment of the tax. The final payment, instead of falling
upon
the shop-keeper, would have fallen upon the consumer, with a
considerable
overcharge to the profit of the shop-keeper. For
these
reasons, the project of a tax upon shops was laid aside,
and in
the room of it was substituted the subsidy, 1759.
What in
France is called the personal taille, is perhaps, the
most
important tax upon the profits of stock employed in
agriculture,
that is levied in any part of Europe.
In the
disorderly state of Europe, during the prevalence of the
feudal
government, the sovereign was obliged to content himself
with
taxing those who were too weak to refuse to pay taxes. The
great
lords, though willing to assist him upon particular
emergencies,
refused to subject themselves to any constant tax,
and he
was not strong enough to force them. The occupiers of land
all
over Europe were, the greater part of them, originally
bond-men.
Through the greater part of Europe, they were gradually
emancipated.
Some of them acquired the property of landed
estates,
which they held by some base or ignoble tenure,
sometimes
under the king, and sometimes under some other great
lord,
like the ancient copy-holders of England. Others, without
acquiring
the property, obtained leases for terms of years, of
the
lands which they occupied under their lord, and thus became
less
dependent upon him. The great lords seem to have beheld the
degree
of prosperity and independency, which this inferior order
of men
had thus come to enjoy, with a malignant and contemptuous
indignation,
and willingly consented that the sovereign should
tax
them. In some countries, this tax was confined to the lands
which
were held in property by an ignoble tenure ; and, in this
case,
the taille was said to be real. The land tax established by
the
late king of Sardinia, and the taille in the provinces of
Languedoc,
Provence, Dauphine, and Britanny ; in the generality
of
Montauban, and in the elections of Agen and Condom, as well as
in some
other districts of France; are taxes upon lands held in
property
by an ignoble tenure. In other
countries, the tax
was
laid upon the supposed profits of all those who held, in farm
or
lease, lands belonging to other people, whatever might be the
tenure
by which the proprietor held them ; and in this case, the
taille
was said to be personal. In the greater part of those
provinces
of France, which are called the countries of elections,
the
taille is of this kind. The real taille, as it is imposed
only
upon a part of the lands of the country, is necessarily an
unequal,
but it is not always an arbitrary tax, though it is so
upon
some occasions. The personal taille, as it is intended to be
proportioned
to the profits of a certain class of people, which
can
only be guessed at, is necessarily both arbitrary and
unequal.
In
France, the personal taille at present (1775) annually imposed
upon
the twenty generalities, called the countries of elections,
amounts
to 40,107,239 livres, 16 sous. {Memoires concernant les
Droits,
etc tom. ii, p.17.} the proportion in which this sum is
assessed
upon those different provinces, varies from year to
year,
according to the reports which are made to the king's
council
concerning the goodness or badness of the crops, as well
as
other circumstances, which may either increase or diminish
their
respective abilities to pay. Each generality is divided
into a
certain number of elections; and the proportion in which
the sum
imposed upon the whole generatlity is divided among those
different
elections, varies likewise from year to year, according
to the
reports made to the council concerning their respective
abilities. It seems impossible, that the council,
with the
best
intentions, can ever proportion, with tolerable exactness,
either
of these two assessments to the real abilities of the
province
or district upon which they are respectively laid.
Ignorance
and misinformation must always, more or
less. mislead
the
most upright council. The proportion which each parish ought
to
support of what is assessed upon the whole election, and that
which
each individual ought to support of what is assessed upon
his
particular parish, are both in the same manner varied from
year to
year, according as circumstances are supposed to require.
These
circumstances are judged of, in the one case, by the
officers
of the election, in the other, by those of the parish;
and
both the one and the other are, more or less, under the
direction
and influence of the intendant. Not
only ignorance
and
misinformation, but friendship, party animosity, and private
resentment,
are said frequently to mislead such assessors. No man
subject
to such a tax, it is evident, can ever be certain, before
he is
assessed, of what he is to pay. He cannot even be certain
after
he is assessed. If any person has been taxed who ought to
have
been exempted, or if any person has been taxed beyond his
proportion,
though both must pay in the mean time, yet if they
complain,
and make good their complaints, the whole parish is
reimposed
next year, in order to reimburse them.
If any of
the
contributors become bankrupt or insolvent, the collector is
obliged
to advance his tax ; and the whole parish is reimposed
next
year, in order to reimburse the collector. If the collector
himself
should become bankrupt, the parish which elects him must
answer
for his conduct to the receiver-general of the election.
But, as
it might be troublesome for the receiver to prosecute the
whole
parish, he takes at his choice five or six of the richest
contributors,
and obliges them to make good what had been lost by
the
insolvency of the collector. The parish is afterwards
reimposed,
in order to reimburse those five or six.
Such
reimpositions
are always over and above the taille of the
particular
year in which they are laid on.
When a
tax is imposed upon the profits of stock in a particular
branch
of trade, the traders are all careful to bring no more
goods
to market than what they can sell at a price sufficient to
reimburse
them from advancing the tax. Some of them withdraw a
part of
their stocks from the trade, and the market is more
sparingly
supplied than before. The price of the goods rises, and
the
final payment of the tax falls upon the consumer. But when a
tax is
imposed upon the profits of stock employed in agriculture,
it is
not the interest of the farmers to withdraw any part of
their
stock from that employment. Each farmer occupies a certain
quantity
of land, for which he pays rent. For the proper
cultivation
of this land, a certain quantity of stock is
necessary;
and by withdrawing any part of this necessary
quantity,
the farmer is not likely to be more able to pay either
the
rent or the tax. In order to pay the tax, it can never be his
interest
to diminish the quantity of his produce, nor
consequently
to supply the market more sparingly than before. The
tax, therefore,
will never enable him to raise the price of his
produce,
so as to reimburse himself, by throwing the final
payment
upon the consumer. The farmer, however, must have his
reasonable
profit as well as every other dealer, otherwise he
must
give up the trade. After the imposition of a tax of this
kind,
he can get this reasonable profit only by paying less rent
to the
landlord. The more he is obliged to pay in the way of tax,
the
less he can afford to pay in the way of rent. A tax of this
kind,
imposed during the currency of a lease, may, no doubt,
distress
or ruin the farmer. Upon the renewal of the lease, it
must
always fall upon the landlord.
In the
countries where the personal taille takes place, the
farmer
is commonly assessed in proportion to the stock which he
appears
to employ in cultivation. He is, upon this account,
frequently
afraid to have a good team of horses or oxen, but
endeavours
to cultivate with the meanest and most wretched
instrutnents
of husbandry that he can. Such is his distrust in
the
justice of his assessors, that he counterfeits poverty, and
wishes
to appear scarce able to pay anything, for fear of being
obliged
to pay too much. By this miserable policy, he does not,
perhaps,
always consult his own interest in the most effectual
manner
; and he probably loses more by the diminution of his
produce,
than he saves by that of his tax. Though, in consequence
of this
wretched cultivation, the market is, no doubt, somewhat
worse
supplied; yet the small rise of price which this may
occasion,
as it is not likely even to indemnify the farmer for
the
diminution of his produce, it is still less likely to enable
him to
pay more rent to the landlord. The public, the farmer, the
landlord,
all suffer more or less by this degraded cultivation.
That
the personal taille tends, in many different ways, to
discourage
cultivation, and consequently to dry up the principal
source
of the wealth of every great country, I have already had
occasion
to observe in the third book of this Inquiry.
What
are called poll-taxes in the southern provinces of North
America,
and the West India islands, annual taxes of so much
a-head
upon every negro, are properly taxes upon the profits of a
certain
species of stock employed in agriculture. As the
planters,
are the greater part of them, both farmers and
landlords,
the final payment of the tax falls upon them in their
quality
of landlords, without any retribution.
Taxes
of so much a head upon the bondmen employed in cultivation,
seem
anciently to have been common all over Europe. There
subsists
at present a tax of this kind in the empire of Russia.
It is
probably upon this account that poll-taxes of all kinds
have
often been represented as badges of slavery. Every tax,
however,
is, to the person who pays it, a badge, not of slavery,
but of
liberty. It denotes that he is subject to government,
indeed
; but that, as he has some property, he cannot himself be
the
property of a master. A poll tax upon slaves is altogether
different
from a poll-tax upon freemen. The latter is paid by the
persons
upon whom it is imposed; the former, by a different set
of
persons. The latter is either altogether arbitrary, or
altogether
unequal, and, in most cases, is both the one and the
other;
the former, though in some respects unequal, different
slaves
being of different values, is in no respect arbitrary.
Every
master, who knows the number of his own slaves, knows
exactly
what he has to pay. Those different taxes, however, being
called by
the same name, have been considered as of the same
nature.
The
taxes which in Holland are imposed upon men and maid
servants,
are taxes, not upon stock, but upon expense; and so far
resemble
the taxes upon consumable commodities.
The tax of a
guinea
a-head for every man-servant, which has lately been
imposed
in Great Britain, is of the same kind. It falls heaviest
upon
the middling rank. A man of two hundred a-year may keep a
single
man-servant. A man of ten thousand a-year will not keep
fifty.
It does not affect the poor.
Taxes
upon the profits of stock, in particular employments, can
never
affect the interest of money. Nobody will lend his money
for
less interest to those who exercise the taxed, than to those
who
exercise the untaxed employments. Taxes upon the revenue
arising
from stock in all employments, where the government
attempts
to levy them with any degree of exactness, will, in many
cases,
fall upon the interest of money. The vingtieme, or
twentieth
penny, in France, is a tax of the same kind with what
is
called the land tax in England, and is assessed, in the same
manner,
upon the revenue arising upon land, houses, and stock. So
far as
it affects stock, it is assessed, though not with great
rigour,
yet with much more exactness than that part of the land
tax in
England which is imposed upon the same fund. It, in many
cases,
falls altogether upon the interest of money. Money is
frequently
sunk in France, upon what are called contracts for the
constitution
of a rent ; that is, perpetual annuities, redeemable
at any
time by the debtor, upon payment of the sum originally
advanced,
but of which this redemption is not exigible by the
creditor
except in particular cases. The
vingtieme seems not
to have
raised the rate of those annuities, though it is exactly
levied
upon them all.
APPENDIX
TO ARTICLES I. AND II. ˜ Taxes upon the Capital Value of
Lands,
Houses, and Stock.
While
property remains in the possession of the same person,
whatever
permanent taxes may have been imposed upon it, they have
never
been intended to diminish or take away any part of its
capital
value, but only some part of the revenue arising from it.
But
when property changes hands, when it is transmitted either
from
the dead to the living, or from the living to the living,
such
taxes have frequently been imposed upon it as necessarily
take
away some part of its capital value.
The
transference of all sorts of property from the dead to the
living,
and that of immoveable property of land and houses from
the
living to the living, are transactions which are in their
nature
either public and notorious, or such as cannot be long
concealed.
Such transactions, therefore, may be taxed directly.
The
transference of stock or moveable property, from the living
to the
living, by the lending of money, is frequently a secret
transaction,
and may always be made so. It cannot easily,
therefore,
be taxed directly. It has been taxed indirectly in two
different
ways; first, by requiring that the deed, containing the
obligation
to repay, should be written upon paper or parchment
which
had paid a certain stamp duty, otherwise not to be valid ;
secondly,
by requiring, under the like penalty of invalidity,
that it
should be recorded either in a public or secret register,
and by
imposing certain duties upon such registration. Stamp
duties,
and duties of registration, have frequently been imposed
likewise
upon the deeds transferring property of all kinds from
the
dead to the living, and upon those transferring immoveable
property
from the living to the living ; transactions which might
easily
have been taxed directly.
The
vicesima hereditatum, or the twentieth penny of inheritances,
imposed
by Augustus upon the ancient Romans, was a tax upon the
transference
of property from the dead to the living. Dion
Cassius,
{ Lib. 55. See also Burman. de Vectigalibus Pop. Rom.
cap.
xi. and Bouchaud de l'impot du vingtieme sur les
successions.}
the author who writes concerning it the least
indistinctly,
says, that it was imposed upon all successions,
legacies
and donations, in case of death, except upon those to
the
nearest relations, and to the poor.
Of the
same kind is the Dutch tax upon successions. { See
Memoires
concernant les Droits, etc. tom i, p. 225.} Collateral
successions
are taxed according to the degree of relation, from
five to
thirty per cent. upon the whole value of the succession.
Testamentary
donations, or legacies to collaterals, are subject
to the
like duties. Those from husband to wife, or from wife to
husband,
to the fiftieth penny. The luctuosa hereditas, the
mournful
succession of ascendants to descendants, to the
twentieth
penny only. Direct successions, or
those of
descendants
to ascendants, pay no tax. The death of a father, to
such of
his children as live in the same house with him, is
seldom
attended with any increase, and frequently with a
considerable
diminution of revenue ; by the loss of his industry,
of his
office, or of some life-rent estate, of which he may have
been in
possession. That tax would be cruel
and oppressive,
which
aggravated their loss, by taking from them any part of his
succession. It may, however, sometimes be otherwise
with
those
children, who, in the language of the Roman law, are said
to be
emancipated; in that of the Scotch law, to be
foris-familiated
; that is, who have received their portion, have
got
families of their own, and are supported by funds separate
and
independent of those of their father. Whatever part of his
succession
might come to such children, would be a real addition
to
their fortune, and might, therefore, perhaps, without more
inconveniency
than what attends all duties of this kind, be
liable
to some tax.
The
casualties of the feudal law were taxes upon the transference
of
land, both from the dead to the living, and from the living to
the
living. In ancient times, they
constituted, in every part
of
Europe, one of the principal branches of the revenue of the
crown.
The heir
of every immediate vassal of the crown paid a certain
duty,
generally a year's rent, upon receiving the investiture of
the
estate. If the heir was a minor, the whole rents of the
estate.
during the continuance of the minority, devolved to the
superior,
without any other charge besides the maintenance of the
minor,
and the payment of the widow's dower, when there happened
to be a
dowager upon the land. When the minor came to de of age,
another
tax, called relief, was still due to the superior, which
generally
amounted likewise to a year's rent. A long minority,
which,
in the present times, so frequently disburdens a great
estate
of all its incumbrances. and restores the family to their
ancient
splendour, could in those times have no such effect. The
waste,
and not the disincumbrance of the estate, was the common
effect
of a long minority.
By a
feudal law, the vassal could not alienate without the
consent
of his superior, who generally extorted a fine or
composition
on granting it. This fine, which was at first
arbitrary,
came, in many countries, to be regulated at a certain
portion
of the price of the land. In some countries, where the
greater
part of the other feudal customs have gone into disuse,
this
tax upon the alienation of land still continues to make a
very
considerable branch of the revenue of the sovereign. In the
canton
of Berne it is so high as a sixth part of the price of all
noble
fiefs, and a tenth part of that of all ignoble
ones.{Memoires
concernant les Droits, etc, tom.i p.154} In the
canton
of Lucern, the tax upon the sale of land is not universal,
and
takes place only in certain districts. But if any person
sells
his land in order to remove out of the territory, he pays
ten per
cent. upon the whole price of the sale. { id. p.157.}
Taxes
of the same kind, upon the sale either of all lands, or of
lands
held by certain tenures, take place in many other
countries,
and make a more or less considerable branch of the
revenue
of the sovereign.
Such
transactions may be taxed indirectly, by means either of
stamp
duties, or of duties upon registration; and those duties
either
may, or may not, be proportioned to the value of the
subject
which is transferred.
In
Great Britain, the stamp duties are higher or lower, not so
much
according to the value of the property transferred (an
eighteen-penny
or half-crown stamp being sufficient upon a bond
for the
largest sum of money), as according to the nature of the
deed.
The highest do not exceed six pounds upon every sheet of
paper,
or skin of parchment ; and these high duties fall chiefly
upon
grants from the crown, and upon certain law proceedings,
without
any regard to the value of the subject. There are, in
Great
Britain, no duties on the registration of deeds or
writings,
except the fees of the officers who keep the register ;
and
these are seldom more than a reasonable recompence for their
labour.
The crown derives no revenue from them.
In
Holland {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. tom. i. p 223,
224,
225.} there are both stamp duties and duties upon
registration
; which in some cases are, and in some are not,
proportioned
to the value of the property transferred. All
testaments
must be written upon stamped paper, of which the price
is
proportioned to the property disposed of ; so that there are
stamps
which cost from three pence or three stivers a-sheet, to
three
hundred florins, equal to about twenty-seven pounds ten
shillings
of our money. If the stamp is of an inferior price to
what
the testator ought to have made use of, his succession is
confiscated.
This is over and above all their other taxes on
succession.
Except bills of exchange, and some other mercantile
bills,
all other deeds, bonds, and contracts, are subject to a
stamp
duty. This duty, however, does not rise in proportion to
the
value of the subject. All sales of land and of houses, and
all
mortgages upon either, must be registered, and, upon
registration,
pay a duty to the state of two and a-half per cent.
upon
the amount of the price or of the mortgage. This duty is
extended
to the sale of all ships and vessels of more than two
tons
burden, whether decked or undecked. These, it seems, are
considered
as a sort of houses upon the water. The sale of
moveables,
when it is ordered by a court of justice, is subject
to the
like duty of two and a-half per cent.
In
France, there are both stamp duties and duties upon
registration. The former are considered as a branch of
the
aids of
excise, and, in the provinces where those duties take
place,
are levied by the excise officers. The latter are
considered
as a branch of the domain of the crown and are levied
by a
different set of officers.
Those
modes of taxation by stamp duties and by duties upon
registration,
are of very modern invention. In the
course of
little
more than a century, however, stamp duties have, in
Europe,
become almost universal, and duties upon registration
extremely
common. There is no art which one government sooner
learns
of another, than that of draining money from the pockets
of the
people.
Taxes
upon the transference of property from the dead to the
living,
fall finally, as well as immediately, upon the persons to
whom
the property is transferred. Taxes
upon the sale of
land fall
altogether upon the seller. The
seller is almost
always
under the necessity of selling, and must, therefore, take
such a
price as he can get. The buyer is scarce ever under the
necessity
of buying, and will, therefore, only give such a price
as he
likes. He considers what the land will cost him, in tax and
price
together. The more he is obliged to pay in the way of tax,
the
less he will be disposed to give in the way of price. Such
taxes,
therefore, fall almost always upon a necessitous person,
and
must, therefore, be frequently very cruel and oppressive.
Taxes
upon the sale of new-built houses, where the building is
sold
without the ground, fall generally upon the buyer, because
the
builder must generally have his profit ; otherwise he must
give up
the trade. If he advances the tax, therefore, the buyer
must
generally repay it to him. Taxes upon the sale of old
houses,
for the same reason as those upon the sale of land, fall
generally
upon the seller ; whom, in most cases, either
conveniency
or necessity obliges to sell. The number of new-built
houses
that are annually brought to market, is more or less
regulated
by the demand. Unless the demand is such as to afford
the
builder his profit, after paying all expenses, he will build
no more
houses. The number of old houses which happen at any time
to come
to market, is regulated by accidents, of which the
greater
part have no relation to the demand. Two or three great
bankruptcies
in a mercantile town, will bring many houses to
sale,
which must be sold for what can be got for them. Taxes upon
the
sale of ground-rents fall altogether upon the seller, for the
same
reason as those upon the sale of lands. Stamp duties, and
duties
upon the registration of bonds and contracts for borrowed
money,
fall altogether upon the borrower, and, in fact, are
always
paid by him. Duties of the same kind upon law proceedings
fall
upon the suitors. They reduce to both the capital value of
the
subject in dispute. The more it costs to acquire any
property,
the less must be the neat value of it when acquired.
All
taxes upon the transference of property of every kind, so far
as they
diminish the capital value of that property, tend to
diminish
the funds destined for the maintenance of productive
labour. They are all more or less unthrifty taxes
that
increase
the revenue of the sovereign, which seldom maintains any
but
unproductive labourers, at the expense of the capital of the
people,
which maintains none but productive.
Such
taxes, even when they are proportioned to the value of the
property
transferred, are still unequal; the frequency of
transference
not being always equal in property of equal value.
When
they are not proportioned to this value, which is the case
with
the greater part of the stamp duties and duties of
registration,
they are still more so. They are in no respect
arbitrary,
but are, or may be, in all cases, perfectly clear and
certain.
Though they sometimes fall upon the person who is not
very
able to pay, the time of payment is, in most cases,
sufficiently
convenient for him. When the payment becomes due, he
must,
in most cases, have the more to pay. They are levied at
very
little expense, and in general subject the contributors to
no
other inconveniency, besides always the unavoidable one of
paying
the tax.
In
France, the stamp duties are not much complained of. Those
of
registration, which they call the Controle, are. They give
occasion,
it is pretended, to much extortion in the officers of
the
farmers-general who collect the tax, which is in a great
measure
arbitrary and uncertain. In the
greater part of the
libels
which have been written against the present system of
finances
in France, the abuses of the controle make a principal
article.
Uncertainty, however, does not seem to be necessarily
inherent
in the nature of such taxes. If the
popular
complaints
are well founded, the abuse must arise, not so much
from
the nature of the tax as from the want of precision and
distinctness
in the words of the edicts or laws which impose it.
The
registration of mortgages, and in general of all rights upon
immoveable
property, as it gives great security both to creditors
and
purchasers, is extremely advantageous to the public. That of
the
greater part of deeds of other kinds, is frequently
inconvenient
and even dangerous to individuals, without any
advantage
to the public. All registers which, it is acknowledged,
ought
to be kept secret, ought certainly never to exist. The
credit
of individuals ought certainly never to depend upon so
very
slender a security, as the probity and religion of the
inferior
officers of revenue. But where the fees of registration
have
been made a source of revenue to the sovereign,
register-officcs
have commonly been multiplied without end, both
for the
deeds which ought to be registered, and for those which
ought
not. In France there are several different sorts of secret
registers.
This abuse, though not perhaps a necessary, it must be
acknowledged,
is a very natural effect of such taxes.
Such
stamp duties as those in England upon cards and dice, upon
newspapers
and periodical pamphlets, etc. are properly taxes upon
consumption;
the final payment falls upon the persons who use or
consume
such commodities. Such stamp duties
as those upon
licences
to retail ale, wine, and spiritous liquors, though
intended,
perhaps, to fall upon the profits of the retailers, are
likewise
finally paid by the consumers of those liquors. Such
taxes, though
called by the same name, and levied by the same
officers,
and in the same manner with the stamp duties above
mentioned
upon the transference of property, are, however, of a
quite
different nature, and fall upon quite different funds.
ARTICLE
III. ˜ Taxes upon the Wages of Labour.
The wages of the inferior classes of work
men, I have
endeavoured
to show in the first book are everywhere necessarily
regulated
by two different circumstances; the demand for labour,
and the
ordinary or average price of provisions. The demand for
labour,
according as it happens to be either increasing
stationary
or declining ; or to require an increasing,
stationary,
or declining population. regulates the subsistence of
the
labourer, and determines in what degree it shall be either
liberal,
moderate, or scanty. The ordinary average price of
provisions
determines the quantity of money which must be paid to
the
workman, in order to enable him, one year with another, to
purchase
this liberal, moderate, or scanty subsistence. While the
demand
for the labour and the price of provisions, therefore,
remain
the same, a direct tax upon the wages of labour can have
no
other effect, than to raise them somewhat higher than the tax.
Let us
suppose, for example, that, in a particular place, the
demand
for labour and the price of provisions were such as to
render
ten shillings a-week the ordinary wages of labour ; and
that a
tax of one-fifth, or four shillings in the pound, was
imposed
upon wages. If the demand for labour and the price of
provisions
remained the same, it would still be necessary that
the
labourer should, in that place, earn such a subsistence as
could
be bought only for ten shillings a-week; so that, after
paying
the tax, he should have ten shillings a-week free wages.
But, in
order to leave him such free wages, after paying such a
tax,
the price of labour must, in that place, soon rise, not to
twelve
sillings aweek only, but to twelve and sixpence ; that is,
in
order to enable him to pay a tax of one-fifth, his wages must
necessarily
soon rise, not one-fifth part only, but one-fourth.
Whatever
was the proportion of the tax, the wages of labour must,
in all
cases rise, not only in that proportion, but in a higher
proportion. If the tax for example, was one-tenth,
the wages
of
labour must necessarily soon rise, not one-tenth part only,
but
one-eighth.
A
direct tax upon the wages of labour, therefore, though the
labourer
might, perhaps, pay it out of his hand, could not
properly
be said to be even advanced by him ; at least if the
demand
for labour and the average price of provisions remained
the
same after the tax as before it. In all such cases, not only
the
tax, but something more than the tax, would in reality be
advanced
by the person who immediately employed him. The final
payment
would, in different cases, fall upon different persons.
The
rise which such a tax might occasion in the wages of
manufacturing
labour would be advanced by the master
manufacturer,
who would both be entitled and obliged to charge
it,
with a profit, upon the price of his goods. The final payment
of this
rise of wages, therefore, together with the additional
profit
of the master manufacturer would fall upon the consumer.
The
rise which such a tax might occasion in the wages of country
labour
would be advanced by the farmer, who, in order to maintain
the
same number of labourers as before, would be obliged to
employ
a greater capital. In order to get back this greater
capital,
together with the ordinary profits of stock, it would be
necessary
that he should retain a larger portion, or, what comes
to the
same thing, the price of a larger portion, of the produce
of the
land, and, consequently, that he should pay less rent to
the
landlord. The final payment of this rise of wages, therefore,
would,
in this case, fall upon the landlord, together with the
additional
profit of the farmer who had advanced it. In all
cases,
a direct tax upon the wages of labour must, in the
long-run,
occasion both a greater reduction in the rent of land,
and a
greater rise in the price of manufactured goods than would
have
followed from the proper assessment of a sum equal to the
produce
of the tax, partly upon the rent of land, and partly upon
consumable
commodities.
If
direct taxes upon the wages of labour have not always
occasioned
a proportionable rise in those wages, it is because
they
have generally occasioned a considerable fall in the demand
of
labour. The declension of industry,
the decrease of
employment
for the poor, the diminution of the annual produce of
the
land and labour of the country, have generally been the
effects
of such taxes. In consequence of them, however, the price
of
labour must always be higher than it otherwise would have been
in the
actual state of the demand ; and this enhancenmnt of
price,
together with the profit of those who advance it, must
always
be finally paid by the landlords and comsumers.
A tax
upon the wages of country labour does not raise the price
of the
rude produce of land in proportion to the tax; for the
same
reason that a tax upon the farmer's profit does not raise
that
price in that proportion.
Absurd
and destructive as such taxes are, however, they take
place
in many countries. In France, that part of the taille which
is
charged upon the industry of workmen and day-laboururs in
country
villages, is properly a tax of this kind. Their wages are
computed
according to the common rate of the district in which
they
reside ; and, that they may be as little liable as possible
to any
overcharge, their yearly gains are estimated at no more
than
two hundred working days in the year. {Memoires concernant
les
Droits, etc. tom. ii. p. 108.} The tax of each individual is
varied
from year to year, according to different circumstances,
of
which the collector or the commissary, whom intendant appoints
to
assist him, are the judges. In
Bohemia, in consequence of
the
alteration in the system of finances which was begun in 1748,
a very
heavy tax is imposed upon the industry of artificers. They
are
divided into four classes. The highest class pay a hundred
florins
a year, which, at two-and-twenty pence half penny
a-florin,
amounts to £9:7:6. The second class are taxed at
seventy
; the third at fifty ; and the fourth, comprehending
artificers
in villages, and the lowest class of those in towns,
at
twenty-five florins.{ Memoires concemant les Droits, etc. tom.
iii. p.
87.}
The
recompence of ingenious artists, and of men of liberal
professions,
I have endeavoured to show in the first book,
necessarily
keeps a certain proportion to the emoluments of
inferior
trades. A tax upon this recompence, therefore, could
have no
other effect than to raise it somewhat higher than in
proportion
to the tax. If it did not rise in
this manner, the
ingenious
arts and the liberal professions, being; no longer upon
a level
with other trades, would be so much deserted, that they
would
soon return to that level.
The
emoluments of offices are not, like those of trades and
professions,
regulated by the free competition of the market, and
do not,
therefore, always bear a just proportion to what the
nature
of the employment requires. They are, perhaps, in most
countries,
higher than it requires; the persons who have the
administration
of government being generally disposed to regard
both
themselves and their immediate dependents, rather more than
enough.
The emoluments of offices, therefore, can, in most cases,
very
well bear to be taxed. The persons, besides, who enjoy
public
offices, especially the more lucrative, are, in all
countries,
the objects of general envy ; and a tax upon their
emolmnents,
even though it should be somewhat higher than upon
any
other sort of revenue, is always a very popular tax. In
England,
for example, when, by the land-tax, every other sort of
revenue
was supposed to be assessed at four shillings in the
pound,
it was very popular to lay a real tax of five shillings
and
sixpence in the pound upon the salaries of offices which
exceeded
a hundred pounds a-year; the pensions of the younger
branches
of the royal family, the pay of the officers of the army
and
navy, and a few others less obnoxious to envy, excepted.
There
are in England no other direct taxes upon the wages of
labour.
ARTICLE IV. ˜ Taxes which it is intended should
fall
indifferently
upon every different Species of Revenue.
The
taxes which it is intended should fall indifferently upon
every
different species of revenue, are capitation taxes, and
taxes
upon consunmble commodities. Those must be paid
indifferently,
from whatever revenue the contributors may possess
; from
the rent of their land, from the profits of their stock,
or from
the wages of their labour.
Capitation
Taxes.
Capitation
taxes, if it is attempted to proportion them to the
fortune
or revenue of each contributor, become altogether
arbitrary.
The state of a man's fortune varies from day to day ;
and,
without an inquisition, more intolerable than any tax, and
renewed
at least once every year, can only be guessed at. His
assessment,
therefore, must, in most cases, depend upon the good
or bad
humour of his assessors, and must, therefore, be
altogether
arbitrary and uncertain.
Capitation
taxes, if they are proportioned, not to the supposed
fortune,
but to the rank of each contributor, become altogether
unequal
; the degrees of fortune being frequently unequal in the
same
degree of rank.
Such
taxes, therefore, if it is attempted to render them equal,
become
altogether arbitrary and uncertain ; and if it is
attempted
to render them certain and not arbitrary, become
altogether
unequal. Let the tax be light or heavy, uncertainty is
always
a great grievance. In a light tax, a considerable degree
of
inequality may be supported; in a heavy one, it is altogether
intolerable.
In the
different poll-taxes which took place in England during
the
reign of William III. the contributors were, the greater part
of
them, assessed according to the degree of their rank; as
dukes,
marquises, earls, viscounts, barons, esquires, gentlemen,
the
eldest and youngest sons of peers, etc. All shop-keepers and
tradesmen
worth more than three hundred pounds, that is, the
better
sort of them, were subject to the same assessment, how
great
soever might be the difference in their fortunes. Their
rank
was more considered than their fortune. Several of those
who, in
the first poll-tax, were rated according to their
supposed
fortune were afterwards rated according to their rank.
Serjeants,
attorneys, and proctors at law, who, in the first
poll-tax,
were assessed at three shillings in the pound of their
supposed
income, were afterwards assessed as gentlemen. In the
assessment
of a tax which was not very heavy, a considerable
degree
of inequality had been found less insupportable than any
degree
of uncertainty.
In the
capitation which has been levied in France, without-any
interruption,
since the beginning of the present century, the
highest
orders of people are rated according to their rank, by an
invariable
tariff; the lower orders of people, according to what
is
supposed to be their fortune, by an assessment which varies
from
year to year. The officers of the king's court, the judges,
and
other officers in the superior courts of justice, the
officers
of the troops, etc are assessed in the first manner. The
inferior
ranks of people in the provinces are assessed in the
second.
In France, the great easily submit to a considerable
degree
of inequality in a tax which, so far as it affects them,
is not
a very heavy one; but could not brook the arbitrary
assessment
of an intendant.
The
inferior ranks of people must, in that country, suffer
patiently
the usage which their superiors think proper to give
them.
In
England, the different poll-taxes never produced the sum which
had
been expected from them, or which it was supposed they might
have
produced, had they been exactly levied. In France, the
capitation
always produces the sum expected from it. The mild
government
of England, when it assessed the different ranks of
people
to the poll-tax, contented itself with what that
assessment
happened to produce, and required no compensation for
the
loss which the state might sustain, either by those who could
not
pay, or by those who would not pay (for there were many
such),
and who, by the indulgent execution of the law, were not
forced
to pay. The more severe government of France assesses upon
each
generality a certain sum, which the intendant must find as
he can.
If any province complains of being assessed too high, it
may, in
the assessment of next year, obtain an abatement
proportioned
to the overcharge of the year before ; but it must
pay in
the mean time. The intendant, in order to be sure of
finding
the sum assessed upon his generality, was empowered to
assess
it in a larger sum, that the failure or inability of some
of the
contributors might be compensated by the overcharge of the
rest ;
and till 1765, the fixation of this surplus assessment was
left
altogether to his discretion. In that year, indeed, the
council
assumed this power to itself. In the capitation of the
provinces,
it is observed by the perfectly well informed author
of the
Memoirs upon the Impositions in France, the proportion
which
falls upon the nobility, and upon those whose privileges
exempt
them from the taille, is the least considerable. The
largest
falls upon those subject to the taille, who are assessed
to the
capitation at so much a-pound of what they pay to that
other
tax.
Capitation
taxes, so far as they are levied upon the lower ranks
of
people, are direct taxes upon the wages of labour, and are
attended
with all the inconveniencics of such taxes.
Capitation
taxes are levied at little expense ; and, where they
are
rigorously exacted, afford a very sure revenue to the state.
It is
upon this account that, in countries where the case,
comfort,
and security of the inferior ranks of people are little
attended
to, capitation taxes are very common. It is in general,
however,
but a small part of the public revenue, which, in a
great
empire, has ever been drawn from such taxes ; and the
greatest
sum which they have ever afforded, might always have
been
found in some other way much more convenient to the people.
Taxes
upon Consumable Commodities.
The
impossibility of taxing the people, in proportion to their
revenue,
by any capitation, seems to have given occasion to the
invention
of taxes upon consumable commodities. The state not
knowing
how to tax, directly and proportionably, the revenue of
its
subjects, endeavours to tax it indirectly by taxing their
expense,
which, it is supposed, will, in most cases, be nearly in
proportion
to their revenue. Their expense is taxed, by taxing
the
consumable commodities upon which it is laid out.
Consumable
commodities are either necessaries or luxuries.
By
necessaries I understand, not only the commodities which are
indispensibly
necessary for the support of life, but whatever the
custom
of the country renders it indecent for creditable people,
even of
the lowest order, to be without. A linen shirt, for
example,
is, strictly speaking, not a necessary of life. The
Greeks
and Romans lived, I suppose, very comfortably, though they
had no
linen. But in the present times, through the greater part
of
Europe, a creditable day-labourer would be ashamed to appear
in
public without a linen shirt, the want of which would be
supposed
to denote that disgraceful degree of poverty, which, it
is
presumed, nobody can well fall into without extreme bad
conduct.
Custom. in the same manner, has rendered leather shoes a
necessary
of life in England. The poorest creditable person, of
either
sex, would be ashamed to appear in public without them. In
Scotland,
custom has rendered them a necessary of life to the
lowest
order of men ; but not to the same order of women, who
may,
without any discredit, walk about barefooted. In France,
they
are necessaries neither to men nor to women; the lowest rank
of both
sexes appearing there publicly, without any discredit,
sometimes
in wooden shoes, and sometimes barefooted. Under
necessaries,
therefore, I comprehend, not only those things which
nature,
but those things which the established rules of decency
have
rendered necessary to the lowest rank of people. All other
things
I call luxuries, without meaning, by this appellation, to
throw
the smallest degree of reproach upon the temperate use of
them.
Beer and ale, for example, in Great Britain, and wine, even
in the
wine countries, I call luxuries. A man of any rank may,
without
any reproach, abstain totally from tasting such liquors.
Nature
does not render them necessary for the support of life ;
and
custom nowhere renders it indecent to live without them.
As the
wages of labour are everywhere regulated, partly by the
demand
for it, and partly by the average price of the necessary
articles
of subsistence; whatever raises this average price must
necessarily
raise those wages; so that the labourer may still be
able to
purchase that quantity of those necessary articles which
the
state of the demand for labour, whether increasing,
stationary,
or declining, requires that he should have.{See book
i.chap.
8} A tax upon those articles necessarily raises their
price
somewhat higher than the amount of the tax, because the
dealer,
who advances the tax, must generally get it back, with a
profit.
Such a tax must, therefore, occasion a rise in the wages
of
labour, proportionable to this rise of price.
It is
thus that a tax upon the necessaries of life operates
exactly
in the same manner as a direct tax upon the wages of
labour.
The labourer, though he may pay it out of his hand,
cannot,
for any considerable time at least, be properly said even
to
advance it. It must always, in the long-run, be advanced to
him by
his immediate employer, in the advanced state of wages.
His
employer, if he is a manufacturer, will charge upon the price
of his
goods the rise of wages, together with a profit, so that
the
final payment of the tax, together with this overcharge, will
fall
upon the consumer. If his employer is a farmer, the final
payment,
together with a like overcharge, will fall upon the rent
of the
landlord.
It is
otherwise with taxes upon what I call luxuries, even upon
those
of the poor. The rise in the price of the taxed
commodities,
will not necessarily occasion any rise in the wages
of
labour. A tax upon tobacco, for example, though a luxury of
the
poor, as well as of the rich, will not raise wages. Though it
is
taxed in England at three times, and in France at fifteen
times
its original price, those high duties seem to have no
effect
upon the wages of labour. The same thing maybe said of the
taxes
upon tea and sugar, which, in England and Holland, have
become
luxuries of the lowest ranks of people; and of those upon
chocolate,
which, in Spain, is said to have become so.
The
different taxes which, in Great Britain, have, in the course
of the
present century, been imposed upon spiritous liquors, are
not
supposed to have had any effect upon the wages of labour. The
rise in
the price of porter, occasioned by an additional tax of
three
shillings upon the barrel of strong beer, has not raised
the
wages of common labour in London. These were about eighteen
pence
or twenty pence a-day before the tax, and they are not more
now.
The high price of such commodities does not
necessarily diminish
the
ability of the inferior ranks of people to bring up families.
Upon
the sober and industrious poor, taxes upon such commodities
act as
sumptuary laws, and dispose them either to moderate, or to
refrain
altogether from the use of superfluities which they can
no
longer easily afford. Their ability to bring up families, in
consequence
of this forced frugality, instead of being
diminished,
is frequently, perhaps, increased by the tax. It is
the
sober and industrious poor who generally bring up the most
numerous
families, and who principally supply the demand for
useful
labour. All the poor, indeed, are
not sober and
industrious
; and the dissolute and disorderly might continue to
indulge
themselves in the use of such commodities, after this
rise of
price, in the same manner as before, without regarding
the
distress which this indulgence might bring upon their
families. Such disorderly persons, however, seldom
rear up
numerous
families, their children generally perishing from
neglect,
mismanagement, and the scantiness or unwholesomeness of
their
food. If by the strength of their constitution, they
survive
the hardships to which the bad conduct of their parents
exposes
them, yet the example of that bad conduct commonly
corrupts
their morals ; so that, instead of being useful to
society
by their industry, they become public nuisances by their
vices
and disorders. Through the advanced price of the luxuries
of the
poor, therefore, might increase somewhat the distress of
such
disorderly families, and thereby diminish somewhat their
ability
to bring up children, it would not probably diminish much
the
useful population of the country.
Any
rise in the average price of necessaries, unless it be
compensated
by a proportionable rise in the wages of labour, must
necessarily
diminish, more or less, the ability of the poor to
bring
up numerous families, and, consequently, to supply the
demand
for useful labour; whatever may be the state of that
demand,
whether increasing, stationary, or declining; or such as
requires
an increasing, stationary, or declining population.
Taxes
upon luxuries have no tendency to raise the price of any
other
commodities, except that of the commodities taxed. Taxes
upon
necessaries, by raising the wages of labour, necessarily
tend to
raise the price of all manufactures, and consequently to
diminish
the extent of their sale and consumption. Taxes upon
luxuries
are finally paid by the consumers of the commodities
taxed,
without any retribution. They fall
indifferently upon
every
species of revenue, the wages of labour, the profits of
stock,
and the rent of land. Taxes upon necessaries, so far as
they
affect the labouring poor, are finally paid, partly by
landlords,
in the diminished rent of their lands, and partly by
rich
consumers, whether landlords or others, in the advanced
price
of manufactured goods; and always with a considerable
overcharge.
The advanced price of such manufactures as are real
necessaries
of life, and are destined for the consumption of the
poor,
of coarse woollens, for example, must be compensated to the
poor by
a farther advancement of their wages. The middling and
superior
ranks of people, if they understood their own interest,
ought
always to oppose all taxes upon the necessaries of life, as
well as
all taxes upon the wages of labour. The final payment of
both
the one and the other falls altogether upon themselves, and
always
with a considerable overcharge.
They fall heaviest
upon
the landlords, who always pay in a double capacity ; in that
of
landlords, by the reduction, of their rent ; and in that of
rich consumers,
by the increase of their expense. The observation
of Sir
Matthew Decker, that certain taxes are, in the price of
certain
goods, sometimes repeated and accumulated four or five
times,
is perfectly just with regard to taxes upon the
necessaries
of life. In the price of leather,
for example,
you
must pay not only for the tax upon the leather of your own
shoes,
but for a part of that upon those of the shoemaker and the
tanner.
You must pay, too, for the tax upon the salt, upon the
soap, and
upon the candles which those workmen consume while
employed
in your service ; and for the tax upon the leather,
which
the saltmaker, the soap-maker, and the candle-maker
consume,
while employed in their service.
In
Great Britain, the principal taxes upon the necessaries of
life,
are those upon the four commodities just now mentioned,
salt,
leather, soap, and candles.
Salt is
a very ancient and a very universal subject of taxation.
It was
taxed among the Romans, and it is so at present in, I
believe,
every part of Europe. The quantity annually consumed by
any
individual is so small, and may be purchased so gradually,
that
nobody, it seems to have been thought, could feel very
sensibly
even a pretty heavy tax upon it. It is in England taxed
at
three shillings and fourpence a bushel; about three times the
original
price of the commodity. In some other countries, the tax
is
still higher. Leather is a real necessary of life. The use of
linen
renders soap such. In countries where
the winter nights
are
long, candles are a necessary instrument of trade.
Leather
and soap are in Great Britain taxed at three halfpence
a-pound;
candles at a penny; taxes which, upon the original price
of
leather, may amount to about eight or ten per cent. ; upon
that of
soap, to about twenty or five-and-twenty per cent. ; and
upon
that of candles to about fourteen or fifteen per cent.;
taxes
which, though lighter than that upon salt, are still very
heavy.
As all those four commodities are real necessaries of
life,
such heavy taxes upon them must increase somewhat the
expense
of the sober and industrious poor, and must consequently
raise
more or less the wages of their labour.
In a
country where the winters are so cold as in Great Britain,
fuel
is, during that season, in the strictest sense of the word,
a
necessary of life, not only for the purpose of dressing
victuals,
but for the comfortable subsistence of many different
sorts
of workmen who work within doors ; and coals are the
cheapest
of all fuel. The price of fuel has
so important an
influence
upon that of labour, that all over Great Britain,
manufactures
have confined themselves principally to the coal
contries;
other parts of the country, on account of the high
price
of this necessary article, not being able to work so cheap.
In some
manufactures, besides, coal is a necessary instrument of
trade ;
as in those of glass, iron, and all other metals. If a
bounty
could in any case be reasonable, it might perhaps be so
upon
the transportation of coals from those parts of the country
in
which they abound, to those in which they are wanted.
But the
legislature, instead of a bounty, has imposed a tax of
three
shillings and threepence a-ton upon coals carried
coastways;
which, upon most sorts of coal, is more than sixty per
cent.
of the original price at the coal pit.
Coals carried,
either
by land or by inland navigation, pay no duty. Where they
are
naturally cheap, they are consumed duty free ; where they are
naturally
dear, they are loaded with a heavy duty.
Such
taxes, though they raise the price of subsistence, and
consequently
the wages of labour, yet they afford a considerable
revenue
to government, which it might not be easy to find in any
other
way. There may, therefore, be good reasons for continuing
them.
The bounty upon the exportation of corn, so far us it
tends,
in the actual state of tillage, to raise the price of that
necessary
article, produces all the like bad effects ; and
instead
of affording any revenue, frequently occasions a very
great
expense to government. The high duties upon the importation
of
foreign corn, which, in years of moderate plenty, amount to a
prohibition;
and the absolute prohibition of the importation,
either
of live cattle, or of salt provisions, which takes place
in the
ordinary state of the law, and which, on account of the
scarcity,
is at present suspended for a limited time with regard
to
Ireland and the British plantations, have all had the bad
effects
of taxes upon the necessaries of life, and produce no
revenue
to government. Nothing seems necessary for the repeal of
such
regulations, but to convince the public of the futility of
that
system in consequence of which they have been established.
Taxes
upon the necessaries of life are much higher in many other
countries
than in Great Britain. Duties upon flour and meal when
ground
at the mill, and upon bread when baked at the oven, take
place
in many countries. In Holland the
money-price of the:
bread
consumed in towns is supposed to be doubled by means of
such
taxes. In lieu of a part of them, the people who live in the
country,
pay every year so much a-head, according to the sort of
bread
they are supposed to consume. Those who consume wheaten
bread
pay three guilders fifteen stivers; about six shillings and
ninepence
halfpenny. Those, and some other taxes of the same
kind,
by raising the price of labour, are said to have ruined the
greater
part of the manufactures of Holland {Memoires concernant
les
Droits, etc. p. 210, 211.}. Similar taxes, though not quite
so
heavy, take place in the Milanese, in the states of Genoa, in
the
duchy of Modena, in the duchies of Parma, Placentia, and
Guastalla,
and the Ecclesiastical state. A French author {Le
Reformateur}
of some note, has proposed to reform the finances of
his
country, by substituting in the room of the greater part of
other
taxes, this most ruinous of all taxes. There is nothing so
absurd,
says Cicero, which has not sometimes been asserted by
some philosophers.
Taxes
upon butcher's meat are still more common than those upon
bread.
It may indeed be doubted, whether butcher's meat is any
where a
necessary of life. Grain and other vegetables, with the
help of
milk, cheese, and butter, or oil, where butter is not to
be had,
it is known from experience, can, without any butcher's
meat,
afford the most plentiful, the most wholesome, the most
nourishing,
and the most invigorating diet. Decency nowhere
requires
that any man should eat butcher's meat, as it in most
places
requires that he should wear a linen shirt or a pair of
leather
shoes.
Consumable
commodities, whether necessaries or luxuries, may be
taxed
in two different ways. The consumer may either pay an
annual
sum on account of his using or consuming goods of a
certain
kind; or the goods may be taxed while they remain in the
hands
of the dealer, and before they are delivered to the
consumer.
The consumable goods which last a considerable time
before
they are consumed altogether, are most properly taxed in
the one
way ; those of which the consumption is either immediate
or more
speedy, in the other. The coach-tax and plate tax are
examples
of the former method of imposing ; the greater part of
the
other duties of excise and customs, of the latter.
A coach
may, with good management, last ten or twelve years. It
might
be taxed, once for all, before it comes out of the hands of
the
coach-maker. But it is certainly more convenient for the
buyer
to pay four pounds a-year for the privilege of keeping a
coach,
than to pay all at once forty or forty-eight pounds
additional
price to the coach-maker ; or a sum equivalent to what
the tax
is likely to cost him during the time he uses the same
coach. A service of plate in the same manner,
may last more
than a
century. It is certainly-easier for
the consumer to
pay
five shillings a-year for every hundred ounces of plate, near
one per
cent. of the value, than to redeem this long annuity at
five-and-twenty
or thirty years purchase, which would enhance the
price
at least five-and-twenty or thirty per cent. The
different
taxes which affect houses, are certainly more
conveniently
paid by moderate annual payments, than by a heavy
tax of
equal value upon the first building or sale of the house.
It was
the well-known proposal of Sir Matthew Decker, that all
commodities,
even those of which the consumption is either
immediate
or speedy, should be taxed in this manner; the dealer
advancing
nothing, but the consumer paying a certain annual sum
for the
licence to consume certain goods. The object of his
scheme
was to promote all the different branches of foreign
trade,
particularly the carrying trade, by taking away all duties
upon
importation and exportation, and thereby enabling the
merchant
to employ his whole capital and credit in the purchase
of
goods and the freight of ships, no part of either being
diverted
towards the advancing of taxes, The project, however, of
taxing,
in this manner, goods of immediate or speedy consumption,
seems
liable to the four following very important objections.
First,
the tax would be more unequal, or not so well proportioned
to the
expense and consumption of the different contributors, as
in the
way in which it is commonly imposed. The taxes upon ale,
wine,
and spiritous liquors, which are advanced by the dealers,
are
finally paid by the different consumers, exactly in
proportion
to their respective consumption. But if the tax were
to be
paid by purchasing a licence to drink those liquors, the
sober
would, in proportion to his consumption, be taxed much more
heavily
than the drunken consumer. A family which exercised great
hospitality,
would be taxed much more lightly than one who
entertained
fewer guests. Secondly, this mode of taxation, by
paying
for an annual, half-yearly, or quarterly licence to
consume
certain goods, would diminish very much one of the
principal
conveniences of taxes upon goods of speedy consumption;
the
piece-meal payment. In the price of threepence halfpenny,
which
is at present paid for a pot of porter, the different taxes
upon
malt, hops, and beer, together with the extraordinary profit
which
the brewer charges for having advanced than, may perhaps
amount
to about three halfpence. If a workman can conveniently
spare
those three halfpence, he buys a pot of porter. If he
cannot,
he contents himself with a pint; and, as a penny saved is
a penny
got, he thus gains a farthing by his temperance. He pays
the tax
piece-meal, as he can afford to pay it, and when he can
afford
to pay it, and every act of payment is perfectly
voluntary,
and what he can avoid if he chuses to do so.
Thirdly,
such
taxes would operate less as sumptuary laws. When the licence
was
once purchased, whether the purchaser drunk much or drunk
little,
his tax would be the same. Fourthly, if a workman were to
pay all
at once, by yearly, half-yearly, or quarlerly payments, a
tax
equal to what he at present pays, with little or no
inconveniency,
upon all the different pots and pints of porter
which
he drinks in any such period of time, the sum might
frequently
distress him very much. This mode of taxation,
therefore,
it seems evident, could never, without the most
grievous
oppression, produce a revenue nearly equal to what is
derived
from the present mode without any oppression. In several
countries,
however, commodities of an immediate or very speedy
consumption
are taxed in this manner. In Holland, people pay so
much
a-head for a licence to drink tea. I have already mentioned
a tax
upon bread, which, so far as it is consumed in farm houses
and
country villages, is there levied in the same manner.
The
duties of excise are imposed chiefly upon goods of home
produce,
destined for home consumption. They are imposed only
upon a
few sorts of goods of the most general use.
There can
never
be any doubt, either concerning the goods which are subject
to
those duties, or concerning the particular duty which each
species
of goods is subject to. They fall almost altogether upon
what I
call luxuries, excepting always the four duties above
mentioned,
upon salt, soap, leather, candles, and perhaps that
upon
green glass.
The
duties of customs are much more ancient than those of excise.
They
seem to have been called customs, as denoting customary
payments,
which had been in use for time immemorial. They appear
to have
been originally considered as taxes upon the profits of
merchants. During the barbarous times of feudal
anarchy,
merchants,
like all the other inhabitants of burghs, were
considered
as little better than emancipated bondmen, whose
persons
were despised, and whose gains were envied. The great
nobility,
who had consented that the king should tallage the
profits
of their own tenants, were not unwilling that he should
tallage
likewise those of an order of men whom it was much less
their
interest to protect. In those
ignorant times, it was
not
understood, that the profits of merchants are a subject not
taxable
directly ; or that the final payment of all such taxes
must
fall, with a considerable overcharge, upon the consumers.
The
gains of alien merchants were looked upon more unfavourably
than
those of English merchants. It was
natural, therefore.
that
those of the former should be taxed more heavily than those
of the
latter. This distinction between the
duties upon
aliens
and those upon English merchants, which was begun from
ignorance,
has been continued front the spirit of monopoly, or in
order
to give our own merchants an advantage, both in the home
and in
the foreign market.
With
this distinction, the ancient duties of customs were imposed
equally
upon all sorts of goods, necessaries as well its
luxuries,
goods exported as well as goods imported. Why should
the dealers
in one sort of goods, it seems to have been thought,
be more
favoured than those in another ? or why should the
merchant
exporter be more favoured than the merchant importer?
The
ancient customs were divided into three branches. The first,
and,
perhaps, the most ancient of all those duties, was that upon
wool
and leather. It seems to have been chiefly or altogether an
exportation
duty. When the woollen manufacture came to be
established
in England, lest the king should lose any part of his
customs
upon wool by the exportation of woollen cloths, a like
duty
was imposed upon them. The other
two branches were,
first,
a duty upon wine, which being imposed at so much a-ton,
was
called a tonnage; and, secondly, a duty upon all other goods,
which
being imposed at so much a-pound of their supposed value,
was
called a poundage. In the forty-seventh year of Edward III.,
a duty
of sixpence in the pound was imposed upon all goods
exported
and imported, except wools, wool-felts, leather, and
wines
which were subject to particular duties.
In the
fourteenth
of Richard II., this duty was raised to one shilling
in the
pound ; but, three years afterwards, it was again reduced
to
sixpence. It was raised to eightpence in the second year of
Henry
IV. ; and, in the fourth of the same prince, to one
shilling. From this time to the ninth year of
William III.,
this
duty continued at one shilling in the pound. The duties
of
tonnage and poundage were generally granted to the king by one
and the
same act of parliament, and were called the subsidy of
tonnage
and poundage. The subsidy of
poundage having
continued
for so long a time at one shilling in the pound, or at
five
per cent., a subsidy came, in the language of the customs,
to denote
a general duty of this kind of five per cent. This
subsidy,
which is now called the old subsidy, still continues to
be
levied, according to the book of rates established by the
twelfth
of Charles II. The method of
ascertnining, by a book
of rates,
the value of goods subject to this duty, is said to be
older
than the time of James I. The new subsidy, imposed by the
ninth
and tenth of William III., was an additional five per cent.
upon
the greater part of goods. The one-third and the two-third
subsidy
made up between them another five per cent. of which they
were
proportionable parts. The subsidy of 1747 made a fourth five
per
cent. upon the greater part of goods; and that of 1759, a
fifth
upon some particular sorts of goods. Besides those five
subsidies,
a great variety of other duties have occasionally been
imposed
upon particular sorts of goods, in order sometimes to
relieve
the exigencie's of the state, and sometimes to regulate
the
trade of the country, according to the principles of the
mercantile
system.
That
system has come gradually more and more into fashion. The
old
subsidy was imposed indifferently upon exportation, as well
as
importation. The four subsequent subsidies, as well as the
other
duties which have since been occasionally imposed upon
particular
sorts of goods, have, with a few exceptions, been laid
altogether
upon importation. The greater part of the ancient
duties
which had been imposed upon the exportation of the goods
of home
produce and manufacture, have either been lightened or
taken
away altogether. In most cases,
they have been taken
away.
Bounties have even been given upon the exportation of some
of
them. Drawbacks, too, sometimes of the whole, and, in most
cases,
of a part of the duties which are paid upon the
importation
of foreign goods, have been granted upon their
exportation.
Only half the duties imposed by the old subsidy upon
importation,
are drawn back upon exportation; but the whole of
those
imposed by the latter subsidies and other imposts are, upon
the
greater parts of the goods, drawn back in the same manner.
This
growing favour of exportation, and discouragmnent of
importation,
have suffered only a few exceptions, which chiefly
concern
the materials of some manufactures.
These our
merchants
and manufacturers are willing should come as cheap as
possible
to themselves, and as dear as possible to their rivals
and
competitors in other countries.
Foreign materiais are,
upon
this account, sometimes allowed to be imported duty-free;
spanish
wool, for example, flax, and raw linen yarn. The
exportation
of the materials of home produce, and of those which
are the
particular produce of our colonies, has sometimes been
prohibited,
and sometimes subjected to higher duties. The
exportation
of English wool has been prohibited. That of beaver
skins,
of beaver wool, and of gum-senega, has been subjected to
higher
duties ; Great Britain, by the conquests of Canada and
Senegal,
having got almost the monopoly of those commodities.
That
the mercantile system has not been very favourable to the
revenue
of the great body of the people, to the annual produce of
the
land and labour of the country, I have endeavoured to show in
the
fourth book of this Inquiry. It seems not to have been more
favourable
to the revenue of the sovereign; so far, at least, as
that
revenue depends upon the duties of customs.
In
consequence of that system, the importation of several sorts
of
goods has been prohibited altogether.
This prohibition
has, in
some cases, entirely prevented, and in others has very
much
diminished, the importation of those commodities, by
reducing
the importers to the necessity of smuggling. It has
entirely
prevented the importation of foreign wollens; and it has
very
much diminished that of foreign silks and velvets, In both
cases,
it has entirely annihilated the revenue of customs which
might
have been levied upon such importation.
The
high duties which have been imposed upon the importation of
many different
sorts of foreign goods in order to discourage
their
consumption in Great Britain, have, in many cases, served
only to
encourage smuggling, and, in all cases, have reduced the
revenues
of the customs below what more moderate duties would
have afforded.
The saying of Dr. Swift, that in the arithmetic of
the
customs, two and two, instead of making four, make sometimes
only
one, holds perfectly true with regard to such heavy duties,
which
never could have been imposed, had not the mercantile
system
taught us, in many cases, to employ taxation as an
instrument,
not of revenue, but of monopoly.
The
bounties which are sometimes given upon the exportation of
home
produce and manufactures, and the drawbacks which are paid
upon
the re-exportation of the greater part of foreign goods,
have
given occasion to many frauds, and to a species of
smuggling,
more destructive of the public revenue than any other.
In
order to obtain the bounty or drawback, the goods, it is well
known,
are sometimes shipped, and sent to sea, but soon
afterwards
clandestinely re-landed in some other part of the
country.
The defalcation of the revenue of customs occasioned by
bounties
and drawbacks, of which a great part are obtained
fraudulently,
is very great. The gross produce of
the
customs,
in the year which ended on the 5th of January 1755,
amounted
to £5,068,000. The bounties which
were paid out of
this
revenue, though in that year there was no bounty upon corn,
amounted
to £167,806. The drawbacks which
were paid upon
debentures
and certificates, to £2,156,800. Bounties and
drawbacks
together amounted to £2,324,600. In consequence of
these
deductions, the revenue of the customs amounted only to
£2,743,400
; from which deducting £287,900 for the expense of
management,
in salaries and other incidents, the neat revenue of
the
customs for that year comes out to be £2,455,500. The expense
of
management, amounts, in this manner, to between five and six
per
cent. upon the gross revenue of the customs ; and to
something
more than ten per cent. upon what remains of that
revenue,
after deducting what is paid away in bounties and
drawbacks.
Heavy
duties being imposed upon almost all goods imported, our
merchant
importers smuggle as much, and make entry of as little
as they
can. Our merchant exporters, on the contrary, make entry
of more
than they export ; sometimes out of vanity, and to pass
for
great dealers in goods which pay no duty gain a bounty back.
Our
exports, in consequence of these different frauds, appear
upon
the custom-house books greatly to overbalance our imports,
to the
unspeakable comfort of those politicians, who measure the
national
prosperity by what they call the balance of trade.
All
goods imported, unless particularly exempted, and such
exemptions
are not very numerous, are liable to some duties of
customs.
If any goods are imported, not mentioned in the book of
rates,
they are taxed at 4s:9¾d. for every twenty shillings
value,
according to the oath of the importer, that is, nearly at
five
subsidies, or five poundage duties. The book of rates is
extremely
comprehensive, and enumerates a great variety of
articles,
many of them little used, and, therefore, not well
known.
It is, upon this account, frequently uncertain under what
article
a particular sort of goods ought to be classed, and,
consequently
what duty they ought to pay. Mistakes with regard to
this
sometimes ruin the custom-house officer, and frequently
occasion
much trouble, expense, and vexation to the importer.
In
point of perspicuity, precision, and distinctness, therefore,
the
duties of customs are much inferior to those of excise.
In
order that the greater part of the members of any society
should
contribute to the public revenue, in proportion to their
respective
expense, it does not seem necessary. that every single
article
of that expense should be taxed. The revenue which is
levied
by the duties of excise is supposed to fall as equally
upon
the contributors as that which is levied by the duties of
customs;
and the duties of excise are imposed upon a few articles
only of
the most general used and consumption. It has been the
opinion
of many people, that, by proper management, the duties of
customs
might likewise, without any loss to the public revenue,
and
with great advantage to foreign trade, be confined to a few
articles
only.
The
foreign articles, of the most general
use and consumption in
Great
Britain, seem at present to consist chiefly in foreign
wines
and brandies ; in some of the productions of America and
the
West Indies, sugar, rum, tobacco, cocoa-nuts, etc. and in
some of
those of the East Indies, tea, coffee, china-ware,
spiceries
of all kinds, several sorts of piece-goods, etc.
These
different articles afford, the greater part of the perhaps,
at
present, revenue which is drawn from the duties of customs.
The
taxes which at present subsist upon foreign manufactures, if
you
except those upon the few contained in the foregoing
enumeration,
have, the greater part of them, been imposed for the
purpose,
not of revenue, but of monopoly, or to give our own
merchants
an advantage in the home market. By removing all
prohibitions,
and by subjecting all foreign manufactures to such
moderate
taxes, as it was found from experience, afforded upon
each
article the greatest revenue to the public, our own workmen
might
still have a considerable advantage in the home market ;
and
many articles, some of which at present afford no revenue to
government,
and others a very inconsiderable one, might afford a
very
great one.
High
taxes, sometimes by diminishing the consumption of the taxed
commodities,
and sometimes by encouraging smuggling frequently
afford
a smaller revenue to government than what might be drawn
from
more moderate taxes.
When
the diminution of revenue is the effect of the diminutiun of
consumption,
there can be but one remedy, and that is the
lowering
of the tax.
When
the diminution of revenue is the effect of the encouragement
given
to smuggling, it may, perhaps, be remedied in two ways;
either
by diminishing the temptation to smuggle, or by increasing
the
difficulty of smuggling. The temptation to smuggle can be
diminished
only by the lowering of the tax ; and the difficulty
of
smuggling can be increased only by establishing that system of
administration
which is most proper for preventing it.
The
excise laws, it appears, I believe, from experience, obstruct
and
embarrass the operations of the smuggler much more
effectually
than those of the customs. By introducing into the
customs
a system of administration as similar to that of the
excise
as the nature of the different duties will admit, the
difficulty
of smuggling might be very much increased. This
alteration,
it has been supposed by many people, might very
easily
be brought about.
The
importer of commodities liable to any duties of customs, it
has
been said, might, at his option, be allowed either to carry
them to
his own private warehouse ; or to lodge them in a
warehouse,
provided either at his own expense or at that of the
public,
but under the key of the custom-house officer, and never
to be
opened but in his presence. If the merchant carried them to
his own
private warehouse, the duties to be immediately paid, and
never
afterwards to be drawn back ; and that warehouse to be at
all
times subject to the visit and examination of the
custom-house
officer, in order to ascertain how far the quantity
contained
in it corresponded with that for which the duty had
been
paid. If he carried them to the public warehouse, no duty to
be paid
till they were taken out for home comsumption. If taken
out for
exportation, to be duty-free; proper security being
always
given that they should be so exported. The dealers in
those
particular commodities, either by wholesale or retail, to
be at
all times subject to the visit and examination of the
custom-house
officer; and to be obliged to justify, by proper
certificates,
the payment of the duty upon the whole quantity
contained
in their shops or warehouses. What are called the
excise
duties upon rum imported, are at present levied in this
manner
; and the same system of administration might, perhaps, be
extended
to all duties upon goods imported ; provided always that
those
duties were, like the duties of excise, confined to a few
sorts
of goods of the most general use and consumption. If they
were
extended to almost all sorts of goods, as at present, public
warehouses
of sufficient extent could not easily be provided; and
goods
of a very delicate nature, or of which the preservation
required
much care and attention, could not safely be trusted by
the
merchant in any warehouse but his own.
If, by
such a system of administration, smuggling to any
considerable
extent could be prevented, even under pretty high
duties
; and if every duty was occasionally either heightened or
lowered
according as it was most likely, either the one way or
the
other, to afford the greatest revenue to the state; taxation
being
always employed as an instrument of revenue, and never of
monopoly
; it seems not improbable that a revenue, at least equal
to the
present neat revenue of the customs, might be drawn from
duties
upon the importation of only a few sorts of goods of the
most general
use and consumption ; and that the duties of customs
might
thus be brought to the same degree of simplicity,
certainty,
and precision, as those of excise. What the revenue at
present
loses by drawbacks upon the re-exportation of foreign
goods,
which are afterwards re-landed and consumed at home,
would,
under this system, be saved altogether. If to this saving,
which
would alone be very considerable, were added the abolition
of all
bounties upon the exportation of home produce ; in all
cases
in which those bounties were not in reality drawbacks of
some
duties of excise which had before been advanced ; it cannot
well be
doubted, but that the neat revenue of customs might,
after
an alteration of this kind, be fully equal to what it had
ever been
before.
If, by
such a change of system, the public revenue suffered no
loss,
the trade and manufactures of the country would certainly
gain a
very considerable advantage. The trade in the commodities
not
taxed, by far the greatest number would be perfectly free,
and
might be carried on to and from all parts of the world with
every
possible advantage. Among those commodities would be
comprehended
all the necessaries of life, and all the materials
of
manufacture. So far as the free importation of the necessaries
of life
reduced their average money price in the home market, it
would
reduce the money price of labour, but without reducing in
any
respect its real recompence. The value of money is in
proportion
to the quantity of the necessaries of life which it
will
purchase. That of the necessaries of life is altogether
independent
of the quantity of money which can be had for them.
The
reduction in the money price of labour would necessarily be
attended
with a proportionable one in that of all home
manufactures,
which would thereby gain some advantage in all
foreign
markets. The price of some manufactures would be reduced,
in a
still greater proportion, by the free importation of the raw
materials.
If raw silk could be imported from China and Indostan,
duty-free,
the silk manufacturers in England could greatly
undersell
those of both France and Italy. There would be no
occasion
to prohibit the importation of foreign silks and
velvets.
The cheapness of their goods would secure to our own
workmen,
not only the possession of a home, but a very great
command
of the foreign market. Even the trade in the commodities
taxed,
would be carried on with much more advantage than at
present.
If those commodities were delivered out of the public
warehouse
for foreign exportation, being in this case exempted
from
all taxes, the trade in them would be perfectly free. The
carrying
trade, in all sorts of goods, would, under this system,
enjoy
every possible advantage. If these commodities were
delivered
out for home consumption, the importer not being
obliged
to advance the tax till he had an opportunity of selling
his
goods, either to some dealer, or to some consumer, he could
always
afford to sell them cheaper than if he had been obliged to
advance
it at the moment of importation. Under the same taxes,
the
foreign trade of consumption, even in the taxed commodities,
might
in this manner be carried on with much more advantage than
it is
at present.
It was
the object of the famous excise scheme of Sir Robert
Walpole,
to establish, with regard to wine and tobacco, a system
not
very unlike that which is here proposed. But though the bill
which
was then brought into Parliament, comprehended those two
commodities
only, it was generally supposed to be meant as an
introduction
to a more extensive scheme of the same kind.
Faction,
combined with the interest of smuggling merchants,
raised
so violent, though so unjust a clamour, against that bill,
that
the minister thought proper to drop it ; and, from a dread
of
exciting a clamour of the same kind, none of his successors
have
dared to resume the project.
The
duties upon foreign luxuries, imported for home consumption,
though
they sometimes fall upon the poor, fall principally upon
people
of middling or more than middling fortune. Such are, for
example,
the duties upon foreign wines, upon coffee, chocolate,
tea,
sugar, etc.
The
duties upon the cheaper luxuries of home produce, destined
for
home consumption, fall pretty equally upon people of all
ranks,
in proportion to their respective expense. The poor pay
the
duties upon malt, hops, beer, and ale, upon their own
consumption
; the rich, upon both their own consumption and that
of
their servants.
The
whole consumption of the inferior ranks of people, or of
those
below the middling rank, it must be observed, is, in every
country,
much greater, not only in quantity, but in value, than
that of
the middling, and of those above the middling rank. The
whole
expense of the inferior is much greater titan that of the
superior
ranks. In the first place, almost the whole capital of
every
country is annually distributed among the inferior ranks of
people,
as the wages of productive labour.
Secondly, a great
part of
the revenue, arising from both the rent of land and the
profits
of stock, is annually distributed among the same rank, in
the
wages and maintenance of menial servants, and other
unproductive
labourers. Thirdly, some part of the profits of
stock
belongs to the same rank, as a revenue arising from the
employment
of their small capitals. The amount of the profits
annually
made by small shopkeepers, tradesmen, and retailers of
all
kinds, is everywhere very considerable, and makes a very
considerable
portion of the annual produce. Fourthly and lastly,
some
part even of the rent of land belongs to the same rank ; a
considerable
part to those who are somewhat below the middling
rank,
and a small part even to the lowest rank ; common labourers
sometimes
possessing in property an acre or two of land. Though
the
expense of those inferior ranks of people, therefore, taking
them
individually, is very small, yet the whole mass of it,
taking
them collectively, amounts always to by much the largest
portion
of the whole expense of the society ; what remains of the
annual
produce of the land and labour of the country, for the
consumption
of the superior ranks, being always much less, not
only in
quantity, but in value. The taxes upon expense,
therefore,
which fall chiefly upon that of the superior ranks of
people,
upon the smaller portion of the annual produce, are
likely
to be much less productive than either those which fall
indifferently
upon the expense of all ranks, or even those which
fall
chiefly upon that of the inferior ranks, than either those
which
fall indifferently upon the whole annual produce, or those
which
fall chiefly upon the larger portion of it. The excise upon
the
materials and manufacture of home-made fermented and
spirituous
liquors, is, accordingly, of all the different taxes
upon
expense, by far the most productive ; and this branch of the
excise
falls very much, perhaps principally, upon the expense of
the
common people. In the year which ended on the 5th of July
1775,
the gross produce of this branch of the excise amounted to
£3,341,837:9:9.
It must
always be remembered, however, that it is the luxuries,
and not
the necssary expense of the inferior ranks of people,
that
ought ever to be taxed. The final payment of any tax upon
their
necessary expense, would fall altogether upon the superior
ranks
of people; upon the smaller portion of the annual produce,
and not
upon the greater. Such a tax must, in all cases, either
raise
the wages of labour, or lessen the demand for it. It could
not
raise the wages of labour, without throwing the final payment
of the
tax upon the superior ranks of people. It could not lessen
the
demand for labour, without lessening the annual produce of
the
land and labour of the country, the fund upon which all taxes
must be
finally paid. Whatever might be the state to which a tax
of this
kind reduced the demand for labour, it must always raise
wages
higher than they otherwise would be in that state ; and the
final
payment of this enhancement of wages must, in all cases,
fall
upon the superior ranks of people.
Fermented
liquors brewed, and spiritous liquors distilled, not
for
sale, but for private use, are not in Great Britain liable to
any
duties of excise. This exemption, of which the object is to
save
private families from the odious visit and examination of
the
tax-gatherer, occasions the burden of those duties to fall
frequently
much lighter upon the rich than upon the poor. It is
not,
indeed, very common to distil for private use, though it is
done
sometimes. But in the country, many middling and almost all
rich
and great families, brew their own beer. Their strong beer,
therefore,
costs them eight shillings a-barrel less than it costs
the
common brewer, who must have his profit upon the tax, as well
as upon
all the other expense which he advances. Such families,
therefore,
must drink their beer at least nine or ten shillings
a-barrel
cheaper than any liquor of the same quality can be drank
by the
common people, to whom it is everywhere more convenient to
buy
their beer, by little and little, from the brewery or the
ale-house.
Malt, in the same manner, that is made for the use of
a
private family, is not liable to the visit or examination of
the
tax-gatherer but, in this case the family must compound at
seven
shillings and sixpence a-head for the tax. Seven shillings
and
sixpence are equal to the excise upon ten bushels of malt; a
quantity
fully equal to what all the different members of any
sober
family, men, women, and children, are, at an average,
likely
to consume. But in rich and great families, where country
hospitality
is much practised, the malt liqours consumed by the
members
of the family make but a small part of the consmnption of
the
house. Either on account of this composition, however, or for
other
reasons, it is not near so common to malt as to brew for
private
use. It is difficult to imagine any equitable reason, why
those
who either brew or distil for private use should not be
subject
to a composition of the same kind.
A
greater revenue than what is at present drawn from all the
heavy
taxes upon malt, beer, and ale, might be raised, it has
frequently
been said, by a much lighter tax upon malt; the
opportunities
of defrauding the revenue being much greater in a
brewery
than in a malt-house ; and those who brew for private use
being
exempted from all duties or composition for duties, which
is not
the case with those who malt for private use.
In the
porter brewery of London, a quarter of malt is commonly
brewed
into more than two barrels and a-half, sometimes into
three
barrels of porter. The different taxes upon malt amount to
six
shillings a-quarter ; those upon strong ale and beer to eight
shillings
a-barrel. In the porter brewery, therefore, the
different
taxes upon malt, beer, and ale, amount to between
twenty-six
and thirty shillings upon the produce of a quarter of
malt.
In the country brewery for common country sale, a quarter
of malt
is seldom brewed into less than two barrels of strong,
and one
barrel of small beer ; frequently into two barrels and
a-half
of strong beer. The different taxes upon small beer amount
to one
shilling and fourpence a-barrel. In the country brewery,
therefore,
the different taxes upon malt, beer, and ale, seldom
amount
to less than twenty-three shillings and fourpence,
frequently
to twenty-six shillings, upon the produce of a quarter
of
malt. Taking the whole kingdom at an average, therefore, the
whole
amount of the duties upon malt, beer, and ale, cannot be
estimated
at less than twenty-four or twenty-five shillings upon
the
produce of a quarter of malt. But by taking off all the
different
duties upon beer and ale, and by trebling the malt tax,
or by
raising it from six to eighteen shilling's upon the quarter
of
malt, a greater revenue, it is said, might be raised by this
single
tax, than what is at present drawn from all those heavier
taxes.
In
1772, the old malt tax produced.........
£722,023: 11 : 11
The additional....£356,776: 7 :
9¾
In
1775, the old tax protluced....... ...... £561,627: 3 : 7½
The
additonal... £278,650: 15 : 3¾
In
l774, the old tax produced ............ £624,614: 17 : 5¾
The
additional....£310,745: 2 : 8½
In
1775, the old tax produced .......
.....£657,357: 0 : 8¼
The
additional....£323,785: 12 : 6¼
£5,855,580: 12 : 0¾
Average
of these four years .............. £958,895:
3 : 0
In
1772, the country excise produced.......£1,243,120: 5 : 3
The London brewery 408,260: 7 : 2¾
In
1773, the country excise................£1,245,808: 3 : 3
The London brewery 405,406: 17 : 10½
In
1774, the country excise................£1,246,373: 14 : 5½
The London brewery 320,601: 18 : 0¼
In
1775, the country excise................£1,214,583: 6 : 1¼
The London brewery 463,670: 7 : 0¼
4)£6,547,832: 19 : 2¼
Average
of these four years
..............£1,636,958: 4
: 9½
To
which adding the average malt tax........
958,895: 3 : 0¼
The
whole amount of those different
taxes comes out to
be........£2,595,835: 7 : 10
But, by
trebling the malt tax,
or by
raising it from six to
eighteen
shillings upon the quarter
of
malt, that single tax would produce.....£2,876,685: 9 : 0
A sum
which exceeds the
foregoing by.... 280,832: 1 : 3
Under
the old malt tax, indeed, is comprehended a tax of four
shillings
upon the hogshead of cyder, and another of ten
shillings
upon the barrel of mum. In 1774, the tax upon cyder
produced
only £3,083:6:8. It probably fell somewhat short of its
usual
amount ; all the different taxes upon cyder, having, that
year,
produced less than ordinary. The tax upon mum, though much
heavier,
is still less productive, on account of the smaller
consumption
of that liquor. But to balance whatever may be the
ordinary
amount of those two taxes, there is comprehended under
what is
called the country excise, first, the old excise of six
shillings
and eightpence upon the hogshead of cyder; secondly, a
like
tax of six shillings and eightpence upon the hogshead of
verjuice;
thirdly, another of eight shillings and ninepence upon
the
hogshead of vinegar ; and, lastly, a fourth tax of
elevenpence
upon the gallon of mead or metheglin. The produce of
those
different taxes will probably much more than counterbalance
that of
the duties imposed, by what is called the annual malt
tax,
upon cyder and mum.
Malt is
consumed, not only in the brewery of beer and ale, but in
the
manufacture of low wines and spirits. If the malt tax were to
be
raised to eighteen shillings upon the quarter, it might be
necessary
to make some abatement in the different excises which
are
imposed upon those particular sorts of low wines and spirits,
of which
malt makes any part of the materials. In what are called
malt
spirits, it makes commonly but a third part of the
materials;
the other two-thirds being either raw barley , or
one-third
barley and one-third wheat. In the distillery of malt
spirits,
both the opportunity and the temptation to smuggle are
much
greater than either in a brewery or in a malt-house ; the
opportunity,
on account of the smaller bulk and greater value of
the
commodity, and the temptation, on account of the superior
height
of the duties, which amounted to 3s. 10 2/3d. upon the
gallon
of spirits.{Though the duties directly imposed upon proof
spirits
amount only to 2s. 6d per gallon, these, added to the
duties
upon the low wines, from which they are distilled, amount
to 3s
10 2/3d. Both low wines and proof spirits are, to prevent
frauds,
now rated according to what they gauge in the wash.}
By increasing the duties upon malt, and
reducing those upon
the
distillery, both the opportunities and the temptation to
smuggle
would be diminished, which might occasion a still further
augmentation
of revenue.
It has
for some time past been the policy of Great Britain to
discourage
the consumption of spiritous liquors, on account of
their
supposed tendency to ruin the health and to corrupt the
morals
of the common people. According to this policy, the
abatement
of the taxes upon the distillery ought not to be so
great
as to reduce, in any respect, the price of those liquors.
Spiritous
liquors might remain as dear as ever; while, at the
same
time, the wholesome and invigorating liquors of beer and ale
might
be considerably reduced in their price.
The people might
thus be
in part relieved from one of the burdens of which they at
present
complain the most; while, at the same time, the revenue
might
be considerably augmented.
The
objections of Dr. Davenant to this alteration in the present
system
of excise duties, seem to be without foundation. Those
objections
are, that the tax, instead of dividing itself, as at
present,
pretty equally upon the profit of the maltster, upon
that of
the brewer and upon that of the retailer, would so far as
it
affected profit, fall altogether upon that of the maltster ;
that
the maltster could not so easily get back the amount of the
tax in
the advanced price of his malt, as the brewer and retailer
in the
advanced price of their liquor; and that so heavy a tax
upon
malt might reduce the rent and profit of barley land.
No tax
can ever reduce, for any considerable time, the rate of
profit
in any particular trade, which must always keep its level
with
other trades in the neighbourhood. The present duties upon
malt,
beer, and ale, do not affect the profits of the dealers in
those
commodities, who all get back the tax with an additional
profit,
in the enhanced price of their goods. A tax, indeed, may
render
the goods upon which it is imposed so dear, as to diminish
the
consumption of them. But the consumption of malt is in malt
liquors;
and a tax of eighteen shillings upon the quarter of malt
could
not well render those liquors dearer than the different
taxes,
amounting to twenty-four or twenty-five shillings, do at
present. Those liquors, on the contrary, would
probably
become
cheaper, and the consumption of them would be more likely
to
increase than to diminish.
It is
not very easy to understand why it should be more difficult
for the
maltster to get back eighteen shillings in the advanced
price
of his malt, than it is at present for the brewer to get
back
twenty-four or twenty-five, sometimes thirty shillings, in
that of
his liquor. The maltster, indeed, instead of a tax of six
shillings,
would be obliged to advance one of eighteen shilling
upon
every quarter of malt. But the brewer is at present obliged
to
advance a tax of twenty-four or twentyfive, sometimes thirty
shillings,
upon every quarter of malt which he brews.
It
could
not be more inconvenient for the maltster to advance a
lighter
tax, than it is at present for the brewer to advance a
heavier
one. The maltster does not always keep in his granaries a
stock
of malt, which it will require a longer time to dispose of
than
the stock of beer and ale which the brewer frequently keeps
in his
cellars. The former, therefore, may frequently get the
returns
of his money as soon as the latter. But whatever
inconveniency
might arise to the maltster from being obliged to
advance
a heavier tax, it could easily be remedied, by granting
him a
few months longer credit than is at present commonly given
to the
brewer.
Nothing
could reduce the rent and profit of barley land, which
did not
reduce the demand for barley. But a change of system,
which
reduced the duties upon a quarter of malt brewed into beer
and
ale, from twentyfour and twenty-five shillings to eighteen
shillings,
would be more likely to increase than diminish that
demand.
The rent and profit of barley land, besides, must always
be
nearly equal to those of other equally fertile and equally
well
cultivated land. If they were less,
some part of the
barley
land would soon be turned to some other purpose; and if
they
were greater, more land would soon be turned to the raising
of
barley. When the ordinary price of any particular produce of
land is
at what may be called a monopoly price, a tax upon it
necessarily
reduces the rent and profit of the land which grows
it. A
tax upon the produce of those precious vineyards, of which
the
wine falls so much short of the effectual demand, that its
price
is always above the natural proportion to that of the
produce
of other equally fertile and equally well cultivated
land,
would necessarily reduce the rent and profit of those
vineyards.
The price of the wines being already the highest that
could
be got for the quantity commonly sent to market, it could
not be
raised higher without diminishing that quantity ; and the
quantity
could not be diminished without still greater loss,
because
the lands could not be turned to any other equally
valuable
produce. The whole weight of the tax, therefore, would
fall
upon the rent and profit; properly upon the rent of the
vineyard.
When it has been proposed to lay any new tax upon
sugar,
our sugar planters have frequently complained that the
whole
weight of such taxes fell not upon the consumer, but upon
the
producer; they never having been able to raise the price of
their
sugar after the tax higher than it was before. The price
had, it
seems, before the tax, been a monopoly price ; and the
arguments
adduced to show that sugar was an improper subject of
taxation,
demonstrated perhaps that it was a proper one ; the
gains
of monopolists, whenever they can be come at, being
certainly
of all subjects the most proper. But the ordinary price
of
barley has never been a monopoly price ; and the rent and
profit
of barley land have never been above their natural
proportion
to those of other equally fertile and equally well
cultivated
land. The different taxes which have been imposed upon
malt,
beer, and ale, have never lowered the price of barley ;
have
never reduced the rent and profit of barley land. The price
of malt
to the brewer has constantly risen in proportion to the
taxes
imposed upon it ; and those taxes, together with the
different
duties upon beer and ale, have constantly either raised
the
price, or, what comes to the same thing, reduced the quality
of
those commodities to the consumer. The final payment of those
taxes
has fallen constantly upon the consumer, and not upon the
producer.
The
only people likely to suffer by the change of system here
proposed,
are those who brew for their own private use. But
the
exemption, which this superior rank of people at present
enjoy,
from very heavy taxes which are paid by the poor labourer
and
artificer, is surely most unjust and unequal, and ought to be
taken
away, even though this change was never to take place. It
has
probably been the interest of this superior order of people,
however,
which has hitnerto prevented a change of system that
could
not well fail both to increase the revenue and to relieve
the
people.
Besides
such duties as those of custom and excise above
mentioned,
there are several others which affect the price of
goods
more unequally and more indirectly. Of this kind are the
duties,
which, in French, are called peages, which in old Saxon
times
were called the duties of passage, and which seem to have
been
originally established for the same purpose as our turnpike
tolls,
or the tolls upon our canals and navigable rivers, for the
maintenance
of the road or of the navigation. Those duties, when
applied
to such purposes, are most properly imposed according to
the
bulk or weight of the goods. As they were originally local
and
provincial duties, applicable to local and provincial
purposes,
the administration of them was, in most cases,
entrusted
to the particular town, parish, or lordship, in which
they
were levied; such communities being, in some way or other,
supposed
to be accountable for the application.
The
sovereign,
who is altogether unaccountable, has in many countries
assumed
to himself the administration of those duties; and though
he has
in most cases enhanced very much the duty, he has in many
entirely
neglected the application. If the
turnpike tolls of
Great
Britain should ever become one of the resources of
government,
we may learn, by the example of many other nations,
what
would probably be the consequence.
Such tolls, no doubt,
are
finally paid by the consumer; but the consumer is not taxed
in
proportion to his expense, when he pays, not according to the
value,
but according to the bulk or weight of what he consumes.
When
such duties are imposed, not according to the bulk or
weight,
but according to the supposed value of the goods, they
become
properly a sort of inland customs or excise, which
obstruct
very much the most important of all branches of
commerce,
the interior commerce of the country.
In some
small states, duties similar to those passage duties are
imposed
upon goods carried across the territory, either by land
or by
water, from one foreign country to another. These are in
some
countries called transit-duties.
Some of the little
Italian
states which are situated upon the Po, and the rivers
which
run into it, derive some revenue from duties of this kind,
which
are paid altogether by foreigners, and which, perhaps, are
the
only duties that one state can impose upon the subjects of
another,
without obstruction in any respect, the industry or
commerce
of its own. The most important transit-duty in the
world,
is that levied by the king of Denmark upon all merchant
ships
which pass through the Sound.
Such
taxes upon luxuries, as the greater part of the duties of
customs
and excise, though they all fall indifferently upon every
different
species of revenue, and are paid finally, or without
any
retribution, by whoever consumes the commodities upon which
they
are imposed ; yet they do not always fall equally or
proportionally
upon the revenue of every individual. As every
man's
humour regulates the degree of his consumption, every man
contributes
rather according to his humour, than proportion to
his
revenue: the profuse contribute more, the parsimonious less,
than
their proper proportion. During the minority of a man of
great fortune,
he contributes commonly very little, by his
consumption,
towards the support of that state from whose
protection
he derives a great revenue. Those who live in another
country,
contribute nothing by their consumption towards the
support
of the government of that country, in which is situated
the
source of their revenue. If in this latter country there
should
be no land tax, nor any considerable duty upon the
transference
either of moveable or immoveable property, as is the
case in
Ireland, such absentees may derive a great revenue from
the
protection of a government, to the support of which they do
not
contribute a single shilling. This inequality is likely to be
greatest
in a country of which the government is, in some
respects,
subordinate and dependant upon that of some other. The
people
who possess the most extensive property in the dependant,
will,
in this case, generally chuse to live in the governing
country. Ireland is precisely in this situation;
and we
cannot
therefore wonder, that the proposal of a tax upon
absentees
should be so very popular in that country. It might,
perhaps,
be a little difficult to ascertain either what sort, or
what
degree of absence, would subject a man to be taxed as an
absentee,
or at what precise time the tax should either begin or
end. If
you except, however, this very peculiar situation, any
inequality
in the contribution of individuals which can arise
from
such taxes, is much more than compensated by the very
circumstance
which occasions that inequality; the circumstance
that
every man's contribution is altogether voluntary ; it being
altogether
in his power, either to consume, or not to consume,
the
commodity taxed. Where such taxes,
therefore, are
properly
assessed, and upon proper commodities, they are paid
with
less grumbling than any other. When they are advanced by the
merchant
or manufacturer, the consumer, who finally pays them,
soon
comes to confound them with the price of the commodities,
and
almost forgets that he pays any tax.
Such
taxes are, or may be, perfectly certain; or may be assessed,
so as
to leave no doubt concerning either what ought to be paid,
or when
it ought to be paid; concerning either the quantity or
the
time of payment. What ever uncertainty there may sometimes
be,
either in the duties of customs in Great Britain, or in other
duties
of the same kind in other countries, it cannot arise from
the
nature of those duties, but from the inaccurate or unskilful
manner
in which the law that imposes them is expressed.
Taxes
upon luxuries generally are, and always may be, paid
piece-meal,
or in proportion as the contributors have occasion to
purchase
the goods upon which they are imposed. In the time and
mode of
payment, they are, or may be, of all taxes the most
convenient.
Upon the whole, such taxes, therefore, are perhaps as
agreeable
to the three first of the four general maxims
concerning
taxation, as any other. They offend
in every
respect
against the fourth.
Such
taxes, in proportion to what they bring into the public
treasury
of the state, always take out, or keep out, of the
pockets
of the people, more than almost any other taxes. They
seem to
do this in all the four different ways in which it is
possible
to do it.
First, the levying of such taxes, even when
imposed in the most
judicious
manner, requires a great number of custom-house and
excise
officers, whose salaries and perquisites are a real tax
upon
the people, which brings nothing into the treasury of the
state.
This expense, however, it must be acknowledged, is more
moderate
in Great Britain than in most other countries. In
the
year which ended on the 5th of July, 1775, the gross produce
of the
different duties, under the management of the
commissioners
of excise in England, amounted to £5,507,308:18:8¼,
which
was levied at an expense of little more than five and
a-half
per cent. From this gross produce,
however, there
must be
deducted what was paid away in bounties and drawbacks
upon
the exportation of exciseable goods, which will reduce the
neat
produce below five millions. {The neat produce of that year,
after
deducting all expenses and allowances, amounted to
£4,975,652:19:6.} The levying of the salt duty, and excise
duty,
but under a different management, is much more expensive.
The
neat revenue of the customs does not amount to two millions
and
a-half, which is levied at an expense of more than ten per
cent.,
in the salaries of officers and other incidents. But the
perquisites
of custom-house officers are everywhere much greater
than
their salaries ; at some ports more than double or triple
those
salaries. If the salaries of
officers, and other
incidents,
therefore, amount to more than ten per cent. upon the
neat
revenue of the customs, the whole expense of levying that
revenue
may amount, in salaries and perquisites together, to more
than
twenty or thirty per cent. The officers of excise receive
few or
no perquisites ; and the administration of that branch of
the revenue
being of more recent establishment, is in general
less
corrupted than that of the customs, into which length of
time
has introduced and authorised many abuses. By charging upon
malt
the whole revenue which is at present levied by the
different
duties upon malt and malt liquors, a saving, it is
supposed,
of more than £50,000, might be made in the annual
expense
of the excise. By confining the duties of customs to a
few
sorts of goods, and by levying those duties according to the
excise
laws, a much greater saving might probably be made in the
annual
expense of the customs.
Secondly,
such taxes necessarily occasion some obstruction or
discouragement
to certain branches of industry. As they always
raise
the price of the commodity taxed, they so far discourage
its
consumption, and consequently its production. If it is a
commodity
of home growth or manufacture, less labour comes to be
employed
in raising and producing it. If it is a foreign
commodity
of which the tax increases in this manner the price,
the
commodities of the same kind which are made at home may
thereby,
indeed, gain some advantage in the home market, and a
greater
quantity of domestic industry may thereby be turned
toward
preparing them. But though this rise of price in a foreign
cotnmodity,
may encourage domestic industry in one particular
branch,
it necessarily discourages that industry in almost every
other. The dearer the Birmingham manufacturer buys
his foreign
wine,
the cheaper he necessarily sells that part of his hardware
with
which, or, what comes to the same thing, with the price of
which,
he buys it. That part of his hardware, therefore, becomes
of less
value to him, and he has less encouragement to work at
it. The
dearer the consumers in one country pay for the surplus
produce
of another, the cheaper they necessarily sell that part
of
their own surplus produce with which, or, what comes to the
same
thing, with the price of which, they buy it. That part of
their
own surplus produce becomes of less value to them, and they
have
less encouragement to increase its quantity. All taxes
upon
consumable commodities, therefore, tend to reduce the
quantity
of productive labour below what it otherwise would be,
either
in preparing the commodities taxed, if they are home
commodities,
or in preparing those with which they are purchased,
if they
are foreign commodities. Such taxes, too, always alter,
more or
less, the natural direction of national industry, and
turn it
into a channel always different from, and generally less
advantageous,
than that in which it would have run of its own
accord.
Thirdly,
the hope of evading such taxes by smuggling, gives
frequent
occasion to forfeitures and other penalties, which
entirely
ruin the smuggler ; a person who, though no doubt highly
blameable
for violating the laws of his country, is frequently
incapable
of violating those of natural justice, and would have
been,
in every respect. an excellent citizen, had not the laws of
his
country made that a crime which nature never meant to be so.
In
those corrupted governments, where there is at least a general
suspicion
of much unnecessary expense, and great misapplication
of the
public revenue, the laws which guard it are little
respected.
Not many people are scrupulous about smuggling, when,
without
perjury, they can find an easy and safe opportunity of
doing
so. To pretend to have any scruple about buying smuggled
goods,
though a manifest encouragement to the violation of the
revenue
laws, and to the perjury which almost always attends it,
would,
in most countries. be regarded as one of those pedantic
pieces
of hypocrisy which, instead of gaining credit with
anybody,
serve only to expose the person who affects to practise
them to
the suspicion of buing a greater knave than most of his
neighbours.
By this indulgence of the public, the smuggler is
often
encouraged to continue a trade, which he is thus taught to
consider
as in some measure innocent; and when the severity of
the
revenue laws is ready to fall upon him, he is frequently
disposed
to defend with violence, what he has been accustomed to
regard
as his just property. From being at first, perhaps, rather
imprudent
than criminal, he at last too often becomes one of the
hardiest
and most determined violators of the laws of society. By
the
ruin of the smuggler, his capital, which had before been
employed
in maintaining productive labour, is absorbed either in
the
revenue of the state, or in that of the revenue officer; and
is
employed in maintaining unproductive, to the diminution of the
general
capital of the society, and of the useful industry which
it
might otherwise have maintained.
Fourthly,
such taxes, by subjecting at least the dealers in the
taxed
commodities, to the frequent visits and odious examination
of the
tax-gatherers, expose them sometimes, no doubt, to some
degree
of oppression, and always to much trouble and vexation;
and
though vexation, as has already been said, is not strictly
speaking
expense, it is certainly equivalent to the expense at
which
every man would be willing to redeem himself from it. The
laws of
excise, though more effectual for the purpose for which
they
were instituted, are, in this respect, more vexatious than
those
of the customs. When a merchant has imported goods subject
to
certain duties of customs; when he has paid those duties, and
lodged
the goods in his warehouse ; he is not, in most cases,
liable
to any further trouble or vexation from the custom-house
officer. It is otherwise with goods subject to duties
of excise.
The
dealers have no respite from the continual visits and
examination
of the excise officers. The duties of excise are,
upon
this account, more unpopular than those of the customs; and
so are
the officers who levy them. Those officers, it is
pretended,
though in general, perhaps, they do their duty fully
as well
as those of the customs ; yet, as that duty obliges them
to be
frequently very troublesome to some of their neighbours,
commonly
contract a certain hardness of character, which the
others
frequently have not. This observation, however, may very
probably
be the mere suggestion of fraudulent dealers, whose
smuggling
is either prevented or detected by their diligence.
The
inconveniencies, however, which are, perhaps, in some degree
inseparable
from taxes upon consumable communities, fall as light
upon
the people of Great Britain as upon those of any other
country
of which the government is nearly as expensive. Our
state
is not perfect, and might be mended; but it is as good, or
better,
than that of most of our neighbours.
In
consequence of the notion, that duties upon consumable goods
were
taxes upon the profits of merchants, those duties have, in
some
countries, been repeated upon every successive sale of the
goods. If the profits of the merchant-importer
or
merchant-manufacturer
were taxed, equality seemed to require that
those
of all the middle buyers, who intervened between either of
them
and the consumer, should likewise be taxed. The famous
alcavala
of Spain seems to have been established upon this
principle. It was at first a tax of ten per cent.
afterwards
of
fourteen per cent. and it is at present only six per cent.
upon
the sale of every sort of property whether moveable or
immoveable
; and it is repeated every time the property is
sold.{Memoires
concernant les Droits, etc. tom. i, p. 15}
The
levying
of this tax requires a multitude of revenue officers,
sufficient
to guard the transportation of goods, not only from
one
province to another, but from one shop to another. It
subjects,
not only the dealers in some sorts of goods, but those
in all
sorts, every farmer, every manufacturer, every merchant
and
shopkeeper, to the continual visit and examination of the
tax-gatherers. Through the greater part of the country
in
which a
tax of this kind is established, nothing can be produced
for
distant sale. The produce of every part of the country must
be
proportioned to the consumption of the neighbourhood. It is to
the
alcavala, accordingly, that Ustaritz imputes the ruin of the
manufactures
of Spain. He might have imputed to it, likewise, the
declension
of agriculture, it being imposed not only upon
manufactures,
but upon the rude produce of the land.
In the
kingdom of Naples, there is a similar tax of three per
cent.
upon the value of all contracts, and consequently upon that
of all
contracts of sale. It is both lighter than the Spanish
tax,
and the greater part of towns and parishes are allowed to
pay a
composition in lieu of it. They levy this composition in
what
manner they please, generally in a way that gives no
interruption
to the interior commerce of the place. The
Neapolitan
tax, therefore, is not near so ruinous as the Spanish
one.
The
uniform system of taxation, which, with a few exception of no
great
consequence, takes place in all the different parts of the
united
kingdom of Great Britain, leaves the interior commerce of
the
country, the inland and coasting trade, almost entirely free.
The
inland trade is almost perfectly free ; and the greater part
of
goods may be carried from one end of the kingdom to the other,
without
requiring any permit or let-pass, without being subject
to
question, visit or examination, from the revenue officers.
There
are a few exceptions, but they are such as can give no
interruption
to any important branch of inland commerce of the
country.
Goods carried coastwise, indeed, require certificates or
coast-cockets.
If you except coals, however, the rest are almost
all
duty-free. This freedom of interior commerce, the effect of
the
uniformity of the system of taxation, is perhaps one of the
principal
causes of the prosperity of Great Britain ; every great
country
being necessarily the best and most extensive market for
the
greater part of the productions of its own industry. If the
same
freedom in consequence of the same uniformity, could be
extended
to Ireland and the plantations, both the grandeur of the
state,
and the prosperity of every part of the empire, would
probably
be still greater than at present.
In
France, the different revenue laws which take place in the
different
provinces, require a multitude of revenue officers to
surround,
not only the frontiers of the kingdom, but those of
almost
each particular province, in order either to prevent the
importation
of certain goods, or to subject it to the payment of
certain
duties, to the no small interruption of the interior
commerce
of the country. Some provinces are allowed to commpound
for the
gabelle, or salt tax ; others are exempted from it
altogether.
Some provinces are exempted from the exclusive sale
of
tobacco, which the farmers-general enjoy through the greater
part of
the kingdom. The aides, which correspond to the excise in
England,
are very different in different provinces. Some
provinces
are exempted from them, and pay a composition or
equivalent.
In those in which they take place, and are in farm,
there
are many local duties which do not extend beyond a
particular
town or district. The traites, which correspond to our
customs,
divide the kingdom into three great parts; first, the
provinces
subject to the tariff of 1664, which are called the
provinces
of the five great farms, and under which are
comprehended
Picardy, Normandy, and the greater part of the
interior
provinces of the kingdom ; secondly, the provinces
subject
to the tariff of 1667, which are called the provinces
reckoned
foreign, and under which are comprehended the greater
part of
the frontier provinces; and, thirdly, those provinces
which
are said to be treated as foreign, or which, because they
are
allowed a free commerce with foreign countries, are, in their
commerce
with the other provinces of France, subjected to the
same
duties as other foreign countries. These are Alsace, the
three
bishoprics of Mentz, Toul, and Verdun, and the three cities
of
Dunkirk, Bayonne, and Marseilles. Both in the provinces of the
five
great farms (called so on account of an ancient division of
the
duties of customs into five great branches, each of which was
originally
the subject of a particular farm, though they are now
all
united into one), and in those which are said to be reckoned
foreign,
there are many local duties which do not extend beyond a
particular
town or district. There are some such even in the
provinces
which are said to be treated as foreign, particularly
in the
city of Marseilles. It is unnecessary to observe how much
both
the restraints upon the interior commerce of the country,
and the
number of the revenue officers, must be multiplied, in
order
to guard the frontiers of those different provinces and
districts
which are subject to such different systems of
taxation.
Over
and above the general restraints arising from this
complicated
system of revenue laws, the commerce of wine (after
corn,
perhaps, the most important production of France) is, in
the
greater part of the provinces, subject to particular
restraints
arising from the favour which has been shown to the
vineyards
of particular provinces and districts above those of
others.
The provinces most famous for their wines, it will be
found,
I believe, are those in which the trade in that article is
subject
to the fewest restraints of this kind. The extensive
market
which such provinces enjoy, encourages good management
both in
the cultivation of their vineyards, and in the subsequent
preparation
of their wines.
Such
various and complicated revenue laws are not peculiar to
France.
The little duchy of Milan is divided into six provinces,
in each
of which there is a different system of taxation, with
regard
to several different sorts of consumable goods. The still
smaller
territories of the duke of Parma are divided into three
or
four, each of which has, in the same manner, a system of its
own.
Under such absurd management, nothing but the great
fertility
of the soil, and happiness of the climate, could
preserve
such countries from soon relapsing into the lowest state
of
poverty and barbarism.
Taxes upon
consumable commodities may either he levied by an
administration,
of which the officers are appointed by
govermnent,
and are immediately accountable to government, of
which
the revenue must, in this case, vary from year to year,
according
to the occasional variations in the produce of the tax
; or
they may be let in farm for a rent certain, the farmer being
allowed
to appoint his own officers, who, though obliged to levy
the tax
in the manner directed by the law, are under his
immediate
inspection, and are immediately accountable to him. The
best
and most frugal way of levying a tax can never be by farm.
Over
and above what is necessary for paying the stipulated rent,
the
salaries of the officers, and the whole expense of
administration,
the farmer must always draw from the produce of
the tax
a certain profit, proportioned at least to the advance
which
he makes, to the risk which he runs, to the trouble which
he is
at, and to the knowledge and skill which it requires to
manage
so very complicated a concern. Government, by establishing
an
administration under their own immediate inspection, of the
same
kind with that which the farmer establishes, might at least
save
this profit, which is almost always exorbitant. To farm any
considerable
branch of the public revenue requires either a great
capital,
or a great credit; circumstances which would alone
restrain
the competition for such an undertaking to a very small
number
of people. Of the few who have this capital or credit, a
still
smaller number have the necessary knowledge or experience;
another
circumstance which restrains the competition still
further.
The very few who are in condition to become competitors,
find it
more for their interest to combine together ; to become
copartners,
instead of competitors; and, when the farm is set up
to
auction, to offer no rent but what is much below the real
value.
In countries where the public revenues are in farm, the
farmers
are generally the most opulent people. Their wealth would
alone
excite the public indignation; and the vanity which almost
always
accompanies such upstart fortunes, the foolish ostentation
with
which they commonly display that wealth, excite that
indignation
still more.
The
farmers of the public revenue never find the laws too severe,
which
punish any attempt to evade the payment of a tax. They have
no
bowels for the contributors, who are not their subjects, and
whose
universal bankruptcy, if it should happen the day after the
farm is
expired, would not much affect their interest. In the
greatest
exigencies of the state, when the anxiety of the
sovereign
for the exact payment of his revenue is necessarily the
greatest,
they seldom fail to complain, that without laws more
rigorous
than those which actually took place, it will be
impossible
for them to pay even the usual rent. In those moments
of
public distress, their commands cannot he disputed. The
revenue
laws, therefore, become gradually more and more severe.
The
most sanguinary are always to be found in countries where the
greater
part of the public revenue is in farm ; the mildest, in
countries
where it is levied under the immediate inspection of
the
sovereign. Even a bad sovereign feels more compassion for his
people
than can ever be expected from the farmers of his revenue.
He
knows that the permanent grandeur of his family depends upon
the
prosperity of his people, and he will never knowingly ruin
that
prosperity for the sake of any momentary interest of his
own. It
is otherwise with the farmers of his revenue, whose
grandeur
may frequently be the effect of the ruin, and not of the
prosperity,
of his people.
A tax
is sometimes not only farmed for a certain rent, but the
farmer
has, besides, the monopoly of the commodity taxed. In
France,
the duties upon tobacco and salt are levied in this
manner.
In such cases, the farmer, instead of one, levies two
exorbitant
profits upon the people; the profit of the farmer, and
the
still more exorbitant one of the monopolist. Tobacco being a
luxury,
every man is allowed to buy or not to buy as he chuses ;
but
salt being a necessary, every man is obliged to buy of the
farmer
a certain quantity of it ; because, if he did not buy this
quantity
of the farmer, he would, it is presumed, buy it of some
smuggler.
The taxes upon both commodities are exorbitant. The
temptation
to smuggle, consequently, is to many people
irresistible;
while, at the same time, the rigour of the law, and
the
vigilance of the farmer's officers, render the yielding to
the
temptation almost certainly ruinous.
The smuggling of
salt
and tobacco sends every year several hundred people to the
galleys,
besides a very considerable number whom it sends to the
gibbet.
Those taxes, levied in this manner, yield a very
considerable
revenue to government. In 1767, the farm of tobacco
was let
for twenty-two millions five hundred and forty-one
thousand
two hundred and seventy-eight livres a-year; that of
salt
for thirty-six millions four hundred and ninety-two thousand
four
hundred and four livres. The farm, in both cases, was to
commence
in 1768, and to last for six years. Those who consider
the
blood of the people as nothing, in comparison with the
revenue
of the prince, may, perhaps, approve of this method of
levying
taxes. Similar taxes and monopolies
of salt and
tobacco
have been established in many other countries,
particularly
in the Austrian and Prussian dominions, and in the
greater
part of the states of Italy.
In
France, the greater part of the actual revenue of the crown is
derived
from eight different sources; the taille, the capitation,
the two
vingtiemes, the gabelles, the aides, the traites, the
domaine,
and the farm of tobacco. The live last are, in the
greater
part of the provinces, under farm. The three first are
everywhere
levied by an administration, under the immediate
inspection
and direction of government ; and it is universally
acknowledged,
that in proportion to what they take out of the
pockets
of the people, they bring more into the treasury of the
prince
than the other five, of which the administration is much
more
wasteful and expensive.
The
finances of France seem, in their present state, to admit of
three
very obvious reformations. First, by
abolishing the
taille
and the capitation, and by increasing the number of the
vingtiemes,
so as to produce an additional revenue equal to the
amount
of those other taxes, the revenue of the crown might be
preserved;
the expense of collection might be much diminished ;
the vexation
of the inferior ranks of people, which the taille
and
capitation occassion, might be entirely prevented; and the
superior
ranks might not be more burdened than the greater part
of them
are at present. The vingtieme, I have already observed,
is a tax
very nearly of the same kind with what is called the
land
tax of England. The burden of the taille, it is
acknowledged,
falls finally upon the proprietors of land ; and as
the
greater part of the capitation is assessed upon those who are
subject
to the taille, at so much a-pound of that other tax, the
final
payment of the greater part of it must likewise fall upon
the
same order of people. Though the number of the vingtiemes,
therefore,
was increased, so as to produce an additional revenue
equal
to the amount of both those taxes, the superior ranks of
people
might not be more burdened than they are at present; many
individuals,
no doubt, would, on account of the great
inequalities
with which the taille is commonly assessed upon the
estates
and tenants of different individuals. The interest and
opposition
of such favoured subjects, are the obstacles most
likely
to prevent this, or any other reformation of the same
kind.
Secondly, by rendering the gabelle, the aides, the traites,
the
taxes upon tobacco, all the different customs and excises,
uniform
in all the different parts of the kingdom, those taxes
might
be levied at much less expense, and the interior commerce
of the
kingdom might be rendered as free as that of England.
Thirdly,
and lastly, by subjecting all those taxes to an
administration
under the immediate inspection and direction or
government,
the exorbitant profits of the farmers-general might
be
added to the revenue of the state. The opposition arising from
the
private inte rest of individuals, is likely to be as
effectual
for preventing the two last as the first-mentioned
scheme
of reformation.
The
French system of taxation seems, in every respect, inferior
to the
British. In Great Britain, ten millions sterling are
annually
levied upon less than eight millions of people, without
its
being possible to say that any particular order is oppressed.
From
the Collections of the Abbé Expilly, and the observations of
the
author of the Essay upon the Legislation and Commerce of
Corn,
it appears probable that France, including the provinces of
Lorraine
and Bar, contains about twenty-three or twenty-four
millions
of people; three times the number, perhaps, contained in
Great
Britain. The soil and climate of France are better than
those
of Great Britain. The country has been much longer in a
state
of improvement and cultivation, and is, upon that account,
better
stocked with all those things which it requires a long
time to
raise up and accumulate ; such as great towns, and
convenient
and well-built houses, both in town and country. With
these
advantages, it might be expected, that in France a revenue
of
thirty millions might be levied for the support of the state,
with as
little inconvenience as a revenue of ten millions is in
Great
Britain. In 1765 and 1766, the whole revenue paid into the
treasury
of France, according to the best, though, I acknowledge,
very
imperfect accounts which I could get of it, usually run
between
308 and 325 millions of livres ; that is, it did not
amount
to fifteen millions sterling; not the half of what might
have
been expected, had the people contributed in the same
proportion
to their numbers as the people of Great Britain. The
people
of France, however, it is generally acknowledged, are much
more
oppressed by taxes than the people of Great Britain. France,
however,
is certainly the great empire in Europe, which, after
that of
Great Britain, enjoys the mildest and most indulgent
government.
In
Holland, the heavy taxes upon the necessaries of life have
ruined,
it is said, their principal manufacturers, and are likely
to
discourage, gradually, even their fisheries and their trade in
ship-building.
The taxes upon the necessaries of life are
inconsiderable
in Great Britain, and no manufacture has hitherto
been
ruined by them. The British taxes which bear hardest on
manufactures,
are some duties upon the importation of raw
materials,
particularly upon that of raw silk. The revenue of the
States-General
and of the different cities, however, is said to
amount
to more than five millions two hundred and fifty thousand
pounds
sterling ; and as the inhabitants of the United Provinces
cannot
well be supposed to amount to more than a third part of
those
of Great Britain, they must, in proportion to their number,
be much
more heavily taxed.
After
all the proper subjects of taxation have been exhausted, if
the
exigencies of the state still continue to require new taxes,
they
must be imposed upon improper ones. The taxes upon the
necessaries
of life, therefore, may be no impeachment of the
wisdom
of that republic, which, in order to acquire and to
maintain
its independency, has, in spite of its meat frugality,
been
involved in such expensive wars as have obliged it to
contract
great debts. The singular countries of Holland and
Zealand,
besides, require a considerable expense even to preserve
their
existence, or to prevent their being swallowed up by the
sea,
which must have contributed to increase considerably the
load of
taxes in those two provinces. The republican form of
government
seems to be the principal support of the present
grandeur
of Holland. The owners of great capitals, the great
mercantile
families, have generally either some direct share, or
some
indirect influence, in the administration of that
government.
For the sake of the respect and authority which they
derive
from this situation, they are willing to live in a country
where
their capital, if they employ it themselves, will bring
them
less profit, and if they lend it to another, less interest;
and
where the very moderate revenue which they can draw from it
will
purchase less of the necessaries and conveniencies of life
than in
any other part of Europe. The residence of such wealthy
people necessarily
keeps alive, in spite of all disadvantages, a
certain
degree of industry in the country. Any public calamity
which
should destroy the republican form of government, which
should
throw the whole administration into the hands of nobles
and of
soldiers, which should annihilate altogether the
importance
of those wealthy merchants, would soon render it
disagreeable
to them to live in a country where they were no
longer
likely to be much respected. They would remove both their
residence
and their capital to some other country, and the
industry
and commerce of Holland would soon follow the capitals
which
supported them.
CHAPTER III.
OF
PUBLIC DEBTS.
In that
rude state of society which precedes the extension of
commerce
and the improvement of manufactures ; when those
expensive
luxuries, which commerce and manufactures can alone
introduce,
are altogether unknown ; the person who possesses a
large
revenue, I have endeavoured to show in the third book of
this
Inquiry, can spend or enjoy that revenue in no other way
than by
maintaining nearly as many people as it can maintain. A
large
revenue may at all times be said to consist in the command
of a
large quantity of the necessaries of life. In that rude
state
of things, it is commonly paid in a large quantity of those
necessaries,
in the materials of plain food and coarse clothing,
in corn
and cattle, in wool and raw hides. When neither commerce
nor
manufactures furnish any thing for which the owner can
exchange
the greater part of those materials which are over and
above
his own consumption, he can do nothing with the surplus,
but
feed and clothe nearly as many people as it will feed and
clothe.
A hospitality in which there is no luxury, and a
liberality
in which there is no ostentation, occasion, in this
situation
of things, the principal expenses of the rich and the
great.
But these I have likewise endeavoured to show, in the same
book,
are expenses by which people are not very apt to ruin
themselves.
There is not, perhaps, any selfish pleasure so
frivolous,
of which the pursuit has not sometimes ruined even
sensible
men. A passion for cock-fighting has ruined many. But
the
instances, I believe, are not very numerous, of people who
have
been ruined by a hospitality or liberality of this kind;
though
the hospitality of luxury, and the liberality of
ostentation
have ruined many. Among our feudal ancestors, the
long
time during which estates used to continue in the same
family,
sufficiently demonstrates the general disposition of
people
to live within their income. Though the rustic
hospitality,
constantly exercised by the great landholders, may
not, to
us in the present times, seem consistent with that order
which
we are apt to consider as inseparably connected with good
economy;
yet we must certainly allow them to have been at least
so far
frugal, as not commonly to have spent their whole income.
A part
of their wool and raw hides, they had generally an
opportunity
of selling for money. Some part of this money,
perhaps,
they spent in purchasing the few objects of vanity and
luxury,
with which the circumstances of the times could furnish
them ;
but some part of it they seem commonly to have hoarded.
They
could not well, indeed, do any thing else but hoard whatever
money
they saved. To trade, was disgraceful to a gentleman; and
to lend
money at interest, which at that time was considered as
usury,
and prohibited bylaw, would have been still more so. In
those
times of violence and disorder, besides, it was convenient
to have
a hoard of money at hand, that in case they should be
driven
from their own home, they might have something of known
value
to carry with them to some place of safety. The same
violence
which made it convenient to hoard, made it equally
convenient
to conceal the hoard. The frequency of treasure-trove,
or of
treasure found, of which no owner was known, sufficiently
demonstrates
the frequency, in those times, both of hoarding and
of
concealing the hoard. Treasure-trove was then considered as an
important
branch of the revenue of the sovereign.
All the
treasure-truve
of the kingdom would scarce, perhaps, in the
present
times, make an important branch of the revenue of a
private
gentleman of a good estate.
The
same disposition, to save and to hoard, prevailed in the
sovereign,
as well as in the subjects. Among nations, to whom
commerce
and manufacture are little known, the sovereign, it has
already
been observed in the Fourth book, is in a situation which
naturally
disposes him to the parsimony requisite for
accumulation.
In that situation, the expense, even of a
sovereign,
cannot be directed by that vanity which delights in
the
gaudy finery of a court. The ignorance of the times affords
but few
of the trinkets in which that finery consists. Standing
armies
are not then necessary; so that the expense, even of a
sovereign,
like that of any other great lord can be employed in
scarce
any thing but bounty to his tenants, and hospitality to
his
retainers. But bounty and hospitality very seldom lead to
extravagance;
though vanity almost always does. All the ancient
sovereigns
of Europe, accordingly, it has already been observed,
had
treasures. Every Tartar chief, in the present times, is said
to have
one.
In a
commercial country, abounding with every sort of expensive
luxury,
the sovereign, in the same manner as almost all the great
proprietors
in his dominions, naturally spends a great part of
his
revenue in purchasing those luxuries. His own and the
neighbouring
countries supply him abundantly with all the costly
trinkets
which compose the splendid, but insignificant, pageantry
of a
court. For the sake of an inferior pageantry of the same
kind,
his nobles dismiss their retainers, make their tenants
independent,
and become gradually themselves as insignificant as
the
greater part of the wealthy burghers in his dominions.
The
same frivolous passions, which influence their conduct,
influence
his. How can it be supposed that he should be the only
rich man
in his dominions who is insensible to pleasures of this
kind ?
If he does not, what he is very likely to do, spend upon
those
pleasures so great a part of his revenue as to debilitate
very
much the defensive power of the state, it cannot well be
expected
that he should not spend upon them all that part of it
which
is over and above what is necessary for supporting that
defensive
power. His ordinary expense becomes equal to his
ordinary
revenue, and it is well if it does not frequently exceed
it. The
amassing of treasure can no longer be expected; and when
extraordinary
exigencies require extraordinary expenses, he must
necessarily
call upon his subjects for an extraordinary aid. The
present
and the late king of Prussia are the only great princes
of
Europe, who, since the death of Henry IV. of France, in 1610,
are
supposed to have amassed any considerable treasure. The
parsimony
which leads to accumulation has become almost as rare
in
republican as in monarchical governments. The Italian
republics,
the United Provinces of the Netherlands, are all in
debt.
The canton of Berne is the single republic in Europe which
has
amassed any considerable treasure. The other Swiss republics
have
not. The taste for some sort of pageantry, for splendid
buildings,
at least, and other public ornaments, frequently
prevails
as much in the apparently sober senate-house of a little
republic,
as in the dissipated court of the greatest king.
The
want of parsimony, in time of peace, imposes the necessity of
contracting
debt in time of war. When war comes, there is no
money
in the treasury, but what is necessary for carrying on the
ordinary
expense of the peace establishment. In war, an
establishment
of three or four times that expense be. comes
necessary
for the defence of the state ; and consequently, a
revenue
three or four times greater than the peace revenue.
Supposing
that the sovereign should have, what he scarce ever
has,
the immediate means of augmenting his revenue in proportion
to the
augmentation of his expense; yet still the produce of the
taxes,
from which this increase of revenue must be drawn, will
not
begin to come into the treasury, till perhaps ten or twelve
months
after they are imposed. But the moment in which war
begins,
or rather the moment in which it appears likely to begin,
the
army must be augmented, the fleet must be fitted out, the
garrisoned
towns must be put into a posture of defence; that
army,
that fleet, those garrisoned towns, must be furnished with
arms,
ammunition, and provisions. An
immediate and great
expense
must be incurred in that moment of immediate danger,
which
will not wait for the gradual and slow returns of the new
taxes.
In this exigency, government can have no other resource
but in
borrowing.
The
same commercial state of society which, by the operation of
moral
causes, brings government in this manner into the necessity
of
borrowing, produces in the subjects both an ability and an
inclination
to lend. If it commonly brings along with it the
necessity
of borrowing, it likewise brings with it the facility
of
doing so.
A
country abounding with merchants and manufacturers, necessarily
abounds
with a set of people through whose hands, not only their
own
capitals, but the capitals of all those who either lend them
money,
or trust them with goods, pass as frequently, or more
frequently,
than the revenue of a private man, who, without trade
or
business, lives upon his income, passes through his hands. The
revenue
of such a man can regularly pass through his hands only
once in
a year. But the whole amount of the capital and credit of
a
merchant, who deals in a trade of which the returns are very
quick,
may sometimes pass through his hands two, three, or four
times
in a year. A country abounding with merchants and
manufacturers,
therefore, necessarily abounds with a set of
people,
who have it at all times in their power to advance, if
they
chuse to do so, a very large sum of money to government.
Hence
the ability in the subjects of a commercial state to lend.
Commerce
and manufactures can seldom flourish long in any state
which
does not enjoy a regular administration of justice; in
which
the people do not feel themselves secure in the possession
of
their property ; in which the faith of contracts is not
supported
by law ; and in which the authority of the state is not
supposed
to be regularly employed in enforcing the payment of
debts
from all those who are able to pay. Commerce and
manufactures,
in short, can seldom flourish in any state, in
which
there is not a certain degree of confidence in the justice
of
government. The same confidence which disposes great merchants
and
manufacturers upon ordinary occasions, to trust their
property
to the protection of a particular government, disposes
them,
upon extraordinary occasions, to trust that government with
the use
of their property. By lending money to government, they
do not
even for a moment diminish their ability to carry on their
trade
and manufactures; on the contrary, they commonly augment
it. The
necessities of the state render government, upon most
occasions
willing to borrow upon terms extremely advantageous to
the
lender. The security which it grants to the original
creditor,
is made transferable to any other creditor ; and from
the
universal confidence in the justice of the state, generally
sells
in the market for more than was originally paid for it. The
merchant
or monied man makes money by lending money to
government,
and instead of diminishing. increases his trading
capital.
He generally considers it as a favour, therefore, when
the
administration admits him to a share in the first
subscription
for a new loan. Hence the inclination or willingness
in the
subjects of a commercial state to lend.
The
government of such a state is very apt to repose itself upon
this
ability and willingness of its subjects to lend it their
money
on extraordinary occasions. It foresees the facility of
borrowing,
and therefore dispenses itself from the duty of
saving.
In a
rude state of society, there are no great mercantile or
manufacturing
capitals. The individuals, who hoard whatever money
they
can save, and who conceal their hoard, do so from a distrust
of the
justice of government ; from a fear, that if it was known
that
they had a hoard, and where that hoard was to be found, they
would
quickly be plundered. In such a state of things, few people
would
be able, and nobody would be willing to lend their money to
government
on extraordinary exigencies. The sovereign feels that
he must
provide for such exigencies by saving, because he
foresees
the absolute impossibility of borrowing. This foresight
increases
still further his natural disposition to save.
The
progress of the enormous debts which at present oppress, and
will in
the long-run probably ruin, all the great nations of
Europe,
has been pretty uniform. Nations, like private men, have
generally
begun to borrow upon what may be called personal
credit,
without assigning or mortgaging any particular fund for
the
payment of the debt; and when this resource has failed them,
they
have gone on to borrow upon assignments or mortgages of
particular
funds.
What is
called the unfunded debt of Great Britain, is contracted
in the
former of those two ways. It consists partly in a debt
which
bears, or is supposed to bear, no interest, and which
resembles
the debts that a private man contracts upon account;
and
partly in a debt which bears interest, and which resembles
what a
private man contracts upon his bill or promissory-note.
The
debts which are due, either for extraordinary services, or
for
services either not provided for, or not paid at the time
when
they are performed; part of the extraordinaries of the army,
navy,
and ordnance, the arrears of subsidies to foreign princes,
those
of seamen's wages, etc. usually constitute a debt of the
first
kind. Navy and exchequer bills, which are issued sometimes
in
payment of a part of such debts, and sometimes for other
purposes,
constitute a debt of the second kind; exchequer bills
bearing
interest from the day on which they are issued, and navy
bills
six months after they are issued. The bank of England,
either
by voluntarily discounting those bills at their current
value,
or by agreeing with government for certain considerations
to
circulate exchequer bills, that is, to receive them at par,
paying
the interest which happens to be due upon them, keeps up
their
value, and facilitates their circulation, and thereby
frequently
enables government to contract a very large debt of
this
kind. In France, where there is no bank, the state bills
(billets
d'etat { See Examen des Reflections Politiques sur les
Finances.})
have sometimes sold at sixty and seventy per cent.
discount.
During the great recoinage in king William's time, when
the
bank of England thought proper to put a stop to its usual
transactions,
exchequer bills and tallies are said to have sold
from
twenty-five to sixty per cent. discount; owing partly, no
doubt,
to the supposed instability of the new government
established
by the Revolution, but partly, too, to the want of
the
support of the bank of England.
When
this resource is exhausted, and it becomes necessary, in
order
to raise money, to assign or mortgage some particular
branch
of the public revenue for the payment of the debt,
government
has, upon different occasions, done this in two
different
ways. Sometimes it has made this assignment or mortgage
for a
short period of time only, a year, or a few years, for
example;
and sometimes for perpetuity. In the one case, the fund
was
supposed sufficient to pay, within the limited time, both
principal
and interest of the money borrowed. In the other, it
was
supposed sufticient to pay the interest only, or a perpetual
annuity
equivalent to the interest, government being at liberty
to
redeem, at any time, this annuity, upon paying back the
principal
sum borrowed. When money was raised in the one way. it
was
said to be raised by anticipation ; when in the other, by
perpetual
funding, or, more shortly, by funding.
In
Great Britain, the annual land and malt taxes are regularly
anticipated
every year, by virtue of a borrowing clause
constantly
inserted into the acts which impose them. The bank of
England
generally advances at an interest, which, since the
Revolution,
has varied from eight to three per cent., the sums of
which
those taxes are granted, and receives payment as their
produce
gradually comes in. If there is a deficiency, which there
always
is, it is provided for in the supplies of the ensuing
year.
The only considerable branch of the public revenue which
yet
remains unmortgaged, is thus regularly spent before it comes
in.
Like an improvident spendthrift, whose pressing occasions
will
not allow him to wait for the regular payment of his
revenue,
the state is in the constant practice of borrowing of
its own
factors and agents, and of paying interest for the use of
its own
money.
In the
reign of king William, and during a great part of that of
queen
Anne, before we had become so familiar as we are now with
the
practice of perpetual funding, the greater part of the new
taxes
were imposed but for a short period of time (for four,
five,
six, or seven years only), and a great part of the grants
of
every year consisted in loans upon anticipations of the
produce
of those taxes. The produce being frequently insufficient
for
paying, within the limited term, the principal and interest
of the
money borrowed, deficiencies arose; to make good which, it
became
necessary to prolong the term.
In
1697, by the 8th of William III., c. 20, the deficiencies of
several
taxes were charged upon what was then called the first
general
mortgage or fund, consisting of a prolongation to the
first
of August 1706, of several different taxes, which would
have
expired within a shorter term, and of which the produce was
accumulated
into one general fund. The deficiencies charged upon
this
prolonged term amounted to £5,160,459: 14: 9½.
In
1701, those duties, with some others, were still further
prolonged,
for the like purposes, till the first of August 1710,
and
were called the second general mortgage or fund. The
deficiencies
charged upon it amounted to £2,055,999: 7: 11½.
In
1707, those duties were still further prolonged, as a fund for
new
loans. to the first of August 1712, and were called the third
general
mortgage or fund. The sum borrowed upon it was
£983,254:11:9¼.
In
1708, those duties were all (except the old subsidy of tonnage
and
poundage, of which one moiety only was made a part of this
fund,
and a duty upon the importation of Scotch linen, which had
been
taken off by the articles of union) still further continued,
as a
fund for new loans, to the first of August 1714, and were
called
the fourth general mortgage or fund. The sum borrowed upon
it was
£925,176:9:2¼.
In
1709, those duties were all ( except the old subsidy of
tonnage
and poundage, which was now left out of this fund
altogether
) still further continued, for the same purpose, to
the
first of August 1716, and were called the fifth general
mortgage
or fund. The sum borrowed upon it was £922,029:6s.
In
1710, those duties were again prolonged to the first of August
1720,
and were called the sixth general mortgage or fund. The sum
borrowed
upon it was £1,296,552:9:11¾.
In
1711, the same duties (which at this time were thus subject to
four
different anticipations), together with several others, were
continued
for ever, and made a fund for paying the interest of
the
capital of the South-sea company, which had that year
advanced
to government, for paying debts, and making good
deficiencies,
the sum of £9,177,967:15:4d, the greatest loan
which
at that time had ever been made.
Before
this period, the principal, so far as I have been able to
observe,
the only taxes, which, in order to pay the interest of a
debt,
had been imposed for perpetuity, were those for paying the
interest
of the money which had been advanced to government by
the
bank and East-India company, and of what it was expected
would
be advanced, but which was never advanced, by a projected
land
bank. The bank fund at this time amounted to
£3,375,027:17:10½,
for which was paid an annuity or interest of
£206,501:15:5d.
The East-India fund amounted to £3,200,000, for
which
was paid an annuity or interest of £160,000; the bank fund
being
at six per cent., the East-India fund at five per cent.
interest.
In
1715, by the first of George I., c. 12, the different taxes
which
had been mortgaged for paying the bank annuity, together
with
several others, which, by this act, were likewise rendered
perpetual,
were accumulated into one common fund, called the
aggregate
fund, which was charged not only with the payment of
the
bank annuity, but with several other annuities and burdens of
different
kinds. This fund was afterwards augmented by the third
of
George I., c.8., and by the fifth of George I., c. 3, and the
different
duties which were then added to it were likewise
rendered
perpetual.
In
1717, by the third of George I., c. 7, several other taxes
were
rendered perpetual, and accumulated into another common
fund,
called the general fund, for the payment of certain
annuities,
amounting in the whole to £724,849:6:10½.
In
consequence of those different acts, the greater part of the
taxes,
which before had been anticipated only for a short term of
years
were rendered perpetual, as a fund for paying, not the
capital,
but the interest only, of the money which had been
borrowed
upon them by different successive anticipations.
Had
money never been raised but by anticipation, the course of a
few
years would have liberated the public revenue, without any
other
attention of government besides that of not overloading the
fund,
by charging it with more debt than it could pay within the
limited
term, and not of anticipating a second time before the
expiration
of the first anticipation. But the greater part of
European
governments have been incapable of those attentions.
They
have frequently overloaded the fund, even upon the first
anticipation;
and when this happened not to be the case, they
have
generally taken care to overload it, by anticipating a
second
and a third time, before the expiration of the first
anticipation.
The fund becoming in this manner altogether
insufficient
for paying both principal and interest of the money
borrowed
upon it, it became necessary to charge it with the
interest
only, or a perpetual annuity equal to the interest ; and
such
improvident anticipations necessarily gave birth to the more
ruinous
practice of perpetual funding. But though this practice
necessarily
puts off the liberation of the public revenue from a
fixed
period, to one so indefinite that it is not very likely
ever to
arrive ; yet, as a greater sum can, in all cases, be
raised
by this new practice than by the old one of anticipation,
the
former, when men have once become familiar with it, has, in
the
great exigencies of the state, been universally preferred to
the
latter. To relieve the present exigency, is always the object
which
principally interests those immediately concerned in the
administration
of public affairs. The future liberation of the
public
revenue they leave to the care of posterity.
During
the reign of queen Anne, the market rate of interest had
fallen
from six to five per cent.; and, in the twelfth year of
her
reign, five per cent. was declared to be the highest rate
which
could lawfully be taken for money borrowed upon private
security.
Soon after the greater part of the temporary taxes of
Great
Britain had been rendered perpetual, and distributed into
the
aggregate, South-sea, and general funds, the creditors of the
public,
like those of private persons, were induced to accept of
five
per cent. for the interest of their money, which occasioned
a
saving of one per cent. upon the capital of the greater part or
the
debts which had been thus funded for perpetuity, or of
one-sixth
of the greater part of the annuities which were paid
out of
the three great funds above mentioned. This saving left a
considerable
surplus in the produce of the different taxes which
had
been accumulated into those funds, over and above what was
necessary
for paying the annuities which were now charged upon
them,
and laid the foundation of what has since been called the
sinking
fund. In 1717, it amounted to £523,454:7:7½. In 1727, the
interest
of the greater part of the public debts was still
further
reduced to four per cent.; and, in 1753 and 1757, to
three
and a-half, and three per cent., which reductions still
further
augmented the sinking fund.
A
sinking fund, though instituted for the payment of old,
facilitates
very much the contracting of new debts. It is a
subsidiary
fund, always at hand, to be mortgaged in aid of any
other
doubtful fund, upon which money is proposed to be raised in
any
exigency of the state. Whether the sinking fund of Great
Britain
has been more frequently applied to the one or to other
of
those two purposes, will sufficiently appear by and by.
Besides
those two methods of borrowing, by anticipations and by a
perpetual
funding, there are two other methods, which hold a sort
of
middle place between them ; these are, that of borrowing upon
annuities
for terms of years, and that of borrowing upon
annuities
for lives.
During
the reigns of king William and queen Anne, large sums were
frequently
borrowed upon annuities for terms of years, which were
sometimes
longer and sometimes shorter. In 1695, an act was
passed
for borrowing one million upon an annuity of fourteen per
cent.,
or £140,000 a-year, for sixteen years. In 1691, an act was
passed
for borrowing a million upon annuities for lives, upon
terms
which, in the present times, would appear very
advantageous;
but the subscription was not filled up. In the
following
year, the deficiency was made good, by borrowing upon
annuities
for lives, at fourteen per cent. or a little more than
seven
years purchase. In 1695, the persons who had purchased
those
annuities were allowed to exchange them for others of
ninety-six
years, upon paying into the exchequer sixty-three
pounds
in the hundred ; that is, the difference between fourteen
per
cent. for life, and fourteen per cent. for ninety-six years,
was
sold for sixty-three pounds, or for four and a-half years
purchase.
Such was the supposed instability of government, that
even
these terms procured few purchasers. In the reign of queen
Anne,
money was, upon different occasions, borrowed both upon
annuities
for lives, and upon annuities for terms of thirty-two,
of
eighty-nine, of ninety-eight, and of ninety-nine years. In
1719,
the proprietors of the annuities for thirty-two years were
induced
to accept, in lieu of them, South-sea stock to the amount
of
eleven and a-half years purchase of the annuities, together
with an
additional quantity of stock, equal to the arrears which
happened
then to be due upon them. In 1720, the greater part of
the
other annuities for terms of years, both long and short, were
subscribed
into the same fund. The long annuities, at that time,
amounted
to £666,821: 8:3½ a-year. On the 5th of January 1775,
the
remainder of them, or what was not subscribed at that time,
amounted
only to £136,453:12:8d.
During
the two wars which began in 1739 and in 1755, little money
was
borrowed, either upon annuities for terms of years, or upon
those
for lives. An annuity for ninety-eight or ninety-nine
years,
however, is worth nearly as much as a perpetuity, and
should
therefore, one might think, be a fund for borrowing nearly
as
much. But those who, in order to make family settlements, and
to
provide for remote futurity, buy into the public stocks, would
not
care to purchase into one of which the value was continually
diminishing
; and such people make a very considerable
proportion,
both of the proprietors and purchasers of stock. An
annuity
for a long term of years, therefore, though its intrinsic
value
may be very nearly the same with that of a perpetual
annuity,
will not find nearly the same number of purchasers. The
subscribers
to a new loan, who mean generally to sell their
subscription
as soon as possible, prefer greatly a perpetual
annuity,
redeemable by parliament, to an irredeemable annuity,
for a
long term of years, of only equal amount. The value of the
former
may be supposed always the same, or very nearly the same;
and it
makes, therefore, a more convenient transferable stock
than
the latter.
During
the two last-mentioned wars, annuities, either for terms
of
years or for lives, were seldom granted, but as premiums to
the
subscribers of a new loan, over and above the redeemable
annuity
or interest, upon the credit of which the loan was
supposed
to be made. They were granted, not as the proper fund
upon
which the money was borrowed, but as an additional
encouragement
to the lender.
Annuities
for lives have occasionally been granted in two
different
ways ; either upon separate lives, or upon lots of
lives,
which, in French, are called tontines, from the name of
their inventor.
When annuities are granted upon separate lives,
the
death of every individual annuitant disburdens the public
revenue,
so far as it was affected by his annuity. When annuities
are
granted upon tontines, the liberation of the public revenue
does
not commence till the death of all the annuitants
comprehended
in one lot, which may sometimes consist of twenty or
thirty
persons, of whom the survivors succeed to the annuities of
all
those who die before them; the last survivor succeeding to
the annuities
of the whole lot. Upon the same revenue, more money
can
always be raised by tontines than by annuities for separate
lives.
An annuity, with a right of survivorship, is really worth
more
than an equal annuity for a separate life ; and, from the
confidence
which every man naturally has in his own good fortune,
the
principle upon which is founded the success of all lotteries,
such an
annuity generally sells for something more than it is
worth.
In countries where it is usual for government to raise
money
by granting annuities, tontines are, upon this account,
generally
preferred to annuities for separate lives. The
expedient
which will raise most money, is almost always preferred
to that
which is likely to bring about, in the speediest manner,
the
liberation of the public revenue.
In
France, a much greater proportion of the public debts consists
in
annuities for lives than in England. According to a memoir
presented
by the parliament of Bourdeaux to the king, in 1764,
the
whole public debt ot France is estimated at twenty-four
hundred
millions of livres; of which the capital, for which
annuities
for lives had been granted, is supposed to amount to
three
hundred millions, the eighth part of the whole public debt.
The
annuities themselves are computed to amount to thirty
millions
a-year, the fourth part of one hundred and twenty
millions,
the supposed interest of that whole debt. These
estimations,
I know very well, are not exact; but having been
presented
by so very respectable a body as approximations to the
truth,
they may, I apprehend, be considered as such. It is not
the
different degrees of anxiety in the two governments of France
and
England for the liberation of the public revenue, which
occasions
this difference in their respective modes of borrowing
; it
arises altogether from the different views and interests of
the
lenders.
In
England, the seat of government being in the greatest
mercantile
city in the world, the merchants are generally the
people
who advance money to government. By advancing it, they do
not
mean to diminish, but, on the contrary, to increase their
mercantile
capitals; and unless they expected to sell, with some
profit,
their share in the subscription for a new loan, they
never
would subscribe. But if, by advancing their money, they
were to
purchase, instead of perpetual annuities, annuities for
lives
only, whether their own or those of other people, they
would
not always be so likely to sell them with a profit.
Annuities
upon their own lives they would always sell with loss;
because
no man will give for an annuity upon the life of another,
whose
age and state of health are nearly the same with his own,
the
same price which he would give for one upon his own. An
annuity
upon the life of a third person, indeed, is, no doubt, of
equal
value to the buyer and the seller; but its real value
begins
to diminish from the moment it is granted, and continues
to do
so, more and more, as long as it subsists. It can never,
therefore,
make so convenient a transferable stock as a perpetual
annuity,
of which the real value may be supposed always the same,
or very
nearly the same.
In
France, the seat of government not being in a great mercantile
city,
merchants do not make so great a proportion of the people
who
advance money to government. The people concerned in the
finances,
the farmers-general, the receivers of the taxes which
are not
in farm, the court-bankers, etc. make the greater part of
those
who advance their money in all public exigencies. Such
people
are commonly men of mean birth, but of great wealth, and
frequently
of great pride. They are too proud to marry their
equals,
and women of quality disdain to marry them. They
frequently
resolve, therefore, to live bachelors; and having
neither
any families of their own, nor much regard for those of
their
relations, whom they are not always very fond of
acknowledging,
they desire only to live in splendour during their
own
time, and are not unwilling that their fortune should end
with
themselves. The number of rich people, besides, who are
either
averse to marry, or whose condition of life renders it
either
improper or inconvenient for them to do so, is much
greater
in France than in England. To such people, who have
little
or no care for posterity, nothing can be more convenient
than to
exchange their capital for a revenue, which is to last
just as
long, and no longer, than they wish it to do.
The
ordinary expense of the greater part of modern governments,
in time
of peace, being equal, or nearly equal, to their ordinary
revenue,
when war comes, they are both unwilling and unable to
increase
their revenue in proportion to the increase of their
expense.
They are unwilling, for fear of offending the people,
who, by
so great and so sudden an increase of taxes, would soon
be
disgusted with the war ; and they are unable, from not well
knowing
what taxes would be sufficient to produce the revenue
wanted.
The facility of borrowing delivers them from the
embarrassment
which this fear and inability would otherwise
occasion.
By means of borrowing, they are enabled, with a very
moderate
increase of taxes, to raise, from year to year, money
sufficient
for carrying on the war; and by the practice of
perpetual
funding, they are enabled, with the smallest possible
increase
of taxes, to raise annually the largest possible sum of
money.
In great empires, the people who live in the capital, and
in the
provinces remote from the scene of action, feel, many of
them,
scarce any inconveniency from the war, but enjoy, at their
ease,
the amusement of reading in the newspapers the exploits of
their
own fleets and armies. To them this amusement compensates
the
small difference between the taxes which they pay on account
of the
war, and those which they had been accustomed to pay in
time of
peace. They are commonly dissatisfied with the return of
peace,
which puts an end to their amusement, and to a thousand
visionary
hopes of conquest and national glory, from a longer
continuance
of the war.
The
return of peace, indeed, seldom relieves them from the
greater
part of the taxes imposed during the war. These are
mortgaged
for the interest of the debt contracted, in order to
carry
it on. If, over and above paying the interest of this debt,
and
defraying the ordinary expense of government, the old
revenue,
together with the new taxes, produce some surplus
revenue,
it may, perhaps, be converted into a sinking fund for
paying
off the debt. But, in the first place, this sinking fund,
even
supposing it should be applied to no other purpose, is
generally
altogether inadequate for paying, in the course of any
period
during which it can reasonably be expected that peace
should
continue, the whole debt contracted during the war ; and,
in the
second place, this fund is almost always applied to other
purposes.
The new
taxes were imposed for the sole purpose of paying the
interest
of the money borrowed upon them. If they produce more,
it is
generally something which was neither intended nor
expected,
and is, therefore, seldom very considerable. Sinking
funds
have generally arisen, not so much from any surplus of the
taxes
which was over and above what was necessary for paying the
interest
or annuity originally charged upon them, as from a
subsequent
reduction of that interest ; that of Holland in 1655,
and
that of the ecclesiastical state in 1685, were both formed in
this
manner. Hence the usual insufficiency of such funds.
During
the most profound peace, various events occur, which
require
an extraordinary expense ; and government finds it always
more
convenient to defray this expense by misapplying the sinking
fund,
than by imposing a new tax. Every new tax is immediately
felt
more or less by the people. It occasions always some murmur,
and
meets with some opposition. The more taxes may have been
multiplied,
the higher they may have been raised upon every
different
subject of taxation; the more loudly the people
complain
of every new tax, the more difficult it becomes, too,
either
to find out new subjects of taxation, or to raise much
higher
the taxes already imposed upon the old. A momentary
suspension
of the payment of debt is not immediately felt by the
people,
and occasions neither murmur nor complaint. To borrow of
the
sinking fund is always an obvious and easy expedient for
getting
out of the present difficulty. The more the public debts
may
have been accumulated, the more necessary it may have become
to
study to reduce them; the more dangerous, the more ruinous it
may be
to missapply any part of the sinking fund ; the less
likely
is the public debt to be reduced to any considerable
degree,
the more likely, the more certainly, is the sinking fund
to be
misapplied towards defraying all the extraordinary expenses
which
occur in time of peace. When a nation is already
overburdened
with taxes, nothing but the necessities of a new
war,
nothing but either the animosity of national vengeance, or
the
anxiety for national security, can induce the people to
submit,
with tolerable patience, to a new tax. Hence the usual
misapplication
of the sinking fund.
In
Great Britain, from the time that we had first recourse to the
ruinous
expedient of perpetual funding, the reduction of the
public
debt, in time of peace, has never borne any proportion to
its
accumulation in time of war. It was in the war which began in
1668,
and was concluded by the treaty of Ryswick, in 1697, that
the
foundation of the present enormous debt of Great Britain was
first
laid.
On the
31st of December 1697, the public debts of Great Britain,
funded
and unfunded, amounted to £21,515,742:13:8½. A great part
of
those debts had been contracted upon short anticipations, and
some
part upon annuities for lives; so that, before the 31st of
December
1701, in less than four years, there had partly been
paid
off; and partly reverted to the public, the sum of
£5,121,041:12:0¾d;
a greater reduction of the public debt than
has
ever since been brought about in so short a period of time.
The
remaining debt, therefore, amounted only to
£16,394,701:1:7¼d.
In the
war which began in 1702, and which was concluded by the
treaty
of Utrecht, the public debts were still more accumulated.
On the
31st of December 1714, they amounted to £53,681,076:5:6½.
The
subscription into the South-sea fund, of the short and long
annuities,
increased the capital of the public debt ; so that, on
the
31st of December 1722, it amounted to £55,282,978:1:3 5/6.
The
reduction of the debt began in 1723, and went on so slowly,
that,
on the 31st of December 1739, during seventeen years-of
profound
peace, the whole sum paid off was no more than
£8,328,554:17:11
3/12, the capital of the public debt, at that
time,
amounting to £46,954,623:3:4 7/12.
The
Spanish war, which began in 1739, and the French war which
soon
followed it, occasioned a further increase of the debt,
which,
on the 31st of December 1748, after the war had been
concluded
by the treaty of Aix-la-Chapelle, amounted to
£78,293,313:1:10¾.
The most profound peace, of 17 years
continuance,
had taken no more than £8,328,354, 17:11¼ from it. A
war, of
less than nine years continuance, added £31,338,689:18: 6
1/6 to
it. {See James Postlethwaite's History of the Public
Revenue.}
During
the administration of Mr. Pelham, the interest of the
public
debt was reduced, or at least measures were taken for
reducing
it, from four to three per cent.; the sinking fund was
increased,
and some part of the publie debt was paid off. In
1755,
before the breaking out of the late war, the funded debt of
Great
Britain amounted to £72,289,675. On the 5th of January
1763,
at the conclusion of the peace, the funded debt amounted
debt to
£122,603,336:8:2¼. The unfunded debt has been stated at
£13,927,589:2:2.
But the expense occasioned by the war did not
end
with the conclusion of the peace ; so that, though on the 5th
of
January 1764, the funded debt was increased (partly by a new
loan,
and partly by funding a part of the unfunded debt) to
£129,586,789:10:1¾,
there still remained (according to the very
well
informed author of Considerations on the Trade and Finances
of
Great Britain) an unfunded debt, which was brought to account
in that
and the following year, of £9,975,017: 12:2 15/44d. In
1764,
therefore, the public debt of Great Britain, funded and
unfunded
together, amounted, according to this author, to
£139,561,807:2:4.
The annuities for lives, too, which had been
granted
as premiums to the subscribers to the new loans in 1757,
estimated
at fourteen years purchase, were valued at £472,500 ;
and the
annuities for long terms of years, granted as premiums
likewise,
in 1761 and 1762, estimated at twenty-seven
and a-half
years
purchase, were valued at £6,826,875. During a peace of
about
seven years continuance, the prudent and truly patriotic
administration
of Mr. Pelham was not able to pay off an old debt
of six
millions. During a war of nearly the same continuance, a
new
debt of more than seventy-five millions was contracted.
On the
5th of January 1775, the funded debt of Great Britain
amounted
to £124,996,086, 1:6¼d. The unfunded, exclusive of a
large
civil-list debt, to £4,150,236:3:11 7/8. Both together, to
£129,146,322:5:6.
According to this account, the whole debt paid
off,
during eleven years of profound peace, amounted only to
£10,415,476:16:9
7/8. Even this small reduction of debt, however,
has not
been all made from the savings out of the ordinary
revenue
of the state. Several extraneous sums, altogether
independent
of that ordinary revenue, have contributed towards
it.
Amongst these we may reckon an additional shilling in the
pound
land tax, for three years; the two millions received from
the
East-India company, as indemnification for their territorial
acquisitions
; and the one hundred and ten thousand pounds
received
from the bank for the renewal of their charter. To these
must be
added several other sums, which, as they arose out of the
late
war, ought perhaps to be considered as deductions from the
expenses
of it. The principal are,
The
produce of French prizes ..............
£690,449: 18: 9
Composition
for French prisoners .........
670,000: 0: 0
What
has been received from the sale
of the
ceded islands .........................
95,500: 0: 0
Total,
.....................................£1,455,949: 18: 9
If we
add to this sum the balance of the earl of Chatham's and
Mr.
Calcraft's accounts, and other army savings of the same kind,
together
with what has been received from the bank, the
East-India
company, and the additional shilling in the pound land
tax,
the whole must be a good deal more than five millions. The
debt,
therefore, which, since the peace, has been paid out of the
savings
from the ordinary revenue of the state, has not, one year
with
another, amounted to half a million a-year. The sinking fund
has, no
doubt, been considerably augmented since the peace, by
the
debt which had been paid off, by the reduction of the
redeemable
four per cents to three per cents, and by the
annuities
for lives which have fallen in; and, if peace were to
continue,
a million, perhaps, might now be annually spared out of
it
towards the discharge of the debt. Another million,
accordingly,
was paid in the course of last year ; but at the
same
time, a large civil-list debt was left unpaid, and we are
now
involved in a new war, which, in its progress, may prove as
expensive
as any of our former wars.{It has proved more expensive
than
any one of our former wars, and has involved us in an
additional
debt of more than one hundred millions. During a
profound
peace of eleven years, little more than ten millions of
debt
was paid; during a war of seven years, more than one hundred
millions
was contracted.} The new debt which will probably be
contracted
before the end of the next campaign, may, perhaps, be
nearly
equal to all the old debt which has been paid off from the
savings
out of the ordinary revenue of the state. It would be
altogether
chimerical, therefore, to expect that the public debt
should
ever be completely discharged, by any savings which are
likely
to be made from that ordinary revenue as it stands at
present.
The
public funds of the different indebted nations of Europe,
particularly
those of England, have, by one author, been
represented
as the accumulation of a great capital, superadded to
the
other capital of the country, by means of which its trade is
extended,
its manufactures are multiplied, and its lands
cultivated
and improved, much beyond what they could have been by
means
of that other capital only. He does not consider that the
capital
which the first creditors of the public advanced to
government,
was, from the moment in which he advanced it, a
certain
portion of the annual produce, turned away from serving
in the
function of a capital, to serve in that of a revenue ;
from
maintaining productive labourers, to maintain unproductive
ones,
and to be spent and wasted, generally in the course of the
year,
without even the hope of any future reproduction. In return
for the
capital which they advanced, they obtained, indeed, an
annuity
of the public funds, in most cases, of more than equal
value.
This annuity, no doubt, replaced to them their capital,
and
enabled them to carry on their trade and business to the
same,
or, perhaps, to a greater extent than before; that is, they
were
enabled, either to borrow of other people a new capital,
upon
the credit of this annuity or, by selling it, to get from
other
people a new capital of their own, equal, or superior, to
that
which they had advanced to government. This new capital,
however,
which they in this manner either bought or borrowed of
other
people, must have existed in the country before, and must
have
been employed, as all capitals are, in maintaining
productive
labour. When it came into the hands of those who had
advanced
their money to government, though it was, in some
respects,
a new capital to them, it was not so to the country,
but was
only a capital withdrawn from certain employments, in
order
to be turned towards others. Though it replaced to them
what
they had advanced to government, it did not replace it to
the
country. Had they not advanced this capital to government,
there
would have been in the country two capitals, two portions
of the
annual produce, instead of one, employed in maintaining
productive
labour.
When,
for defraying the expense of government, a revenue is
raised
within the year, from the produce of free or unmortgaged
taxes,
a certain portion of the revenue of private people is only
turned
away from maintaining one species of unproductive labour,
towards
maintaining another. Some part of what they pay in those
taxes,
might, no doubt, have been accumulated into capital, and
consequently
employed in maintaining productive labour ; but the
greater
part would probably have been spent, and consequently
employed
in maintaining unproductive labour. The public expense,
however,
when defrayed in this manner, no doubt hinders, more or
less,
the further accumulation of new capital; but it does not
necessarily
occasion the destruction of any actually-existing
capital.
When
the public expense is defrayed by funding, it is defrayed by
the
annual destruction of some capital which had before existed
in the
country; by the perversion of some portion of the annual
produce
which had before been destined for the maintenance of
productive
labour, towards that of unproductive labour. As in
this
case, however, the taxes are lighter than they would have
been,
had a revenue sufficient for defraying the same expense
been
raised within the year ; the private revenue of individuals
is
necessarily less burdened, and consequently their ability to
save
and accumulate some part of that revenue into capital, is a
good
deal less impaired. If the method of funding destroys more
old
capital, it, at the same time, hinders less the accumulation
or
acquisition of new capital, than that of defraying the public
expense
by a revenue raised within the year. Under the system of
funding,
the frugality and industry of private people can more
easily
repair the breaches which the waste and extravagance of
government
may occasionally make in the general capital of the
society.
It is
only during the continuance of war, however, that the
system
of funding has this advantage over the other system. Were
the
expense of war to be defrayed always by a revenue raised
within
the year, the taxes from which that extraordinary revenue
was
drawn would last no longer than the war. The ability of
private
people to accumulate, though less during the war, would
have
been greater during the peace, than under the system of
funding.
War would not necessarily have occasioned the
destruction
of any old capitals, and peace would have occasioned
the
accumulation of many more new. Wars would, in general, be
more
speedily concluded, and less wantonly undertaken. The people
feeling,
during continuance of war, the complete burden of it,
would
soon grow weary of it; and government, in order to humour
them,
would not be under the necessity of carrying it on longer
than it
was necessary to do so. The foresight of the heavy and
unavoidable
burdens of war would hinder the people from wantonly
calling
for it when there was no real or solid interest to fight
for.
The seasons during which the ability of private people to
accumulate
was somewhat impaired, would occur more rarely, and be
of
shorter continuance. Those, on the contrary, during which that
ability
was in the highest vigour would be of much longer
duration
than they can well be under the system of funding.
When
funding, besides, has made a certain progress, the
multiplication
of taxes which it brings along with it, sometimes
impairs
as much the ability of private people to accumulate, even
in time
of peace, as the other system would in time of war. The
peace
revenue of Great Britain amounts at present to more than
ten
millions a-year. If free and unmortgaged, it might be
sufficient,
with proper management, and without contracting a
shilling
of new debt, to carry on the most vigorous war. The
private
revenue of the inhabitants of Great Britain is at present
as much
incumbered in time of peace, their ability to accumulate
is as
much impaired, as it would have been in the time of the
most
expensive war, had the pernicious system of funding never
been
adopted.
In the
payment of the interest of the public debt, it has been
said,
it is the right hand which pays the left. The money does
not go
out of the country. It is only a part of the revenue of
one set
of the inhabitants which is transferred to another ; and
the
nation is not a farthing the poorer. This apology is founded
altogether
in the sophistry of the mercantile system; and, after
the
long examination which I have already bestowed upon that
system,
it may, perhaps, be unnecessary to say anything further
about
it. It supposes, besides, that the whole public debt is
owing
to the inhabitants of the country, which happens not to be
true ;
the Dutch, as well as several other foreign nations,
having
a very considerable share in our public funds. But though
the
whole debt were owing to the inhabitants of the country, it
would
not, upon that account, be less pernicious.
Land
and capital stock are the two original sources of all
revenue,
both private and public. Capital stock pays the wages of
productive
labour, whether employed in agriculture, manufactures,
or
commerce. The management of those two original sources of
revenue
belongs to two different sets of people; the proprietors
of
land, and the owners or employers of capital stock.
The
proprietor of land is interested, for the sake of his own
revenue,
to keep his estate in as good condition as he can, by
building
and repairing his tenants houses, by making and
maintaining
the necessary drains and inclosures, and all those
other
expensive improvements which it properly belongs to the
landlord
to make and maintain. But, by different land taxes, the
revenue
of the landlord may be so much diminished, and, by
different
duties upon the necessaries and conveniencies of life,
that
diminished revenue may be rendered of so little real value,
that he
may find himself altogether unable to make or maintain
those
expensive improvements. When the landlord, however, ceases
to do
his part, it is altogether impossible that the tenant
should
continue to do his. As the distress of the landlord
increases,
the agriculture of the country must necessarily
decline.
When,
by different taxes upon the necessaries and conveniencies
of
life, the owners and employers of capital stock find, that
whatever
revenue they derive from it, will not, in a particular
country,
purchase the same quantity of those necessaries and
conveniencies
which an equal revenue would in almost any other,
they
will be disposed to remove to some other. And when, in order
to
raise those taxes, all or the greater part of merchants and
manufacturers,
that is, all or the greater part of the employers
of
great capitals, come to be continually exposed to the
mortifying
and vexatious visits of the tax-gatherers, this
disposition
to remove will soon be changed into an actual
removing.
The industry of the country will necessarily fall with
the
removal of the capital which supported it, and the ruin of
trade
and manufactures will follow the declension of agriculture.
To
transfer from the owners of those two great sources of
revenue,
land, and capital stock, from the persons immediately
interested
in the good condition of every particular portion of
land,
and in the good management of every particular portion of
capital
stock, to another set of persons (the creditors of the
public,
who have no such particular interest ), the greater part
of the
revenue arising from either, must, in the long-run,
occasion
both the neglect of land, and the waste or removal of
capital
stock. A creditor of the public has, no doubt, a general
interest
in the prosperity of the agriculture, manufactures, and
commerce
of the country ; and consequently in the good condition
of its
land, and in the good management of its capital stock.
Should
there be any general failure or declension in any of these
things,
the produce of the different taxes might no longer be
sufficient
to pay him the annuity or interest which is due to
him.
But a creditor of the public, considered merely as such, has
no
interest in the good condition of any particular portion of
land,
or in the good management of any particular portion of
capital
stock. As a creditor of the public, he has no knowledge
of any
such particular portion. He has no inspection of it. He
can
have no care about it. Its ruin may in some cases be unknown
to him,
and cannot directly affect him.
The
practice of funding has gradually enfeebled every state which
has
adopted it. The Italian republics seem to have begun it.
Genoa
and Venice, the only two remaining which can pretend to an
independent
existence, have both been enfeebled by it. Spain
seems
to have learned the practice from the Italian republics,
and
(its taxes being probably less judicious than theirs) it has,
in
proportion to its natural strength, been-still more enfeebled.
The
debts of Spain are of very old standing. It was deeply in
debt
before the end of the sixteenth century, about a hundred
years
before England owed a shilling. France, not. withstanding
all its
natural resources, languishes under an oppressive load of
the
same kind. The republic of the United Provinces is as much
enfeebled
by its debts as either Genoa or Venice. Is it likely
that,
in Great Britain alone, a practice, which has brought
either
weakness or dissolution into every other country, should
prove
altogether innocent ?
The
system of taxation established in those different countries,
it may
be said, is inferior to that of England. I believe it is
so. But
it ought to be remembered, that when the wisest
government
has exhausted all the proper subjects of taxation, it
must,
in cases of urgent necessity, have recourse to improper
ones.
The wise republic of Holland has, upon some occasions, been
obliged
to have recourse to taxes as inconvenient as the greater
part of
those of Spain. Another war, begun before any
considerable
liberation of the public revenue had been brought
about,
and growing in its progress as expensive as the last war,
may,
from irresistible necessity, render the British system of
taxation
as oppressive as that of Holland, or even as that of
Spain. To the honour of our present system of
taxation,
indeed,
it has hitherto given so little embarrassment to
industry,
that, during the course even of the most expensive
wars,
the frugality and good conduct of individuals seem to have
been
able, by saving and accumulation, to repair all the breaches
which
the waste and extravagance of government had made in the
general
capital of the society. At the conclusion of the late
war,
the most expensive that Great Britain ever waged, her
agriculture
was as flourishing, her manufacturers as numerous and
as
fully employed, and her commerce as extensive, as they had
ever
been before. The capital, therefore, which supported all
those
different branches of industry, must have been equal to
what it
had ever been before. Since the peace, agriculture has
been
still further improved; the rents of houses have risen in
every
town and village of the country, a proof of the increasing
wealth
and revenue of the people; and the annual amount of the
greater
part of the old taxes, of the principal branches of the
excise
and customs, in particular, has been continually
increasing,
an equally clear proof of an increasing consumption,
and
consequently of an increasing produce, which could alone
support
that consumption. Great Britain seems to support with
ease, a
burden which, half a century ago, nobody believed her
capable
of supporting, Let us not, however, upon this account,
rashly
conclude that she is capable of supporting any burden; nor
even be
too confident that she could support. without great
distress,
a burden a little greater than what has already been
laid
upon her.
When
national debts have once been accumulated to a certain
degree,
there is scarce, I believe, a single instance of their
having
been fairly and completely paid. The liberation of the
public
revenue, if it has ever been brought about at all, has
always
been brought about by a bankruptcy ; sometimes by an
avowed
one, though frequently by a pretended payment.
The
raising of the denomination of the coin has been the most
usual
expedient by which a real public bankruptcy has been
disguised
under the appearance of a pretended payment. If a
sixpence,
for example, should, either by act of parliament or
royal
proclamation. be raised to the denomination of a shilling,
and
twenty sixpences to that of a pound sterling ; the person
who,
under the old denomination, had borrowed twenty shillings,
or near
four ounces of silver, would, under the new, pay with
twenty
sixpences, or with something less than two ounces. A
national
debt of about a hundred and twenty-eight millions, near
the capital
of the funded and unfunded debt of Great Britain,
might,
in this manner, be paid with about sixty-four millions of
our
present money. It would, indeed, be a pretended payment only,
and the
creditors of the public would really be defrauded of ten
shillings
in the pound of what was due to them. The calamity,
too,
would extend much further than to the creditors of the
public,
and those of every private person would suffer a
proportionable
loss; and this without any advantage, but in most
cases with
a great additional loss, to the creditors of the
public.
If the creditors of the public, indeed, were generally
much in
debt to other people, they might in some measure
compensate
their loss by paying their creditors in the same coin
in
which the public had paid them. But in most countries, the
creditors
of the public are, the greater part of them, wealthy
people,
who stand more in the relation of creditors than in that
of
debtors, towards the rest of their fellow citizens. A
pretended
payment of this kind, therefore, instead of
alleviating,
aggravates, in most cases, the loss of the creditors
of the
public; and, without any advantage to the public, extends
the
calamity to a great number of other innocent people. It
occasions
a general and most pernicious subversion of the
fortunes
of private people; enriching, in most cases, the idle
and
profuse debtor, at the expense of the industrious and frugal
creditor
; and transporting a great part of the national capital
from
the hands which were likely to increase and improve it, to
those
who are likely to dissipate and destroy it. When it becomes
necessary
for a state to declare itself bankrupt, in the same
manner
as when it becomes necessary for an individual to do so, a
fair,
open, and avowed bankruptcy, is always the measure which is
both
least dishonourable to the debtor, and least hurtful to the
creditor.
The honour of a state is surely very poorly provided
for,
when, in order to cover the disgrace of a real bankruptcy,
it has
recourse to a juggling trick of this kind, so easily seen
through,
and at the same time so extremely pernicious.
Almost
all states, however, ancient as well as modern, when
reduced
to this necessity, have, upon some occasions, played this
very
juggling trick. The Romans, at the end of the first Punic
war,
reduced the As, the coin or denomination by which they
computed
the value of all their other coins, from containing
twelve
ounces of copper, to contain only two ounces; that is,
they
raised two ounces of copper to a denomination which had
always
before expressed the value of twelve ounces. The republic
was, in
this manner, enabled to pay the great debts which it had
contracted
with the sixth part of what it really owed. So sudden
and so
great a bankruptcy, we should in the present times be apt
to
imagine, must have occasioned a very violent popular clamour.
It does
not appear to have occasioned any. The law which enacted
it was,
like all other laws relating to the coin, introduced and
carried
through the assembly of the people by a tribune, and was
probably
a very popular law. In Rome, as in all other ancient
republics,
the poor people were constantly in debt to the rich
and the
great, who, in order to secure their votes at the annual
elections,
used to lend them money at exorbitant interest, which,
being
never paid, soon accumulated into a sum too great either
for the
debtor to pay, or for any body else to pay for him. The
debtor,
for fear of a very severe execution, was obliged, without
any
further gratuity, to vote for the candidate whom the creditor
recommended.
In spite of all the laws against bribery and
corruption,
the bounty of the candidates, together with the
occasional
distributions of coin which were ordered by the
senate,
were the principal funds from which, during the latter
times
of the Roman republic, the poorer citizens derived their
subsistence.
To deliver themselves from this subjection to their
creditors,
the poorer citizens were continually calling out,
either
for an entire abolition of debts, or for what they called
new
tables ; that is, for a law which should entitle them to a
complete
acquittance, upon paying only a certain proportion of
their
accumulated debts. The law which reduced the coin of all
denominations
to a sixth part of its former value, as it enabled
them to
pay their debts with a sixth part of what they really
owed,
was equivalent to the most advantageous new tables. In
order
to satisfy the people, the rich and the great were, upon
several
different occasions, obliged to consent to laws, both for
abolishing
debts, and for introducing new tables; and they
probably
were induced to consent to this law, partly for the same
reason,
and partly that, by liberating the public revenue, they
might restore
vigour to that government, of which they themselves
had the
principal direction. An operation
of this kind would
at once
reduce a debt of £128,000,000 to £21,333,333:6:8. In the
course
of the second Punic war, the As was still further reduced,
first,
from two ounces of copper to one ounce, and afterwards
from
one ounce to half an ounce ; that is, to the twenty-fourth
part of
its original value. By combining the three Roman
operations
into one, a debt of a hundred and twenty-eight
millions
of our present money, might in this manner be reduced
all at
once to a debt of £5,333,333:6:8. Even the enormous debt
of
Great Britain might in this manner soon be paid.
By
means of such expedients, the coin of, I believe, all nations,
has
been gradually reduced more and more below its original
value,
and the same nominal sum has been gradually brought to
contain
a smaller and a smaller quantity of silver.
Nations
have sometimes, for the same purpose, adulterated the
standard
of their coin ; that is, have mixed a greater quantity
of
alloy in it. If in the pound weight of our silver coin, for
example,
instead of eighteen penny-weight, according to the
present
standard, there were mixed eight ounces of alloy; a pound
sterling,
or twenty shillings of such coin, would be worth little
more
than six shillings and eightpence of our present money. The
quantity
of silver contained in six shillings and eightpence of
our
present money, would thus be raised very nearly to the
denomination
of a pound sterling. The adulteration of the
standard
has exactly the same effect with what the French call an
augmentation,
or a direct raising of the denomination of the
coin.
An
augmentation, or a direct raising of the denomination of the
coin,
always is, and from its nature must be, an open and avowed
operation.
By means of it, pieces of a smaller weight and bulk
are
called by the same name, which had before been given to
pieces
of a greater weight and bulk. The adulteration of the
standard,
on the contrary, has generally been a concealed
operation.
By means of it, pieces are issued from the mint, of
the
same denomination, and, as nearly as could be contrived, of
the
same weight, bulk, and appearance, with pieces which had been
current
before of much greater value. When king John of
France,{See
Du Cange Glossary, voce Moneta; the Benedictine
Edition.}
in order to pay his debts, adulterated his coin, all
the
officers of his mint were sworn to secrecy. Both operations
are
unjust. But a simple augmentation is an injustice of open
violence;
whereas an adulteration is an injustice of treacherous
fraud.
This latter operation, therefore, as soon as it has been
discovered,
and it could never be concealed very long, has always
excited
much greater indignation than the former. The coin, after
any
considerable augmentation, has very seldom been brought back
to its
former weight ; but after the greatest adulterations, it
has
almost always been brought back to its former fineness. It
has
scarce ever happened, that the fury and indignation of the
people
could otherwise be appeased.
In the
end of the reign of Henry VIII., and in the beginning of
that of
Edward VI., the English coin was not only raised in its
denomination,
but adulterated in its standard. The like frauds
were
practised in Scotland during the minority of James VI. They
have
occasionally been practised in most other countries.
That
the public revenue of Great Britain can never be completely
liberated,
or even that any considerable progress can ever be
made
towards that liberation, while the surplus of that revenue,
or what
is over and above defraying the annual expense of the
peace
establishment, is so very small, it seems altogether in
vain to
expect. That liberation, it is evident, can never be
brought
about, without either some very considerable augmentation
of the
public revenue, or some equally considerable reduction of
the
public expense.
A more
equal land tax, a more equal tax upon the rent of houses,
and
such alterations in the present system of customs and excise
as
those which have been mentioned in the foregoing chapter,
might,
perhaps, without increasing the burden of the greater part
of the
people, but only distributing the weight of it more
equally
upon the whole, produce a considerable augmentation of
revenue.
The most sanguine projector, however, could scarce
flatter
himself, that any augmentation of this kind would be such
as
could give any reasonable hopes, either of liberating the
public
revenue altogether, or even of making such progress
towards
that liberation in time of peace, as either to prevent or
to
compensate the further accumulation of the public debt in the
next
war.
By
extending the British system of taxation to all the different
provinces
of the empire, inhabited by people either of British or
European
extraction, a much greater augmentation of revenue might
be
expected. This, however, could scarce, perhaps, be done,
consistently
with the principles of the British constitution,
without
admitting into the British parliament, or, if you will,
into
the states-general of the British empire, a fair and equal
representation
of all those different provinces ; that of each
province
bearing the same proportion to the produce of its taxes,
as the
representation of Great Britain might bear to the produce
of the
taxes levied upon Great Britain. The private interest of
many
powerful individuals, the confirmed prejudices of great
bodies
of people, seem, indeed, at present, to oppose to so great
a
change, such obstacles as it may be very difficult, perhaps
altogether
impossible, to surmount. Without, however, pretending
to
determine whether such a union be practicable or
impracticable,
it may not, perhaps, be improper, in a speculative
work of
this kind, to consider how far the British system of
taxation
might be applicable to all the different provinces of
the
empire ; what revenue might be expected from it, if so
applied
; and in what manner a general union of this kind might
be
likely to affect the happiness and prosperity of the
differrent
provinces comprehended within it. Such a speculation,
can, at
worst, be regarded but as a new Utopia, less amusing,
certainly,
but no more useless and chimerical than the old one.
The land-tax,
the stamp duties, and the different duties of
customs
and excise, constitute the four principal branches of the
British
taxes.
Ireland
is certainly as able, and our American and West India
plantations
more able, to pay a land tax, than Great Britain.
Where
the landlord is subject neither to tythe nor poor's rate,
he must
certainly be more able to pay such a tax, than where he
is
subject to both those other burdens. The tythe, where there is
no
modus, and where it is levied in kind, diminishes more what
would
otherwise be the rent of the landlord, than a land tax
which
really amounted to five shillings in the pound. Such a
tythe
will be found, in most cases, to amount to more than a
fourth
part of the real rent of the land, or of what remains
after
replacing completely the capital of the farmer, together
with
his reasonable profit. If all moduses and all impropriations
were
taken away, the complete church tythe of Great Britain and
Ireland
could not well be estimated at less than six or seven
millions.
If there was no tythe either in Great Britain or
Ireland,
the landlords could afford to pay six or seven millions
additional
land tax, without being more burdened than a very
great
part of them are at present. America pays no tythe, and
could,
therefore, very well afford to pay a land tax. The lands
in
America and the West Indies, indeed, are, in general, not
tenanted
nor leased out to farmers. They could not, therefore, be
assessed
according to any rent roll. But neither were the lands
of
Great Britain, in the 4th of William and Mary, assessed
according
to any rent roll, but according to a very loose and
inaccurate
estimation. The lands in America might be assessed
either
in the same manner, or acording to an equitable valuation,
in
consequence of an accurate survey, like that which was lately
made in
the Milanese, and in the dominions of Austria, Prussia,
and
Sardinia.
Stamp
duties, it is evident, might be levied without any
variation,
in all countries where the forms of law process, and
the
deeds by which property, both real and personal, is
transferred,
are the same, or nearly the same.
The
extension of the custom-house laws of Great Britain to
Ireland
and the plantations, provided it was accompanied, as in
justice
it ought to be, with an extension of the freedom of
trade,
would be in the highest degree advantageous to both. All
the
invidious restraints which at present oppress the trade of
Ireland,
the distinction between the enumerated and
non-enumerated
commodities of America, would be entirely at an
end.
The countries north of Cape Finisterre would be as open to
every
part of the produce of America, as those south of that cape
are to
some parts of that produce at present. The trade between
all the
different parts of the British empire would, in
consequence
of this uniformity in the custom-house laws, be as
free as
the coasting trade of Great Britain is at present. The
British
empire would thus afford, within itself, an immense
internal
market for every part of the produce of all its
different
provinces. So great an extension of market would soon
compensate,
both to Ireland and the plantations, all that they
could
suffer from the increase of the duties of customs.
The
excise is the only part of the British system of taxation,
which
would require to be varied in any respect, according as it
was
applied to the different provinces of the empire. It might be
applied
to Ireland without any variation ; the produce and
consumption
of that kingdom being exactly of tho same nature with
those
of Great Britain. In its application to America and the
West
Indies, of which the produce and consumption are so very
different
from those of Great Britain, some modification might be
necessary,
in the same manner as in its application to the cyder
and
beer counties of England.
A
fermented liquor, for example, which is called beer, but which,
as it
is made of molasses, bears very little resemblance to our
beer,
makes a considerable part of the common drink of the people
in
America. This liquor, as it can be kept only for a few days,
cannot,
like our beer, be prepared and stored up for sale in
great
breweries ; but every private family must brew it for their
own
use, in the same manner as they cook their victuals. But to
subject
every private family to the odious visits and examination
of the
tax-gatherers, in the same manner as we subject the
keepers
of ale-houses and the brewers for public sale, would be
altogether
inconsistent with liberty. If, for the sake of
equality,
it was thought necessary to lay a tax upon this liquor,
it
might be taxed by taxing the material of which it is made,
either
at the place of manufacture, or, if the circumstances of
the
trade rendered such an excise improper, by laying a duty upon
its
importation into the colony in which it was to be consumed.
Besides
the duty of one penny a-gallon imposed by the British
parliament
upon the importation of molasses into America, there
is a
provincial tax of this kind upon their importation into
Massachusetts
Bay, in ships belonging to any other colony, of
eight-pence
the hogshead; and another upon their importation from
the
northern colonies into South Carolina, of five-pence the
gallon.
Or, if neither of these methods was found convenient,
each
family might compound for its consumption of this liquor,
either
according to the number of persons of which it consisted,
in the
same manner as private families compound for the malt tax
in
England; or according to the different ages and sexes of those
persons,
in the same manner as several different taxes are levied
in
Holland ; or, nearly as Sir Matthew Decker proposes, that all
taxes
upon consumable commodities should be levied in England.
This
mode of taxation, it has already been observed, when applied
to
objects of a speedy consumption, is not a very convenient one.
It
might be adopted, however, in cases where no better could be
done.
Sugar,
rum, and tobacco, are commodities which are nowhere
necessaries
of life, which are become objects of almost universal
consumption,
and which are, therefore, extremely proper subjects
of
taxation. If a union with the colonies were to take place,
those
commodities might be taxed, either before they go out of
the
hands of the manufacturer or grower ; or, if this mode of
taxation
did not suit the circumstances of those persons, they
might
be deposited in public warehouses, both at the place of
manufacture,
and at all the different ports of the empire, to
which
they might afterwards be transported, to remain there,
under
the joint custody of the owner and the revenue officer,
till
such time as they should be delivered out, either to the
consumer,
to the merchant-retailer for home consumption, or to
the
merchant-exporter; the tax not to be advanced till such
delivery.
When delivered out for exportation, to go duty-free,
upon
proper security being given, that they should really be
exported
out of the empire. These are,
perhaps, the principal
commodities,
with regard to which the union with the colonies
might
require some considerable change in the present system of
British
taxation.
What
might be the amount of the revenue which this system of
taxation,
extended to all the different provinces of the empire,
might
produce, it must, no doubt, be altogether impossible to
ascertain
with tolerable exactness. By means of this system,
there
is annually levied in Great Britain, upon less than eight
millions
of people, more than ten millions of revenue. Ireland
contains
more than two millions of people, and, according to the
accounts
laid before the congress, the twelve associated
provinces
of America contain more than three. Those accounts,
however,
may have been exaggerated, in order, perhaps, either to
encourage
their own people, or to intimidate those of this
country
; and we shall suppose, therefore, that our North
American
and West Indian colonies, taken together, contain no
more
than three millions ; or that the whole British empire, in
Europe
and America, contains no more than thirteen millions of
inhabitants.
If, upon less than eight millions of inhabitants,
this
system of taxation raises a revenue of more than ten
millions
sterling; it ought, upon thirteen millions of
inhabitants,
to raise a revenue of more than sixteen millions two
hundred
and fifty thousand pounds sterling. From this revenue,
supposing
that this system could produce it, must be deducted the
revenue
usually raised in Ireland and the plantations, for
defraying
the expense of the respective civil governments. The
expense
of the civil and military establishment of Ireland,
together
with the interest of the public debt, amounts, at a
medium
of the two years which ended March 1775, to something less
than
seven hundred and fifty thousand pounds ayear. By a very
exact
account of the revenue of the principal colonies of America
and the
West Indies, it amounted, before the commencement of the
present
disturbances, to a hundred and forty-one thousand eight
hundred
pounds. In this account, however, the revenue of
Maryland,
of North Carolina, and of all our late acquisitions,
both
upon the continent, and in the islands, is omitted; which
may,
perhaps, make a difference of thirty or forty thousand
pounds.
For the sake of even numbers, therefore, let us suppose
that
the revenue necessary for supporting the civil government of
Ireland
and the plantations may amount to a million. There would
remain,
consequently, a revenue of fifteen millions two hundred
and
fifty thousand pounds, to be applied towards defraying the
general
expense of the empire, and towards paying the public
debt.
But if, from the present revenue of Great Britain, a
million
could, in peaceable times, be spared towards the payment
of that
debt, six millions two hundred and fifty thousand pounds
could
very well be spared from this improved revenue. This great
sinking
fund, too, might be augmented every year by the interest
of the
debt which had been discharged the year before ; and
might,
in this manner, increase so very rapidly, as to be
sufficient
in a few years to discharge the whole debt, and thus
to
restore completely the at-present debilitated and languishing
vigour
of the empire. In the meantime, the people might be
relieved
from some of the most burdensome taxes; from those which
are
imposed either upon the necessaries of life, or upon the
materials
of manufacture. The labouring poor would thus be
enabled
to live better, to work cheaper, and to send their goods
cheaper
to market. The cheapness of their goods would increase
the
demand for them, and consequently for the labour of those who
produced
them. This increase in the demand for labour would both
increase
the numbers, and improve the circumstances of the
labouring
poor. Their consumption would increase, and, together
with
it, the revenue arising from all those articles of their
consumption
upon which the taxes might be allowed to remain.
The
revenue arising from this system of taxation, however, might
not
immediately increase in proportion to the number of people
who
were subjected to it. Great indulgence would for some time be
due to
those provinces of the empire which were thus subjected to
burdens
to which they had not before been accustomed; and even
when
the same taxes came to be levied everywhere as exactly as
possible,
they would not everywhere produce a revenue
proportioned
to the numbers of the people. In a poor country, the
consumption
of the principal commodities subject to the duties of
customs
and excise, is very small; and in a thinly inhabited
country,
the opportunities of smuggling are very great. The
consumption
of malt liquors among the inferior ranks of people in
Scotland
is very small ; and the excise upon malt, beer, and ale,
produces
less there than in England, in proportion to the numbers
of the
people and the rate of the duties, which upon malt is
different,
on account of a supposed difference of quality. In
these
particular branches of the excise, there is not, I
apprehend,
much more smuggling in the one country than in the
other.
The duties upon the distillery, and the greater part of
the
duties of customs, in proportion to the numbers of people in
the
respective countries, produce less in Scotland than in
England,
not only on account of the smaller consumption of the
taxed
commodities, but of the much greater facility of smuggling.
In
Ireland, the inferior ranks of people are still poorer than in
Scotland,
and many parts of the country are almost as thinly
inhabited.
In Ireland, therefore, the consumption of the taxed
commodities
might, in proportion to the number of the people, be
still
less than in Scotland, and the facility of smuggling nearly
the
same. In America and the West Indies, the white people, even
of the
lowest rank, are in much better circumstances than those
of the
same rank in England ; and their consumption of all the
luxuries
in which they usually indulge themselves, is probably
much
greater. The blacks, indeed, who make the greater part of
the
inhabitants, both of the southern colonies upon the continent
and of
the West India islands, as they are in a state of slavery,
are, no
doubt, in a worse condition than the poorest people
either
in Scotland or Ireland. We must not, however, upon that
account,
imagine that they are worse fed, or that their
consumption
of articles which might be subjected to moderate
duties,
is less than that even of the lower ranks of people in
England.
In order that they may work well, it is the interest of
their
master that they should be fed well, and kept in good
heart,
in the same manner as it is his interest that his working
cattle
should be so. The blacks, accordingly, have almost
everywhere
their allowance of rum, and of molasses or
spruce-beer,
in the same manner as the white servants ; and this
allowance
would not probably be withdrawn, though those articles
should
be subjected to moderate duties. The consumption of the
taxed
commodities, therefore, in proportion to the number of
inhabitants,
would probably be as great in America and the West
Indies
as in any part of the British empire. The opportunities of
smuggling,
indeed, would be much greater ; America, in proportion
to the
extent of the country, being much more thinly inhabited
than
either Scotland or Ireland. If the revenue, however, which
is at
present raised by the different duties upon malt and malt
liquors,
were to be levied by a single duty upon malt, the
opportunity
of smuggling in the most important branch of the
excise
would be almost entirely taken away ; and if the duties of
customs,
instead of being imposed upon almost all the different
articles
of importation, were confined to a few of the most
general
use and consumption, and if the levying of those duties
were
subjected to the excise laws, the opportunity of smuggling,
though
not so entirely taken away, would be very much diminished.
In
consequence of those two apparently very simple and easy
alterations,
the duties of customs and excise might probably
produce
a revenue as great, in proportion to the consumption of
the
most thinly inhabited province, as they do at present, in
proportion
to that of the most populous.
The
Americans, it has been said, indeed, have no gold or silver
money,
the interior commerce of the country being carried on by a
paper
currency; and the gold and silver, which occasionally come
among
them, being all sent to Great Britain, in return for the
commodities
which they receive from us. But without gold and
silver,
it is added, there is no possibility of paying taxes. We
already
get all the gold and silver which they have. How is it
possible
to draw from them what they have not ?
The
present scarcity of gold and silver money in America, is not
the
effect of the poverty of that country, or of the inability of
the
people there to purchase those metals. In a country where the
wages
of labour are so much higher, and the price of provisions
so much
lower than in England, the greater part of the people
must
surely have wherewithal to purchase a greater quantity, if
it were
either necessary or convenient for them to do so. The
scarcity
of those metals, therefore, must be the effect of
choice,
and not of necessity.
It is
for transacting either domestic or foreign business, that
gold or
silver money is either necessary or convenient.
The
domestic business of every country, it has been shewn in the
second
book of this Inquiry, may, at least in peaceable times, be
transacted
by means of a paper currency, with nearly the same
degree
of conveniency as by gold and silver money. It is
convenient
for the Americans, who could always employ with
profit,
in the improvement of their lands, a greater stock than
they
can easily get, to save as much as possible the expense of
so
costly an instrument of commerce as gold and silver; and
rather
to employ that part of their surplus produce which would
be
necessary for purchasing those metals, in purchasing the
instruments
of trade, the materials of clothing, several parts of
household
furniture, and the iron work necessary for building and
extending
their settlements and plantations ; in purchasing not
dead
stock, but active and productive stock. The colony
governments
find it for their interest to supply the people with
such a
quantity of paper money as is fully sufficient, and
generally
more than sufficient, for transacting their domestic
business.
Some of those governments, that of Pennsylvania,
particularly,
derive a revenue from lending this paper money to
their
subjects, at an interest of so much per cent. Others, like
that of
Massachusetts Bay, advance, upon extraordinary
emergencies,
a paper money of this kind for defraying the public
expense;
and afterwards, when it suits the conveniency of the
colony,
redeem it at the depreciated value to which it gradually
falls.
In 1747, {See Hutchinson's History of Massachusetts Bay
vol.
ii. page 436 et seq.} that colony paid in this manner the
greater
part of its public debts, with the tenth part of the
money
for which its bills had been granted. It suits the
conveniency
of the planters, to save the expense of employing
gold
and silver money in their domestic transactions; and it
suits
the conveniency of the colony governments, to supply them
with a
medium, which, though attended with some very considerable
disadvantages,
enables them to save that expense. The redundancy
of
paper money necessarily banishes gold and silver from the
domestic
transactions of the colonies, for the same reason that
it has
banished those metals from the greater part of the
domestic
transactions in Scotland ; and in both countries, it is
not the
poverty, but the enterprizing and projecting spirit of
the
people, their desire of employing all the stock which they
can
get, as active and productive stock, which has occasioned
this
redundancy of paper money.
In the
exterior commerce which the different colonies carry on
with
Great Britain, gold and silver are more or less employed,
exactly
in proportion as they are more or less necessary. Where
those
metals are not necessary, they seldom appear. Where they
are
necessary, they are generally found.
In the
commerce between Great Britain and the tobacco colonies,
the
British goods are generally advanced to the colonists at a
pretty
long credit, and are afterwards paid for in tobacco, rated
at a
certain price. It is more convenient for the colonists to
pay in
tobacco than in gold and silver. It would be more
convenient
for any merchant to pay for the goods which his
correspondents
had sold to him, in some other sort of goods which
he
might happen to deal in, than in money. Such a merchant would
have no
occasion to keep any part of his stock by him unemployed,
and in
ready money, for answering occasional demands. He could
have,
at all times, a larget quantity of goods in his shop or
warehouse,
and he could deal to a greater extent. But it seldom
happens
to be convenient for all the correspondents of a merchant
to
receive payment for the goods which they sell to him, in goods
of some
other kind which he happens to deal in. The British
merchants
who trade to Virginia and Maryland, happen to be a
particular
set of correspondents, to whom it is more convenient
to
receive payment for the goods which they sell to those
colonies
in tobacco, than in gold and silver. They expect to make
a
profit by the sale of the tobacco ; they could make none by
that of
the gold and silver. Gold and silver, therefore, very
seldom
appear in the commerce between Great Britain and the
tobacco
colonies. Maryland and Virginia have as little occasion
for
those metals in their foreign, as in their domestic commerce.
They
are said, accordingly, to have less gold and silver money
than
any other colonies in America. They are reckoned, however,
as
thriving, and consequently as rich, as any of their
neighbours.
In the
northern colonies, Pennsylvania, New York, New Jersey, the
four
governments of New England, etc. the value of their own
produce
which they export to Great Britain is not equal to that
of the
manufactures which they import for their own use, and for
that of
some of the other colonies, to which they are the
carriers.
A balance, therefore, must be paid to the
mother-country
in gold and silver and this balance they generally
find.
In the
sugar colonies, the value of the produce annually exported
to
Great Britain is much greater than that of all the goods
imported
from thence. If the sugar and rum annually sent to the
mother-country
were paid for in those colonies, Great Britain
would
be obliged to send out, every year, a very large balance in
money ;
and the trade to the West Indies would, by a certain
species
of politicians, be considered as extremely
disadvantageous.
But it so happens, that many of the principal
proprietors
of the sugar plantations reside in Great Britain.
Their
rents are remitted to them in sugar and rum, the produce of
their
estates. The sugar and rum which the West India merchants
purchase
in those colonies upon their own account, are not equal
in
value to the goods which they annually sell there. A balance,
therefore,
must necessarily be paid to them in gold and silver,
and
this balance, too, is generally found.
The
difficulty and irregularity of payment from the different
colonies
to Great Britain, have not been at all in proportion to
the
greatness or smallness of the balances which were
respectively
due from them. Payments have, in general, been more
regular
from the northern than from the tobacco colonies, though
the
former have generally paid a pretty large balance in money,
while
the latter have either paid no balance, or a much smaller
one.
The difficulty of getting payment from our different sugar
colonies
has been greater or less in proportion, not so much to
the
extent of the balances respectively due from them, as to the
quantity
of uncultivated land which they contained; that is, to
the
greater or smaller temptation which the planters have been
under
of over-trading, or of undertaking the settlement and
plantation
of greater quantities of waste land than suited the
extent
of their capitals. The returns from the great island of
Jamaica,
where there is still much uncultivated land, have, upon
this
account, been, in general, more irregular and uncertain than
those
from the smaller islands of Barbadoes, Antigua, and St.
Christopher's,
which have, for these many years, been completely
cultivated,
and have, upon that account, afforded less field for
the
speculations of the planter. The new acquisitions of Grenada,
Tobago,
St. Vincent's, and Dominica, have opened a new field for
speculations
of this kind ; and the returns front those islands
have of
late been as irregular and uncertain as those from the
great
island of Jamaica.
It is
not, therefore, the poverty of the colonies which
occasions,
in the greater part of them, the present scarcity of
gold
and silver money. Their great demand for active and
productive
stock makes it convenient for them to have as little
dead
stock as possible, and disposes them, upon that account, to
content
themselves with a cheaper, though less commodious
instrument
of commerce, than gold and silver. They are thereby
enabled
to convert the value of that gold and silver into the
instruments
of trade, into the materials of clothing, into
household
furniture, and into the iron work necessary for
building
and extending their settlements and plantations. In
those
branches of business which cannot be transacted without
gold
and silver money, it appears, that they can always find the
necessary
quantity of those metals; and if they frequently do not
find
it, their failure is generally the effect, not of their
necessary
poverty, but of their unnecessary and excessive
enterprise.
It is not because they are poor that their payments
are
irregular and uncertain, but because they are too eager to
become
excessively rich. Though all that part of the produce of
the
colony taxes, which was over and above what was necessary for
defraying
the expense of their own civil and military
establishments,
were to be remitted to Great Britain in gold and
silver,
the colonies have abundantly wherewithal to purchase the
requisite
quantity of those metals. They would in this case be
obliged,
indeed, to exchange a part of their surplus produce,
with
which they now purchase active and productive stock, for
dead
stock. In transacting their domestic
business, they
would
be obliged to employ a costly, instead of a cheap
instrument
of commerce; and the expense of purchasing this costly
instrument
might damp somewhat the vivacity and ardour of their
excessive
enterprise in the improvement of land. It might not,
however,
be necessary to remit any part of the American revenue
in gold
and silver. It might be remitted in bills drawn upon, and
accepted
by, particular merchants or companies in Great Britain,
to whom
a part of the surplus produce of America had been
consigned,
who would pay into the treasury the American revenue
in
money, after having themselves received the value of it in
goods ;
and the whole business might frequently be transacted
without
exporting a single ounce of gold or silver from America.
It is
not contrary to justice, that both Ireland and America
should
contribute towards the discharge of the public debt of
Great
Britain. That debt has been contracted in support of the
government
established by the Revolution ; a government to which
the
protestants of Ireland owe, not only the whole authority
which
they at present enjoy in their own country, but every
security
which they possess for their liberty, their property,
and
their religion; a government to which several of the colonies
of
America owe their present charters, and consequently their
present
constitution; and to which all the colonies of America
owe the
liberty, security, and property, which they have ever
since
enjoyed. That public debt has been contracted in the
defence,
not of Great Britain alone, but of all the different
provinces
of the empire. The immense debt contracted in the late
war in
particular, and a great part of that contracted in the war
before,
were both properly contracted in defence of America.
By a
union with Great Britain, Ireland would gain, besides the
freedom
of trade, other advantages much more important, and which
would
much more than compensate any increase of taxes that might
accompany
that union. By the union with
England, the
middling
and inferior ranks of people in Scotland gained a
complete
deliverance from the power of an aristocracy, which had
always
before oppressed them. By a union with Great Britain, the
greater
part of people of all ranks in Ireland would gain an
equally
complete deliverance from a much more oppressive
aristocracy
; an aristocracy not founded, like that of Scotland,
in the
natural and respectable distinctions of birth and fortune,
but in
the most odious of all distinctions, those of religious
and
political prejudices; distinctions which, more than any
other,
animate both the insolence of the oppressors, and the
hatred
and indignation of the oppressed, and which commonly
render
the inhabitants of the same country more hostile to one
another
than those of different countries ever are. Without a
union
with Great Britain, the inhabitants of Ireland are not
likely,
for many ages, to consider themselves as one people.
No
oppressive aristocracy has ever prevailed in the colonies.
Even
they, however, would, in point of happiness and
tranquillity,
gain considerably by a union with Great Britain. It
would,
at least, deliver them from those rancourous and virulent
factions
which are inseparable from small democracies, and which
have so
frequently divided the affections of their people, and
disturbed
the tranquillity of their governments, in their form so
nearly
democratical. In the case of a total separation from Great
Britain,
which, unless prevented by a union of this kind, seems
very
likely to take place, those factions would be ten times more
virulent
than ever. Before the commencement of the present
disturbances,
the coercive power of the mother-country had always
been
able to restrain those factions from breaking out into any
thing
worse than gross brutality and insult. If that coercive
power
were entirely taken away, they would probably soon break
out
into open violence and bloodshed. In all great countries
which
are united under one uniform government, the spirit of
party
commonly prevails less in the remote provinces than in the
centre
of the empire. The distance of those provinces from the
capital,
from the principal seat of the great scramble of faction
and
ambition, makes them enter less into the views of any of the
contending
parties, and renders them more indifferent and
impartial
spectators of the conduct of all. The spirit of party
prevails
less in Scotland than in England. In the case of a
union,
it would probably prevail less in Ireland than in
Scotland;
and the colonies would probably soon enjoy a degree of
concord
and unanimity, at present unknown in any part of the
British
empire. Both Ireland and the colonies, indeed, would be
subjected
to heavier taxes than any which they at present pay. In
consequence,
however, of a diligent and faithful application of
the
public revenue towards the discharge of the national debt,
the
greater part of those taxes might not be of long continuance,
and the
public revenue of Great Britain might soon be reduced to
what
was necessary for maintaining a moderate
peace-establishment.
The
territorial acquisitions of the East India Company, the
undoubted
right of the Crown, that is, of the state and people of
Great
Britain, might be rendered another source of revenue, more
abundant,
perhaps, than all those already mentioned. Those
countries
are represented as more fertile, more extensive, and,
in
proportion to their extent, much richer and more populous than
Great
Britain. In order to draw a great revenue from them, it
would
not probably be necessary to introduce any new system of
taxation
into countries which are already sufficiently, and more
than
sufficiently, taxed. It might, perhaps, be more proper to
lighten
than to aggravate the burden of those unfortunate
countries,
and to endeavour to draw a revenue from them, not by
imposing
new taxes, but by preventing the embezzlement and
misapplication
of the greater part of those which they already
pay.
If it
should be found impracticable for Great Britain to draw any
considerable
augmentation of revenue from any of the resources
above
mentioned, the only resource which can remain to her, is a
diminution
of her expense. In the mode of collecting and in that
of
expending the public revenue, though in both there may be
still
room for improvement, Great Britain seems to be at least as
economical
as any of her neighbours. The military establishment
which
she maintains for her own defence in time of peace, is more
moderate
than that of any European state, which can pretend to
rival
her either in wealth or in power. None of these articles,
therefore,
seem to admit of any considerable reduction of
expense. The expense of the peace-establishment of
the
colonies
was, before the commencement of the present
disturbances,
very considerable, and is an expense which may,
and, if
no revenue can be drawn from them, ought certainly to be
saved
altogether. This constant expense in time of peace, though
very
great, is insignificant in comparison with what the defence
of the
colonies has cost us in time of war. The last war, which
was
undertaken altogether on account of the colonies, cost Great
Britain,
it has already been observed, upwards of ninety
millions.
The Spanish war of 1739 was principally undertaken on
their
account; in which, and in the French war that was the
consequence
of it, Great Britain, spent upwards of forty millions
; a
great part of which ought justly to be charged to the
colonies.
In those two wars, the colonies cost Great Britain much
more
than double the sum which the national debt amounted to
before
the commencement of the first of them. Had it not been for
those
wars, that debt might, and probably would by this time,
have
been completely paid; and had it not been for the colonies,
the
former of those wars might not, and the latter certainly
would
not, have been undertaken. It was because the colonies were
supposed
to be provinces of the British Empire, that this expense
was
laid out upon them. But countries which contribute neither
revenue
nor military force towards the support of the empire,
cannot
be considered as provinces. They may, perhaps, be
considered
as appendages, as a sort of splendid and shewy
equipage
of the empire. But if the empire can no longer support
the
expense of keeping up this equipage, it ought certainly to
lay it
down ; and if it cannot raise its revenue in proportion to
its
expense, it ought at least to accommodate its expense to its
revenue.
If the colonies, notwithstanding their refusal to submit
to
British taxes, are still to be considered as provinces of the
British
empire, their defence, in some future war, may cost Great
Britain
as great an expense as it ever has done in any former
war.
The rulers of Great Britain have, for more than a century
past,
amused the people with the imagination that they possessed
a great
empire on the west side of the Atlantic. This empire,
however,
has hitherto existed in imagination only. It has
hitherto
been, not an empire, but the project of an empire ; not
a gold
mine, but the project of a gold mine; a project which has
cost,
which continues to cost, and which, if pursued in the same
way as
it has been hitherto, is likely to cost, immense expense,
without
being likely to bring any profit ; for the effects of the
monopoly
of the colony trade, it has been shewn, are to the great
body of
the people, mere loss instead of profit. It is surely now
time
that our rulers should either realize this golden dream, in
which
they have been indulging themselves, perhaps, as well as
the
people ; or that they should awake from it themselves, and
endeavour
to awaken the people. If the project cannot be
completed,
it ought to be given up. If any of the provinces of
the
British empire cannot be made to contribute towards the
support
of the whole empire, it is surely time that Great Britain
should
free herself from the expense of defending those provinces
in time
of war, and of supporting any part of their civil or
military
establishment in time of peace; and endeavour to
accommodate
her future views and designs to the real mediocrity
of her
circumstances.